St MI v. EPA

United States Court of Appeals FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT Argued November 9, 1999 Decided March 3, 2000 No. 98-1497 State of Michigan, Michigan Department of Environmental Quality and State of West Virginia, Division of Environmental Protection, Petitioners v. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Respondent New England Council, Inc., et al., Intervenors --------- Consolidated with 98-1499, 98-1500, 98-1501, 98-1502, 98-1504, 98-1518, 98-1556, 98-1567, 98-1573, 98-1585, 98-1588, 98-1590, 98-1596, 98-1598, 98-1601, 98-1602, 98-1608, 98-1609, 98-1611, 98-1615, 98-1616, 98-1617, 98-1618, 98-1619, 98-1621, 99-1070, 99-1093 On Petitions for Review of an Order of the Environmental Protection Agency Susan E. Ashbrook, Assistant Attorney General, State of Ohio, James C. Gulick, Special Deputy Attorney, State of North Carolina, Andrea B. Field, Theodore L. Garrett, Todd Palmer, Jonathan S. Martel, William F. Pedersen and Scott H. Segal argued the causes for petitioners. With them on the briefs were Betty D. Montgomery, Attorney General, State of Ohio, Andrew S. Bergman, Assistant Attorney General, Mi- chael F. Easley, Attorney General, State of North Carolina, J. Allen Jernigan, Special Deputy Attorney General, James P. Longest, Jr., and Amy R. Gillespie, Assistant Attorneys General, Bill Pryor, Attorney General, State of Alabama, Tommy E. Bryan, Assitant Attorney General, Jeffrey Modi- sett, Attorney General, State of Indiana, Daniel B. Dovenbar- ger, Chief Counsel, Jennifer M. Granholm, Attorney General, State of Michigan, Thomas Casey, Solicitor General, Alan F. Hoffman, Assistant Attorney General, Charles M. Condon, Attorney General, State of South Carolina, Mark E. Earley, Attorney General, State of Virginia, Roger L. Chaffe, Senior Assistant Attorney General, Stewart T. Leeth, Assistant At- torney General, Thomas H. Zerbe, Senior Counsel, State of West Virginia, Samuel L. Finklea, III, Grant Crandall, Eugene M. Trisko, Norman W. Fichthorn, Mel S. Schulze, David M. Flannery, Kathy Beckett, Harold P. Quinn, Jr., Michael D. Hockley, J. Lister Hubbard, R. Brooke Lawson, III, Robert E. Lannan, II, Terry J. Satterlee, Alok Ahuja, Mark E. Shere, Bryan G. Tabler, Jeffrey L. Landsman, Jennifer S. McGinnity, Howard E. Shapiro, Margaret Clai- borne Campbell, Thomas E. Knauer, David R. Straus, Debo- rah E. Jennings, Julie R. Domike, Patricia T. Barmeyer, Lisa G. Dowden, Brian J. Renaud, Rhonda L. Ross, Jeffrey F. Cherry, Katherine L. Rhyne, John M. Koeppl, Henry J. Handzel, Jeffrey A. Knight, Joan Dreskin, Kevin B. Belford, Pamela A. Lacey, Gene E. Godley, Michael H. Levin and Edmund B. Frost. Earle D. Getchell, Jr., Neal J. Cabral, Christopher D. Man, Jacqueline H. Fine, Jon S. Faletto and John P. Proctor entered appearances. James E. Doyle, Attorney General, State of Wisconsin, and Philip Peterson and Thomas L. Dosch, Assistant Attorneys General, were on the brief for intervenor State of Wisconsin. Louis E. Tosi and William L. Patberg were on the brief for amicus curiae Toledo Metropolitan Area Council of Govern- ments. Charles S. Carter and Deborah Ann Hottel were on the brief of amici curiae South Carolina Chamber of Commerce, Environmental Management Association of South Carolina, South Carolina Manufacturers Alliance, and South Carolina Farm Bureau Federation. Jon M. Lipshultz and Patricia R. McCubbin, Attorneys, U.S. Department of Justice, argued the causes for respon- dent. With them on the brief were Lois J. Schiffer, Assistant Attorney General, and Jan Tierney, Howard Hoffman, Amey W. Marrella and Dwight C. Alpern, Attorneys, U.S. Environ- mental Protection Agency. J. Jared Snyder, Assistant Attorney General, State of New York, argued the cause for state intervenors. With him on the brief were Elliot Spitzer, Attorney General, Peter H. Schiff, Deputy Attorney General, Thomas F. Reilly, Attorney Gener- al, State of Massachusetts, William L. Pardee, Assistant Attorney General, M. Dukes Pepper, Jr., Assistant Counsel, State of Pennsylvania, Sheldon Whitehouse, Attorney Gener- al, State of Rhode Island, Michael Rubin, Environmental Advocate, William H. Sorrell, Attorney General, State of Vermont, Ronald A. Shems, Assistant