IN THE SUPREME COURT OF TENNESSEE
AT NASHVILLE
October 2, 2002 Session
JOHN T. KING v. ANNE B. POPE
Appeal by permission from the Court of Appeals, Middle Section
Chancery Court for Davidson County
No. 99-3550-III Ellen Hobbs Lyle, Chancellor
No. M2000-02127-SC-R11-CV - Filed December 19, 2002
In this case, we must decide whether a pay telephone sale-leaseback program marketed and
sold by the plaintiff constitutes an investment contract, and thus a security under the Tennessee
Securities Act of 1980. In finding that the program was a security, the trial court applied the
definition of “investment contract” adopted by the Court of Criminal Appeals in State v. Brewer, 932
S.W.2d 1 (Tenn. Crim. App.), perm. app. denied (Tenn. 1996). Under this test, an investment
contract exists where
(1) An offeree furnishes initial value to an offeror, and (2) a portion of this initial
value is subjected to the risks of the enterprise, and (3) the furnishing of the initial
value is induced by the offeror's promises or representations which give rise to a
reasonable understanding that a valuable benefit of some kind, over and above the
initial value, will accrue to the offeree as a result of the operation of the enterprise,
and (4) the offeree does not receive the right to exercise practical and actual control
over the managerial decisions of the enterprise.
Brewer, 932 S.W.2d at 11 (quoting State v. Hawaii Market, 485 P.2d 105, 109 (Haw. 1971)).
The Court of Appeals rejected the Brewer test and instead adopted the federal test for
determining whether a particular transaction is an investment contract. See United Hous. Found.,
Inc. v. Forman, 421 U.S. 837 (1975); SEC v. W.J. Howey Co., 328 U.S. 293 (1946). Applying this
test, the Court of Appeals held that the pay telephone sale-leaseback program at issue in this case is
not a security. After careful consideration, we agree with the trial court’s finding that the appropriate
test for determining the presence of an investment contract is set forth in Brewer. Applying this test,
we agree with the trial court that the plaintiff’s payphone sale-leaseback program is an investment
contract and that the plaintiff was thus marketing and selling unregistered securities in violation of
Tennessee law.
Tenn. R. App. P. 11; Judgment of the Court of Appeals Reversed
FRANK F. DROWOTA , III, C. J., delivered the opinion of the court, in which E. RILEY ANDERSON,
ADOLPHO A. BIRCH, JR., JANICE M. HOLDER, and WILLIAM M. BARKER, JJ. joined.
Paul G. Summers, Attorney General and Reporter; Michael E. Moore, Solicitor General; and Janet
M. Kleinfelter, Senior Counsel, Nashville, Tennessee, for Appellant, Anne B. Pope, Commissioner
of the Tennessee Department of Commerce and Insurance.
R. Louis Crossley, Jr., Knoxville, Tennessee, and W. Davidson Broemel, Nashville, Tennessee, for
Appellee, John T. King.
OPINION
Factual Background
In February 1994, the plaintiff, John King, a registered securities agent and president of
Capital Investments, Inc. (“CII”), began offering and selling to Tennessee residents a pay telephone
sale-leaseback program for Quarter Call, Inc. (“QCI”), a company that provided discount pay
telephone long distance service to all fifty states, at the rate of twenty-five cents per minute. The
program was comprised of three documents, all of which were executed by participants
simultaneously: a purchase agreement, a telephone lease-agreement, and an option to sell agreement.
Participants first signed the purchase agreement to buy a minimum of three pay telephones from
QCI, at a price of $4,995 per phone, with $495 of that amount applied toward the purchase of a
performance bond from American Diversified Insurance Company (“ADIC”). The purchase
agreement provided that the telephones would be delivered to QCI’s home office in Bethesda,
Maryland.
Participants next executed a telephone lease-agreement whereby they leased the pay
telephones back to QCI for a term of sixty months. QCI agreed to pay participants $75 per month
per telephone for the term. Participants did not receive any right under the lease agreement to any
percentage of the revenues or profits generated through operation of the pay telephones. In addition,
participants did not share in the losses. QCI agreed to pay all costs associated with using the
telephones, including expenses of repair, taxes, and insurance. QCI further agreed to indemnify the
participants against any and all loss, damage, liability, and expense associated with the pay
telephones. While the lease agreement provided that “the equipment shall at all times be under the
sole and absolute control of QCI,” participants were entitled to notification of their telephones’
exact location within ten business days of the time the telephones had been installed. The lease
agreement afforded participants the right to terminate the lease upon sixty days notice and payment
of a termination fee. However, QCI was not required to accept more than 100 early terminations
during any sixty-day period.
The final document participants executed was an option to sell agreement whereby they were
given the option to sell the pay telephones back to QCI at any time so long as specified notice was
given: To sell at the end of the lease term, 180 days notice was required. To sell prior to the lease’s
expiration, sixty days notice was required. Upon receiving the appropriate notice, QCI agreed to
purchase participants’ pay telephones for $4500 each, less any applicable early termination fee.
-2-
QCI and King used promotional literature, containing a number of representations, to market
and advertise the program to the general public. Promotional literature indicated that QCI chose the
locations for the pay telephones and supplied advertising and marketing of the payphone service to
the general public. Materials included a letter from QCI President Glenn Kendall, stating the
following:
I assume you are interested because you are fed up with 3% or 4% returns on
your savings; or, maybe you are uncomfortable with risking your money in the stock
market?
Whatever the reasons for your interest, you are about to learn how, by buying
and leasing pay telephones, you can receive......
• An 18% net, fixed annual return on your money.
• Fully guaranteed income. Your returns are insured through a faithful
performance bond from American Diversified Insurance Company.
• Monthly returns. You receive a check every month for 60 consecutive
months.
• A high degree of liquidity. You may withdraw all or part of your money prior
to the full term!
• Substantially tax sheltered income (IRS Section 179). See your tax advisor.
• Security. You actually hold title to a valuable asset and always know where
it is located.
• Insurance. Your equipment is insured at 100% of its value.
• A successful, growing company. QCI has grown tremendously due to
increasing consumer demand for the QCI discount payphones which enable
callers to call all 50 states (including Alaska and Hawaii) for just 25 [cents]
per minute.
Admin. R. at 64 (emphasis in original). Additionally, QCI described the nature of the sale-leaseback
program as “a very common and legal method by which corporations may quickly raise money for
capital expenditures and expansion, without sacrificing equity in the company.”
On March 22, 1994, less than two months after King began advertising and marketing this
program, the Commissioner of the Department of Commerce and Insurance (“Commissioner”)
issued a cease and desist order against King and CII, on the basis that the QCI sale-leaseback
program was a security as defined in the Tennessee Securities Act of 1980 (“the Act”), that the
program had not been registered as a security, and therefore, that King and CII had violated the Act
by selling this unregistered security. Thereafter, the Securities Division of the Department of
Commerce and Insurance filed a complaint seeking to revoke King’s registration as a securities agent
for violating the Act. King’s response denied all allegations and requested a contested case hearing
under the Uniform Administrative Procedures Act. Following a pre-trial conference, the parties
stipulated as to the facts and submitted briefs on the issue of whether the QCI sale-leaseback
program was a security under Tennessee law. The Administrative Law Judge, applying the test
adopted in State v. Brewer, 932 S.W.2d 1 (Tenn. Crim. App.), perm. app. denied (Tenn. 1996),
-3-
concluded that the sale-leaseback program was a security. The Commissioner issued a final order
adopting the findings and conclusions of the Administrative Law Judge and directing that King’s
license be revoked.
King filed a petition for judicial review in the Chancery Court of Davidson County. See
Tenn. Code Ann. § 4-5-322 (1999). The chancery court held that the Hawaii Market test adopted
in Brewer is the appropriate test to apply to determine if the sale-leaseback transaction was an
investment contract. Applying this test, the Chancellor upheld the Commissioner’s decision
revoking King’s license for selling unregistered securities in violation of state law.
King appealed, and the Court of Appeals reversed. In so doing, the intermediate court
rejected the test adopted in Brewer and held that the federal Howey-Forman definition for
“investment contract” is the appropriate test to apply in Tennessee when determining whether a
transaction constitutes an investment contract. The Court of Appeals found that the QCI sale-
leaseback program was not an investment contract because it lacked the “common enterprise”
element. Therefore, the Court of Appeals held that King’s license should not be revoked for selling
unregistered securities.