Attorney General, Jennifer L. Wurzbacher, Assistant Attorney General, State of Maryland, Richard Blumenthal, Attorney General, State of Connecticut, Richard F. Webb, Assistant Attorney General, Andrew Ketterer, Attorney General, State of Maine, Paul Stern, Deputy Attorney General, Philip McLaughlin, Attor- ney General, State of New Hampshire, and Maureen D. Smith, Assistant Attorney General. Kathleen L. Millian argued the cause for intervenor Her Majesty the Queen in Right of Ontario (Province of Ontario, Canada). With her on the brief was Bruce J. Terris. David Hawkins and Raissa Griffin were on the brief for intervenor Natural Resources Defense Council, et al. An- drew P. Caputo entered an appearance. Patrick M. Raher, John G. Roberts, Jr., Catherine E. Stetson, Michael R. Barr, Michael A. Conley, Theresa Fene- lon Falk, John H. Sharp, Paul G. Wallach and Kenneth R. Meade were on the brief for industry intervenors. Richard A. Wegman was on the brief for intervenor the Government of Canada. Before: Williams, Sentelle and Rogers, Circuit Judges. Opinion Per Curiam.* Dissenting opinion filed by Circuit Judge Sentelle. Introduction Under the Clean Air Act the Environmental Protection Agency promulgates national ambient air quality standards ("NAAQS") for air pollutants, and states must then adopt state implementation plans ("SIPs") providing for the imple- mentation, maintenance, and enforcement of the NAAQS; such plans are then submitted to EPA for approval. See Clean Air Act ("CAA") s 110(a)(1), 42 U.S.C. s 7410(a)(1) (1994). Even after a SIP is approved, EPA may at a later time call for SIP revisions if the Administrator finds a SIP __________ * Judge Williams wrote Parts I.B-C and II.B; Judge Sentelle wrote Parts I.A, II.A, II.C, and III.A; Judge Rogers wrote Parts III.B and IV. inadequate to attain or maintain the NAAQS, to meet the dictates of pollutant transport commissions, or "to otherwise comply with any requirement of this chapter." CAA s 110(k)(5), 42 U.S.C. s 7410(k)(5). In October 1998 EPA issued a final rule mandating that 22 states and the District of Columbia revise their SIPs to mitigate the interstate transport of ozone.1 See Finding of Significant Contribution and Rulemaking for Certain States in the Ozone Transport Assessment Group Region for Pur- poses of Reducing Regional Transport of Ozone ("Final Rule"), 63 Fed. Reg. 57,356 (1998). The statutory hook for EPA's action was a 1990 amendment to the Clean Air Act which requires that SIPs contain "adequate provisions" pro- hibiting any source or other type of emissions activity within the State from emitting any air pollutant in amounts which will ... contribute significantly to nonattainment in, or interfere with maintenance by, any other State with respect to any such national primary or secondary am- bient air quality standard. CAA s 110(a)(2)(D)(i)(I), 42 U.S.C. s 7410(a)(2)(D)(i)(I) (1994). EPA uniformly required that each state reduce nitro- gen oxides (NOx--an ozone precursor) by the amount accom- plishable by what EPA dubbed "highly cost-effective con- trols," namely, those controls EPA found capable of removing NOX at a cost of $2000 or less per ton. Numerous petitions for review challenge various aspects of EPA's decision. In Part I we reject the following claims: that EPA could not call for the SIP revisions without convening a transport commission; that EPA failed to undertake a sufficiently state-specific determination of ozone contribution; that EPA unlawfully overrode past precedent regarding "significant" contribution; that EPA's consideration of the cost of NOx __________ 1 The states are Alabama, Connecticut, Delaware, Georgia, Illi- nois, Indiana, Kentucky, Maryland, Massachusetts, Michigan, Mis- souri, North Carolina, New Jersey, New York, Ohio, Pennsylvania, Rhode Island, South Carolina, Tennessee, Virginia, West Virginia, and Wisconsin. reduction violated the statute; that EPA's scheme of uniform controls is arbitrary and capricious; that CAA s 110(a)(2)(D)(i)(I) as construed by EPA violates the nondele- gation doctrine. In Part II we hold that the record does not support including Wisconsin in the SIP call, nor does it support creating NOx budgets based on the entire emissions of Mis- souri or Georgia. We reject the claim that South Carolina was improperly included in the SIP call. In Part III we reject the claim that EPA impermissibly intruded on the statutory rights of states to fashion their SIPs. We also reject the claim that EPA violated the Regu- latory Flexibility Act. In Part IV we reject the claim that EPA arbitrarily revised the definition of a "NOx budget unit." We reject all of the claims raised by the Council of Industrial Boilers save one: we hold that EPA failed to provide adequate notice of a change in the definition of an electric generating unit. We also hold that EPA did not provide adequate notice of a change in the control level assumed for large, stationary internal combustion engines, but we reject the claim that EPA failed to follow its own standards in defining such engines. Finally, we uphold EPA's limits on early reduction credits, and EPA's use of a 15% multiplier for calculating emissions from low mass emission units. We note at the outset that one challenge has been stayed. In 1979, EPA set the acceptable level for ozone in the ambient air at 0.12 parts per million ("ppm"), averaged over intervals of one hour. This standard is commonly known as the "1-hour standard." By 1997, EPA had concluded that the 1-hour standard no longer adequately protected public health. See National Ambient Air Quality Standards for Ozone, 62 Fed. Reg. 38,856 (1997). Pursuant to the agency's statutory mandate to review and revise NAAQS as appropri- ate, 42 U.S.C. s 7409(d)(1), EPA promulgated a new, more stringent "8-hour standard" which limits ozone levels to 0.08 ppm, averaged over an 8-hour period. See 62 Fed. Reg. 38,856 (codified at 40 C.F.R. s 50.10). EPA has undertaken the phasing out of the 1-hour stan- dard on an area-by-area basis, mandating that the standard would no longer apply to an area once it is "determine[d] that the area has air quality meeting the 1-hour standard." 40 C.F.R. s 50.9(b). The call for SIP revisions in question here requires the covered upwind states to submit SIP revisions pursuant to the 8-hour standard even though EPA was not designating any 8-hour nonattainment areas prior to July 1999. See 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,370; Transportation Equity Act for the 21st Century, Pub. L. No. 105-178, s 6103, 112 Stat. 107, 465 (1998) (providing that states submit suggested desig- nations no later than July 1999 and EPA finalize those designations no later than July 2000). EPA maintains that it has the authority to include the 8-hour standard in the current s 110(a)(2)(D)-specific SIP call pursuant to its au- thority under s 110(a)(1). Section 110(a)(1) provides that [e]ach State shall ... adopt and submit to [EPA], within 3 years (or such shorter period as [EPA] may prescribe) after the promulgation of a national primary ambient air quality standard (or any revision thereof) ..., a plan which provides for implementation, maintenance, and enforcement of such primary standard in each air quality control region (or portion thereof) within such State. 42 U.S.C. s 7410(a)(1). State and Industry/Labor petitioners initially attacked the challenged SIP call on the basis that EPA exceeded its statutory authority and acted arbitrarily in basing the SIP call on the 8-hour standard when the agency had not yet designated any areas as being in nonattainment under the new standard. After petitioners' final briefs were submitted, we held in American Trucking Ass'ns, Inc. v. EPA, 175 F.3d 1027, reh'g granted in part, den'd in part 195 F.3d 4 (D.C. Cir. 1999), that the new NAAQS based on the 8-hour stan- dard was derived from a construction of the Clean Air Act that rendered the relevant provision an unconstitutional dele- gation of legislative power and remanded the case to the agency. See id. at 1033-40. Seizing on this holding, petition- ers added in their reply briefs that if this court does not accept the contention in their original briefs as to why EPA impermissibly relied on the 8-hour standard, then we should hold that American Trucking means that EPA cannot rely on the 8-hour standard because it was promulgated in violation of the non-delegation doctrine. Regardless, EPA moved to stay