We granted the Commissioner’s application for permission to appeal and now reverse the
judgment of the Court of Appeals.
Standard of Review
Resolution of the issues before this Court hinges on the interpretation of Tennessee Code
Annotated section 48-2-102(12) and the application of that law to the facts of the case.
“Construction of a statute and its application to the facts of a case are issues of law.” Patterson v.
Tennessee Dept. of Labor and Workforce Dev., 60 S.W.3d 60, 62 (Tenn. 2001) (citing Beare Co. v.
Tennessee Dept. of Revenue, 858 S.W.2d 906, 907 (Tenn.1993)). “The review of a question of law
is de novo, with no presumption of correctness afforded to the conclusions of the court below.” State
v. McKnight, 51 S.W.3d 559, 562 (Tenn. 2001) (citing Comdata Network, Inc. v. Tennessee Dept.
of Revenue, 852 S.W.2d 223, 224 (Tenn.1993); Tennessee Farmers Mut. Ins. Co. v. Witt, 857
S.W.2d 26, 29 (Tenn.1993); Nash v. Mulle, 846 S.W.2d 803, 804 (Tenn.1993)).
Analysis
The Definition of an Investment Contract
We begin our analysis with the language of the Tennessee Securities Act of 1980, which
defines the term “security” as follows:
(12) ‘Security’ means any note, stock, treasury stock, bond, debenture, evidence of
indebtedness, certificate of interest or participation in any profit-sharing agreement,
collateral-trust certificate, preorganization certificate or subscription, transferable
-4-
share, investment contract, voting-trust certificate, certificate of deposit for a security,
certificate of interest or participation in an oil, gas, or mining title or lease or in
payments out of production under such a title or lease; or, in general, any interest or
instrument commonly known as a “security,” or any certificate of interest or
participation in, temporary or interim certificate for, receipt for, guarantee of, or
warrant or right to subscribe to or purchase any of the foregoing.
Tenn. Code Ann. § 48-2-102(12) (1995) (emphasis added). This definition is substantially identical
to definitions contained in the federal Securities Act of 1933 and the federal Securities Exchange Act
of 1934 . See Securities Act of 1933, 15 U.S.C. § 77b(1) (2002); Securities Exchange Act of 1934,
15 U.S.C. § 78c(a)(10) (2002). While the statute makes plain that an investment contract is a
security, the statute does not define the term “investment contract.”
The Commissioner argues that the Court of Appeals’ decision rejecting Brewer and applying
Howey-Forman conflicts with the fundamental purpose of Tennessee’s securities laws, which is to
protect investors. As support for this claim, the Commissioner relies upon this Court’s decision in
DeWees v. State, 390 S.W.2d 241, 242 (Tenn. 1965), directing that securities laws are remedial
statutes that must be liberally construed to protect investors from fraud.
A brief review of the development, history, and purpose of state securities laws is necessary
to place this issue in context. Securities regulation first developed as state law. State securities
statutes, or “blue sky” laws, were this country’s sole means of regulating securities for more than two
decades, until the federal government enacted the Securities Act of 1933 and the Securities Exchange
Act of 1934.1 In creating the federal securities regulation laws, Congress has specifically refused to
preempt state blue sky laws. See 15 U.S.C. § 77r (2002). Thus, both state and federal laws now
regulate the marketing and sales of securities.
One reason for this dual system of securities regulation is that the state and federal laws were
adopted to serve different purposes. Like Tennessee, states enacted securities regulation to protect
investors. See 1980 Tenn. Pub. Acts, ch. 866, § 25 (stating that the securities laws are intended “to
protect investors”); see also, e.g., Carder v. Burrow, 940 S.W.2d 429 (Ark. 1997); People v.
Figueroa, 715 P.2d 680, 695 (Cal. 1986); Rosenthal v. Dean Witter Reynolds, 908 P.2d 1095, 1105
(Colo. 1995); Skurnick v. Ainsworth, 591 So.2d 904, 906 (Fla. 1994); Ratliffe v. Hartsfield Co., 184
S.E. 324, 327 (Ga. 1935); State v. Hawaii Market, 485 P.2d 105, 109 (Haw. 1971); State v. Coin
Wholesalers, Inc., 250 N.W.2d 583, 588 (Minn. 1976). Federal securities regulations, on the other
hand, were enacted to serve the broader purpose of protecting the integrity of the increasingly
nationalized market. See 15 U.S.C. § 78b (2002); Robert B. Thompson, The Measure of Recovery
Under Rule 10b-5: A Restitution Alternative to Tort Damages, 37 Vand. L. Rev. 349, 393 (1984)
1
See generally Jonathan R. Macey & Geoffrey P. Miller, Origin of the Blue Sky Laws, 70
Tex. L. Rev. 347 (1991).
-5-
(quoting Shapiro v. Merrill Lynch, Pierce, Fenner & Smith, Inc., 495 F.2d 228, 236-37 (2d Cir.
1974)).
The different, but complementary, purposes served by the dual system of securities regulation
is further reflected in the differing treatment of the term “investment contract” by state and federal
courts. The term was first used by state legislatures and first construed by state courts. Seeking to
afford maximum protection to investors, state courts, like the Minnesota Supreme Court,2 construed
the term broadly in accordance with its commonly understood meaning.
Twenty-six years later, the United States Supreme Court defined “investment contract” as
it applied to the Securities Exchange Act of 1933 in SEC v. W.J. Howey Co., 328 U.S. 293 (1946).
Under Howey, an investment contract “means a contract, transaction or scheme whereby a person
invests his money in a common enterprise and is led to expect profits solely from the efforts of the
promoter or a third party.” Id. at 298-99 (emphasis added). This definition was criticized as being
too rigid, particularly its requirement that profits be derived solely from the efforts of the promoter
or a third party.3
In 1971, the Hawaii Supreme Court became one of the first state courts to openly reject the
Howey test and formulate a more flexible test for determining which transactions constitute an
investment contract under its state securities laws.4 See State v. Hawaii Market, 485 P.2d 105 (Haw.
2
The Minnesota Supreme Court stated: “The placing of capital or laying out of money in a
way intended to secure income or profit from its employment is an investment as that word is
commonly used and understood. If defendant issued and sold its certificates to purchasers who paid
their money, justly expecting to receive an income or profit from the investment, it would seem that
the statute should apply.” State v. Gopher Tire & Rubber Co., 177 N.W. 937, 938 (Minn. 1920).
3
See, e.g., SEC v. Koscot Inter., Inc., 497 F.2d 473, 479-84 (5th Cir. 1974); SEC v. Glenn
W. Turner Enters., Inc., 474 F.2d 476, 482 (9th Cir. 1973); State v. Hawaii Market, 485 P.2d 105,
108 (Haw. 1971) (“The primary weakness of the Howey formula is that it has led courts to analyze
investment projects mechanically, based on a narrow concept of investor participation.” (citations
omitted)).
4
Note, however, that the Minnesota Supreme Court, which construed “investment contract”
in 1920, continues to adhere to its initial construction and refuses to follow Howey. “In contrast to
the fairly rigid Howey test, we have continued to abide by a broader and more flexible standard.
In State v. Gopher Tire & Rubber Co., 146 Minn. 52, 56, 177 N.W. 937, 938 (1920), we defined an
investment contract as ‘[t]he placing of capital or laying out of money in a way intended to secure
income or profit from its employment.’ As recently as 1973, this court exhaustively reviewed the
history of securities regulation in this state and concluded that although ‘the Howey test is useful in
(continued...)
-6-
1971). The Hawaii Market test requires proof of the following four elements for an investment
contract to be present:
(1) An offeree furnishes initial value to an offeror, and (2) a portion of this initial
value is subjected to the risks of the enterprise, and (3) the furnishing of the initial
value is induced by the offeror's promises or representations which give rise to a
reasonable understanding that a valuable benefit of some kind, over and above the
initial value, will accrue to the offeree as a result of the operation of the enterprise,
and (4) the offeree does not receive the right to exercise practical and actual control
over the managerial decisions of the enterprise.