consideration of the issues involving the 8-hour standard because the agency has stayed the 8-hour findings contained in the challenged SIP call. We granted the motion. Because EPA's stay removes the 8-hour findings as a basis for the SIP call, we will resolve only the issues involving the 1-hour standard. I. General Claims A. Transport Commission States have the primary responsibility to attain and main- tain NAAQS within their borders. See CAA s 107(a), 42 U.S.C. s 7407(a). When EPA concludes that an "implemen- tation plan for any area is substantially inadequate to attain or maintain the relevant [NAAQS], to mitigate adequately the interstate pollutant transport described in section [176A] or [184], or to otherwise comply with any requirement of this chapter," the CAA requires EPA to order a state to revise and correct its SIP "as necessary" ("SIP call"). CAA s 110(k)(5), 42 U.S.C. s 7410(k)(5). One such "requirement of this chapter," is the "good neighbor provision" of section 110(a)(2)(D). As amended, section 110(a)(2)(D) requires that a SIP "contain adequate provisions" (i) prohibiting, consistent with the provisions of this sub- chapter, any source or other type of emissions activity within the State from emitting any air pollutant in amounts which will ... contribute significantly to nonat- tainment in, or interfere with maintenance by, any other State with respect to any such national primary or secondary ambient air quality standard ... [and] (ii) insuring compliance with the applicable requirements of sections [126] and [115] ... (relating to interstate and international pollution abatement). 42 U.S.C. s 7410(a)(2)(D) (emphasis added). Section 126(b) enables an individual state or a political subdivision of a state to petition EPA to make a "finding that any major source or group of stationary sources emits or would emit any air pollutant in violation of the prohibition of [s 110(a)(2)(D)(ii)]." 42 U.S.C. s 7426(b). EPA may make or deny such a finding. See id. Section 115 pertains to petitions made by foreign countries. See 42 U.S.C. s 7415. Title I, the subchapter referenced in section 110(a)(2)(D), also includes sections 176A and 184, the provisions referenced in section 110(k)(5). In 1990, Congress added a provision to section 176A stating that EPA "may" establish an interstate air pollution transport region whenever EPA "has reason to believe that the interstate transport of air pollutants from one or more States contributes significantly to a violation of a national ambient air quality standard in one or more other States." 42 U.S.C. s 7506a(a). The section also provides that whenever EPA "establishes a transport region ... [EPA] shall establish a transport commission." 42 U.S.C. s 7506a(b)(1). Among other things, a section 176A commis- sion is to assess the interstate transport situation in the relevant transport region, assess interstate pollution mitiga- tion strategies, and recommend to EPA measures necessary "to ensure that the plans for the relevant States meet the requirements of [section 110(a)(2)(D)]." 42 U.S.C. s 7506a(b)(2). In addition, section 176A permits a transport commission to request that EPA "issue a finding under [section 110(k)(5)] ... that the implementation plan for one or more of the States in the transport region is substantially inadequate to meet [section 110(a)(2)(D) requirements]." 42 U.S.C. s 7506a(c). After public comment, EPA has the au- thority to approve, approve in part, or disapprove such a request. See id. In part, section 184, an ozone-specific provision, establishes an ozone transport region in the northeast ("NOTR") and sets the deadline for convening the transport commission required as a result of NOTR's establishment. See 42 U.S.C. s 7511c(a). The section also requires that "[i]n accordance with [section 110] ... each State included [or subsequently included] within a transport region established for ozone shall submit a State implementation plan or revision" regarding vehicle inspection programs and volatile organic compounds control technology. 