Id. at 109. The Hawaii Supreme Court utilized the concepts from “risk capital theory,” stating that
the “subjection of the investor’s money to the risks of an enterprise over which he exerts no
managerial control is the basic economic reality of a security transaction.” Id.
A few years after the Hawaii Market decision, the United States Supreme Court revisited the
test adopted in Howey. Responding to the criticism of Howey, the Court in Forman emphasized that
in determining whether a particular transaction is an investment contract and thus a “security,” the
focus must be on “the substance — the economic realities of the transaction — rather than the names
that may have been employed by the parties.” United Hous. Found., Inc. v. Forman, 421 U.S. 837,
851-52 (1975). To this end, the Court stated that “[t]he touchstone is the presence of an investment
in a common venture premised on a reasonable expectation of profits to be derived from the
entrepreneurial or managerial efforts of others.” Id. at 852. Thus, the “Howey-Forman” test
emerged as the new, more flexible federal test for what constitutes a security.
Against this backdrop, in 1996, the Tennessee Court of Criminal Appeals elected to employ
the Hawaii Market test to determine whether the transaction in question was an investment contract
under Tennessee law. See Brewer, 932 S.W.2d at 14. In support of its decision, the Brewer court
noted that, as of 1996, seventeen jurisdictions had adopted the Hawaii Market test. See id. at 13
n.13. Furthermore, Brewer highlighted the similarities between the two tests as follows:
The first prong of the Hawaii Market test is nothing more than the investment
concept of the Howey-Forman test. The second prong adopts the concept of risk
capital, whereas Howey-Forman focuses on the existence of a common venture, i.e.,
vertical or horizontal commonality. The third prong of Hawaii Market utilizes the
more liberal concept of the expectation to receive a “benefit” instead of the slightly
4
(...continued)
identifying most “investment contracts,” we decline to adopt it as exclusive under our statute.’ State
v. Investors Security Corp., 297 Minn. 1, 11, 209 N.W.2d 405, 410 (1973). We remain convinced
that the Gopher Tire test is better suited to facilitate the objectives of our securities act, which is
designed to protect investors by regulating the merits of securities offered for sale to the public.”
State by Spannaus v. Coin Wholesalers, Inc., 250 N.W.2d 583, 588 (Minn. 1976).
-7-
more restrictive concept of “profits” found in Howey-Forman. Lastly, the fourth
prong makes explicit, in layman’s terms, the Howey-Forman principle that the
investor exercises no managerial control.
Id. at 13-14.
In adopting the Hawaii Market test, the Brewer court noted that DeWees mandated liberal
construction of securities laws to protect the public and that the Hawaii Market test better serves the
remedial purpose of Tennessee’s securities laws by embracing not only “obvious and commonplace”
investment schemes, but also “‘the countless and variable schemes devised by those who seek the
money of others on the promise of profits.’” Id. at 14 (quoting Howey, 328 U.S. at 299).
Additionally, the Brewer court deemed the Hawaii Market test superior in providing detailed
statements of its elements in layman’s terms, which promotes the proper administration of justice
by the jury. Id.
In this case, the test adopted in Brewer was applied by the administrative law judge, the
Commissioner, and the chancery court. However, the Court of Appeals adopted the Howey-Forman
test used by the Sixth Circuit in Cooper v. King, No. 96-5361, 1997 U.S. App. LEXIS 11296, (6th
Cir. May 9, 1997), an unpublished case involving the sale of pay telephones in the same manner and
under the same terms as in the present case.5
After careful consideration, we conclude the Court of Appeals erred in adopting the Howey-
Forman test. The appropriate test for defining an “investment contract” under Tennessee law is the
Hawaii Market test adopted in Brewer. First, the General Assembly has stated that the Tennessee
Securities Act of 1980 should be interpreted “to effectuate its general purpose to protect investors”
and “to coordinate the interpretation and administration of this Act with related federal and state
regulation.” 1980 Tenn. Pub. Acts, ch. 866, § 25. As noted by the Brewer court, the Hawaii Market
test better serves the remedial purpose of Tennessee’s securities laws by embracing not only
“obvious and commonplace” investment schemes, but also “‘the countless and variable schemes
devised by those who seek the money of others on the promise of profits.’” Brewer, 932 S.W.2d at
14 (quoting Howey, 328 U.S. at 299). As previously explained, state and federal regulations serve
different purposes. While the federal test is tailored to federal law, the Hawaii Market test adopted
in Brewer is more in keeping with the public policy espoused by this Court in DeWees because it
presents a more flexible definition of “investment contract.”