42 U.S.C. s 7511c(b). In addition, section 184 contains provisions giving states within an established transport region the opportunity to use their section 176A-established transport commission to help develop addi- tional ozone control measures. See 42 U.S.C. s 7511c(c). Efforts to control states' upwind contributions to ozone pollution continued to fall short during the early 1990s. In 1995, upon the recommendation of the Environmental Council of the States, thirty-seven states and representatives from EPA, industry, and environmental groups formed a national work-group called the Ozone Transport Assessment Group ("OTAG") to study and devise solutions to the interstate ozone transport problem. See 62 Fed. Reg. 60,318, at 60,319; EPA, Ozone Transport Assessment Group Executive Report, EPA Document No. A 95-56, Doc. No. II-G-05 ("Executive Report") at ii. More specifically, OTAG's purpose was to "identify and recommend a strategy to reduce transported ozone and its precursors, which, in combination with other measures, will enable attainment and maintenance of the ozone standard in the OTAG region." Executive Report at ii. OTAG concluded that upwind states needed to reduce NOx emissions in order to address the transport problem. Howev- er, the OTAG members could not agree on specific control measure recommendations. See 62 Fed. Reg. at 60,320. In response to OTAG's efforts, EPA engaged in further analysis and devised the SIP call challenged here. Industry/Labor petitioners argue that the CAA required EPA to convene a transport commission pursuant to sections 176A/184 prior to issuing the challenged SIP call. EPA concedes that OTAG was not a statutorily-mandated 176A/184 transport commission as defined in the CAA. If a transport commission is required, EPA would be bound by statute to follow certain procedures in establishing and executing its commission obligation. However, we hold that the CAA does not require EPA to establish such a commission. Industry/Labor petitioners contend that the reference to the transport commission provisions in section 110(k)(5) and the mandate of section 110(a)(2)(D) that SIP requirements be consistent with Title I provisions obligated EPA, prior to issuing the SIP call, to create a transport commission guided by the terms in sections 176A and 184 of the statute. Industry/Labor petitioners also note that sections 176A and 184 reference both sections 110(a)(2)(D) and 110(k)(5). See 42 U.S.C. ss 7506a(b)(2), (c), 7511c(c)(5). From this hodgepodge of largely unrelated cross-references, Industry/Labor peti- tioners argue that EPA can only issue a section 110(k)(5) SIP call to enforce section 110(a)(2)(D)'s requirement after form- ing a 176A/184 transport commission. We disagree. As a threshold matter, subsections 176A(a) and (b)(1) make clear that EPA must establish a transport commission if the agency exercises its discretion to create a transport region pursuant to section 176A(a). See 42 U.S.C. ss 7506a(a), (b)(1). However, EPA can address interstate transport apart from convening a 176A/184 transport commission as subsec- tion (a) provides that EPA "may" establish a transport region and subsection (b)(1) only requires a transport commission upon the establishment of a transport region because "[w]henever the Administrator establishes a transport region under subsection (a) ..., the Administrator shall establish a transport commission." Moreover, the relevant section 184 requirements apply to states within established transport regions. See 42 U.S.C. s 7511c(a)-(c). Thus, Industry/Labor petitioners cannot reason around the determinative statutory language contained in section 176A. Statutory construction is not an exercise in picking apart a complex statute and piecing the parts back togther in a manner to effect a particular end. Ideally, a statute's directive concerning a certain issue will be plain and clear. Just so here. B. State-Specific Analysis Section 110(a)(2)(D)(I)(i) requires that the relevant offend- ing emissions be "emissions activity within the State." Sever- al petitioners charge that EPA did not sufficiently analyze each particular state in determining which states contributed unduly to ozone downwind. In issuing its Notice of Proposed Rulemaking ("NPRM"), EPA relied on data collected from OTAG. The data were multi-state and regional in nature and were framed as a model of how ozone was transported downwind from 12 different regions that covered the eastern half of the United States. See Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,382. The OTAG regions do not track state boundaries, so several states are split between regions. EPA also relied upon the NOx emis- sions of the individual states. See id. at 57,383-84. A potential shortcoming of the NPRM's approach was that it was too multi-state in nature. EPA knew how much NOx each state was emitting, but a state's emissions as a share of total emissions do not necessarily correspond proportionately to its share in the creation of ozone in downwind states. OTAG's multi-state modeling of such downwind transporta- tion painted with a rather broad brush. We need not pass judgment on whether the evidence and approach of the NPRM would have supported the final rule. After receiving comments regarding the insufficiently state- specific analysis of the NPRM, EPA performed state-specific modeling. Id. at 57,384. According to EPA, this confirmed the results of the regional modeling. Id. The two types of state-specific modeling go by the names UAM-V and CAMx. In the UAM-V approach, the research- ers model an affected downwind area to establish a base case, and then "zero-out" a particular source state. Thus with UAM-V it can be estimated what ozone concentrations would be like if a particular state contributed no ozone or ozone precursors. The CAMx modeling, on the other hand, is a source apportionment analysis which tracks modeled ozone from its precursors (NOx and volatile organic compounds (VOCs)) through the formation of ozone and subsequent migration. Whereas UAM-V tells modelers how much ozone is missing when one state is zeroed out, CAMx models an ozone concentration and provides apportionment, i.e., who sent what. An advantage of the CAMx model used by EPA was that, unlike the UAM-V modeling, with CAMx EPA could isolate man-made emissions, or ozone creation based on reactions between man-made and biogenic emissions. UAM-V modeling was less discriminating. Petitioners really do nothing more than quibble with the state-specific modeling. For example, Industry/Labor peti- tioners argue that zero-out modeling is inappropriate because it models an impossible scenario--the elimination of all man- made NOx emissions; but they do not suggest how much this characteristic is likely to distort the results. State petitioners charge that sometimes the results of the two models were inconsistent, with, for example, the CAMx showing a larger migration of ozone from a state than the UAM-V showed for all man-made NOx in that state. EPA itself noted this infrequent inconsistency. See id. at 57,385. Neither criticism affords ground for non-expert judges to find a material likelihood of serious error. See Appalachian Power Co. v. EPA, 135 F.3d 791, 802 (D.C. Cir. 1998). Petitioners complain that EPA did not provide the data sooner. EPA made the new modeling available on the Inter- net six weeks prior to the final rule, published its availability in the Federal Register a month before the final rule, and during that time received and responded to questions and comments regarding the modeling. Other than what we have already mentioned, petitioners have evidently not been able to identify further flaws in the modeling used, and thus have failed to show any prejudice from EPA's timetable. Personal Watercraft Indus. Ass'n v. Department of Commerce, 48 F.3d 540, 544 (D.C. Cir. 1995). C. Determining "Significant" Contribution Section 110(a)(2)(D)(i)(I) applies only to states that "con- tribute significantly" to nonattainment in a downwind state. Petitioners make essentially four arguments challenging EPA's determination of "significance": (1) EPA acted con- trary to precedent; (2) EPA considered forbidden factors, namely, costs of reduction; (3) EPA irrationally imposed uniform NOx controls on the states; (4) EPA's determination was so devoid of intelligible principles as to violate the nondelegation doctrine. 1. Past Precedent Before the 1990 amendments to the Clean Air Act, s 110(a)(2)(E)(I) directed the EPA to insist on SIP provisions adequate to prevent sources within a state from emitting air pollution that would "prevent attainment or maintenance [of primary or secondary standards] by any other State." 