5
In Cooper, the plaintiffs were individuals who participated in the QCI payphone sale-
leaseback program. QCI defaulted on its payments to the plaintiffs after only four payments, and the
performance bond payed only a fraction of its obligation. The plaintiffs sued in federal court under
federal and state securities laws, but the District Court and the Court of Appeals found that the
program was not a security under the Howey-Forman test, as the courts found that the second prong
of the Howey-Forman test, “a common enterprise,” was lacking.
-8-
King argues that the Howey-Forman test advances the second stated purpose of the 1980 Act
— uniformity and coordination with state and federal regulation. See 1980 Tenn. Pub. Acts, ch. 866,
§ 25. In support of this argument, King emphasizes that the Howey-Forman test has been adopted
by a majority of jurisdictions and that the ample case law from other jurisdictions applying the
Howey-Forman test to various transactions provides notice to investors and brokers of the types of
transactions that qualify as investment contracts under Tennessee law. We disagree. While the
General Assembly clearly intended for Tennessee’s securities laws to operate harmoniously with
federal and other state securities regulations, adopting the Howey-Forman test does not accomplish
this result because this test is not consistently applied among the states or the federal circuits.
The primary area of disagreement surrounds the Howey-Forman test’s second element: a
common enterprise. Three bases for commonality are recognized by the federal courts. The strictest
test is that of horizontal commonality, requiring the pooling of assets in which the fortunes of the
individual investors are inextricably intertwined by contractual and financial arrangement. See
Union Planters Nat’l Bank v. Commercial Credit Bus. Loans, Inc., 651 F.2d 1174, 1183 (6th Cir.
1981). The other test, vertical commonality, has two variants. Narrow vertical commonality
requires that the investors’ fortunes be “interwoven with and dependent upon the efforts and success
of those seeking the investment of third parties.” SEC v. Glenn W. Turner Enters., 474 F.2d 476,
482 n.7 (9th Cir. 1973). Broad vertical commonality, on the other hand, only requires that the well-
being of the investors be dependent on the promoter’s experience. See SEC v. SG Ltd., 265 F.3d
42, 49 (1st Cir. 2001).
The United States Supreme Court has not adopted a test for the common enterprise element
of the Howey-Forman test, and the circuits are split on this issue. Both the Sixth and Seventh
Circuits require a showing of horizontal commonality to satisfy the common enterprise element.
See, e.g., Curran v. Merrill Lynch, Pierce, Fenner & Smith, 622 F.2d 216, 222, 224 (6th Cir. 1980);
Wals v. Fox Hills Dev. Corp., 24 F.3d 1016, 1018 (7th Cir. 1994). Four other circuits have adopted
horizontal commonality, but have yet to rule on whether vertical commonality also would be
acceptable. See SEC v. Infinity Group Co., 212 F.3d 180, 187 n.9 (3d Cir. 2000), cert. denied, 121
S. Ct. 1228 (2001); SEC v. Life Partners, Inc., 87 F.3d 536, 544 (D.C. Cir. 1996); Teague v. Bakker,
35 F.3d 978, 986 n.8 (4th Cir. 1994); Revak v. SEC Realty Co., 18 F.3d 81, 88 (2d Cir.
1994)(rejecting broad vertical commonality). Thus, the Howey-Forman test is not applied
consistently among the circuits. Moreover, despite its adherence to horizontal commonality, the
Sixth Circuit has not been consistent in its interpretation of the “pooling of funds” requirement.6 In
6
For example, in McCoy v. Hilliard, 940 F.2d 660, 1991 U.S. App. LEXIS 17760 at 24 (6th
Cir. 1991), the Sixth Circuit found that an investment contract existed where river barges were sold
either individually or through limited partnerships to investors and the barges themselves, rather than
investor funds, were pooled. In SEC v. Professional Associates, 731 F.2d 349, 354 (6th Cir. 1984),
the Sixth Circuit found that certain trust agreements were investment contracts, because although
(continued...)