42 U.S.C. s 7410(a)(2)(E) (1982) (emphasis added). In a number of decisions EPA found, with approval of the courts, that various emissions of a particular state, having a proportionate impact on some downwind state greater than the impacts involved here, did not meet that standard. See New York v. EPA, 852 F.2d 574 (D.C. Cir. 1988); Air Pollution Control Dist. of Jefferson County v. EPA, 739 F.2d 1071 (6th Cir. 1984); New York v. EPA, 716 F.2d 440 (7th Cir. 1983); New York v. EPA, 710 F.2d 1200 (6th Cir. 1983); Connecticut v. EPA, 696 F.2d 147 (2d Cir. 1982). According to the states, these decisions, and what they claim to be Congress's implicit endorsement in the 1990 amendments, bar EPA from regard- ing the ozone emissions here as "significant" within the meaning of s 110(a)(2)(D)(i)(I). Thus the states would equate the old standard--"prevent attainment"--with the new stan- dard: "contribute significantly to nonattainment." Nothing in the text of the new section or any other provision of the statute spells out a criterion for classifying "emissions activity" as "significant." Nor did EPA, under the then-existing provision, bind itself to any criterion. Further, given EPA's finding as to the cumulative effects of the pollutants that generate ozone, EPA might well be able to distinguish this case from the sulfur dioxide cases that the states have cited. See 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,359 ("The chemical reactions that create ozone take place while the pollutants are being blown through the air by the wind, which means that ozone can be more severe many miles away from the source of emissions than it is at the source."). But the states point to nothing suggesting any prior adoption by EPA of any binding concept of how much was too much, so the claim falls short at the threshold. 2. Consideration of costs Petitioners claim s 110(a)(2)(D)(i)(I) does not permit EPA to take into consideration the cost of reducing ozone. The full section provides that SIPs must contain provisions ade- quately prohibiting any source or other type of emissions activity within the State from emitting any air pollutant in amounts which will ... contribute significantly to nonattainment in, or interfere with maintenance by, any other State with respect to any such national primary or secondary am- bient air quality standard. 42 U.S.C. s 7410(a)(2)(D)(i)(I) (emphasis added). Before reviewing the petitioners' attacks we must first describe how EPA went about the business at hand. It first determined that 23 jurisdictions are "significant" contributors to downwind nonattainment. 63 Fed. Reg. 57,398. In mak- ing this listing EPA drew lines based on the magnitude, frequency, and relative amount of each state's ozone contribu- tion to a nonattainment area. For example, in one calculation it looked at the number of NOx parts per billion ("ppb") that a candidate state's emissions made to exceedances in specific downwind locations (examined as a proportion of those excee- dances). Indiana was found to contribute at least 2 ppb to 4% of the 1-hour ozone exceedances in New York City, and was deemed a "significant contributor" to nonattainment there. On the other hand, Alabama, Georgia, Massachusetts, Missouri, South Carolina, Tennessee, and Wisconsin were not deemed "significant contributors" to New York City nonat- tainment because none of these states ever contributed more than 2 ppb to a 1-hour exceedance in that area. Although EPA looked at other measures, e.g., the percentage contribu- tion of a state's emissions to total concentrations in a specified area, no one quarrels either with its use of multiple measures, or with the way it drew the line at this stage. Although the dividing line was a very low threshold of contribution, in the end EPA's rule called for termination of only a subset of each state's contribution. EPA decided that the 23 "significant contributors" need only reduce their ozone by the amount achievable with "highly cost-effective con- trols." 