-9-
addition, states within the Sixth Circuit — Ohio, Kentucky, and Michigan — have varying
approaches to defining an investment contract. The Ohio Court of Appeals has adopted the Hawaii
Market test. See State v. George, 362 N.E.2d 1223 (Ohio. App. 1975). The Kentucky Court of
Appeals has adopted the Howey-Forman definition, as has the Michigan Court of Appeals. See
Scholarship Counselors, Inc. v. Waddle, 507 S.W.2d 138 (Ky. 1974); Rzepka v. Michael, 431
N.W.2d 441 (Mich. App. 1988). However, a Michigan statute defines “security” by using the
language of the Hawaii Market test. See Mich. Comp. Laws § 451.801(1) (2002). Given the federal
and state courts’ varying interpretations of Howey-Forman, King’s assertion that its adoption will
advance uniformity and predictability has a hollow ring.
We reiterate and reaffirm our statement in DeWees, that securities laws “are remedial in
character, designed to prevent frauds and impositions upon the public, and consequently should be
liberally construed to effectuate the purpose of the acts.” 390 S.W.2d at 242. Since the Tennessee
Securities Act of 1980 was enacted with the goal of protecting investors, this Court’s primary
concern is with the investors of this state. This Court also believes that the danger in adopting the
stricter Howey-Forman test for “investment contract” is that it allows unscrupulous promoters to
circumvent the law. Thus, we find that the Hawaii Market test as adopted in Brewer is the test better
suited to protect investors.
The Brewer Test as Applied to the Sale-Leaseback Program
A. Initial Value
The first prong of the Brewer test requires that the offeree furnishes “initial value.”
Participants in King and QCI’s program bought a minimum of three pay telephones at $4995 per pay
telephone. Participants never took possession of the phones, nor did participants pay taxes on the
phones or choose locations for their phones. Furthermore, it is clear from promotional materials that
QCI intended the program to “quickly raise money for capital expenditures and expansion, without
sacrificing equity in the company.”
6
(...continued)
there was no commingling of investor assets, the court looked to promotional materials that “gave
rise to an implication that investors' funds were to be pooled” and considered testimony that
suggested that some investors’ money was actually commingled. Finally, in Cooper v. King, 1997
U.S. App. LEXIS 11296, at *6, the Sixth Circuit found that while pooling of funds was present, there
was no evidence of contractual or financial arrangement that “inextricably intertwined” the investors’
fortunes, thus, contrary to the holding in Professional Associates, horizontal commonality was not
present in Cooper.
-10-
King argues that, in the case of the sale of personal property, there must be an overpayment
of fair value by the investor in order for there to be a finding of initial value. King bases his
argument on Hawaii Market, in which participants in a private wholesale club scheme payed grossly
inflated prices for consumer items in order to join the club and receive future commissions on sales.
Rather than being a requirement for “initial value,” however, the presence of overpayment was
simply how the Hawaii Market court distinguished the transaction from a simple purchase of
merchandise. In this case, King’s program requires little distinguishing from a sale of merchandise:
purchasers never took possession of the pay telephones, and, furthermore, QCI was not in the
business of selling pay telephones: QCI was in the business of providing discount long-distance
telephone service. Thus, this Court finds that Prong 1, the furnishing of initial value, is satisfied.
B. Initial Value Subject to the Risks of the Enterprise
The second prong of the Brewer test requires that a portion of the initial value be subject to
the risks of the enterprise. As the Brewer court stated, this “second prong adopts the concept of risk
capital.” Brewer, 932 S.W.2d at 13. The Brewer court explained that “[u]nder the risk capital test
the focus is . . . on whether the promoter is relying on the investors for a substantial portion of the
initial capital necessary to launch the enterprise.” Id. at 11 (citing State v. Consumer Bus. Sys., Inc,
482 P.2d 549, 555 (Or. App. 1971)). QCI was looking for a quick means of financing a $50 million
expansion. The promotional materials clearly stated that “[b]y going to private investors, QCI is able
to raise expansion capital quickly without having to give up valuable equity.” These promotional
materials clearly reflect the risk capital concept: investors were sought out by King, they paid value,
and in return they expected QCI to pay them a return on their investment. Furthermore, investors
did not rely on their own pay telephones to produce an income; instead, investors were dependent
on the profitability of the entire enterprise.
King argues that this prong is not met because the lease provided for a fixed payment that
was secured by a performance bond. However, it is clear from the record that potential investors
were led to believe that the transaction was an investment. QCI promotional materials invited
participants to join “our growing QCI network” and pledged that “it is QCI’s business policy to share
the profits with our clients, by paying them a very high rate of return.” The chancery court found
that the performance bond was essentially worthless from the outset because it was guaranteed by
an insurance company that was neither registered nor qualified to do business in Tennessee. King
asks this Court to look only at the structure of the transaction, to focus on the provision of the lease
securing payment by a performance bond, and to ignore the reality that the performance bond was
worthless. To do so would exalt form over substance, something which, in the interest of protecting
the investors of this state, this Court refuses to do. Thus, we find that the second prong of the
Brewer test is met.
C. Initial Value Induced by Promises of Benefits in Excess of Initial Value
-11-
The third prong of the Brewer test is that the investor had a “reasonable understanding that
a valuable benefit of some kind, over and above initial value, will accrue as a result of the operation
of the enterprise.” Brewer, 932 S.W.2d at 11. The QCI promotional materials are relevant to
determining the existence of this element. The materials contain several assurances that participants
will receive a benefit:
I assume you are interested [in this program] because you are fed up with 3% or 4%
returns on your savings; or, maybe you are uncomfortable with risking your money
in the stock market?
Admin. R. at 64.
QCI’s Telephone Equipment Lease Agreement will give you an exceptional 18%
return on your principal. This is what you will earn each year for a five year term.
You will receive a check for $75.00 for 60 consecutive months for each unit
purchased.
Admin. R. at 68 (emphasis in original).
King argues that the third prong of the Brewer test is lacking because QCI’s obligation was
fixed and was not dependent on the enterprise making a profit. However, the Hawaii Market court
rightly noted that it is “irrelevant to the protective policies of the securities laws that the inducements
leading an investor to risk his initial investment are founded on the promises of fixed returns rather
than a share of profits.” Hawaii Market, 485 P.2d at 110. Participants in this sale-leaseback
program clearly expected a benefit as the result of QCI’s successful operation, and the third prong
is thus satisfied.
D. No Right to Exercise Control
The fourth and final prong of the Brewer test requires that the “offeree does not receive the
right to exercise practical and actual control over managerial decisions of the enterprise.” Brewer,
932 S.W.2d at 11. King argues that since the purchaser has the right to terminate the relationship
with QCI, the purchaser has the right to exercise ultimate control over the destiny of his or her
phone. The State calls this right to terminate misleading: the agreement actually requires the
payment of a potentially large early termination fee, and QCI limits the number of early terminations
it must accept in any sixty-day period. Additionally, as the Commissioner points out, the right to
terminate relates to liquidity. The right to terminate certainly is not the equivalent of exercising
practical and actual control over managerial decisions. Participants in this sale-leaseback program
had no right to exercise practical or actual managerial control. Participants never took possession
of the pay telephones, and they had no control over the location or use of the telephones. Thus, we
find that the participants did not receive the right to exercise practical and actual control over
managerial decisions and that the fourth and final prong of the Brewer test is satisfied.
-12-
Conclusion
For the reasons stated herein, we hold that the QCI sale-leaseback program marketed and sold
by the plaintiff was a security under the Tennessee Securities Act of 1980. Therefore, the plaintiff
was offering and selling an unregistered security in violation of Tennessee law. Accordingly, we
reverse the judgment of the Court of Appeals and reinstate the judgment of the Tennessee
Department of Commerce and Insurance. Costs of this appeal are taxed to the appellee, John T.
King, for which execution may issue if necessary.
___________________________________
FRANK F. DROWOTA, III, CHIEF JUSTICE
-13-