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,403. Thus, once a state had been nominally marked a "significant contributor," it could satisfy the statute, i.e., reduce its contribution to a point where it would not be "significant" within the meaning of s 110(a)(2)(D)(i)(I), by cutting back the amount that could be eliminated with "highly cost-effective controls." EPA's de- sign was to have a lot of states make what it considered modest NOx reductions, uniformly limited to ones that could be achieved (in EPA's estimate) for less than $2000 a ton. As a result, naturally, the ultimate line of "significance," whether measured in volume of NOx emitted or arriving in nonattain- ment areas, would vary from state to state depending on variations in cutback costs. State and Industry/Labor petitioners argue that this ap- proach runs afoul of s 110(a)(2)(D), which they read as pro- hibiting any consideration of costs or cost-effectiveness in determining what contributions are "significant." So far as appears, none of the states proposes that EPA, if reversed, must require complete extirpation of their NOx emissions. Rather, the gamble--at least of the small contributors--is evidently that if EPA were barred from considering costs, it would never have included such states. Because the attacks from the states and Industry/Labor are somewhat dissimilar and have shifted back-and-forth between the opening briefs, reply briefs, and oral argument, a summary of the relevant differences and vacillations is in order. We note that no party makes any claim that EPA was either confined to adopting rules whose benefits exceeded their costs, or permit- ted to use that criterion in selecting its final rule.2 Nor has it __________ 2 Indeed, accepting EPA's belief that ozone cannot be held re- sponsible for mortality effects, see Proposed Rule, 62 Fed. Reg. at 60,321 (not listing death as a health effect of groundlevel ozone); compare Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,359 (listing "[p]ossible long- been argued that the term "significant" required consider- ation of costs. State petitioners initially argued that it was "arbitrary and unlawful" for EPA to make cost effectiveness a "controlling factor" or "linchpin" in the determination of significant contri- bution under s 110(a)(2)(D). Thus EPA's error, as the states would have it, was in considering costs too much: "Petitioning States do not claim that there is no role for cost consider- ations; Petitioning States simply stress that EPA must estab- lish a definition of significance that is dominated by air quality factors, as air quality is the sole factor mentioned in the statute." Reply Br. of Petitioning States at 4. In support of this position, State petitioners cited our en banc decision in Natural Resources Defense Council v. EPA, 824 F.2d 1146, 1163 (D.C. Cir. 1987) (en banc), where we held that a statutory mandate for EPA to set a standard with an "ample margin of safety to protect the public health" did not preclude the consideration of costs and technological feasibili- ty, but that these concerns could not be the "primary consid- eration." At oral argument, counsel for the states abandoned this position and decided that the statute flatly prohibits EPA from considering costs at all. Transcript of Oral Argument at 14-17. Indeed, counsel eventually went so far as to claim that if faced with two states, one of which could eliminate all relevant emissions at a trivial cost, while the other could eliminate none at a cost of less than $5000 a ton, EPA must mandate the same cutback for each. Id. at 16-17. __________ term damage to the lungs or even premature death" as health effects), and mainly using EPA data, some outside observers have calculated the benefit per ton of NOx reduction as ranging from a high of $750 per ton (for mobile sources in certain areas) to a low of negative $6 per ton (for other mobile sources). Alan Krupnick & Virginia McConnell, "Cost-Effective NOx control in the Eastern U.S." (Draft July 1999) (Table 4); see Krupnick & Anderson, A Dilemma Downwind, 137 Resources for the Future 5, 7 (1999) ("If one assumes that ozone does not cause deaths, the EPA's proposal is much too restrictive, incurring costs far out of proportion with the benefits it would bring."). We should note here that the consequence of this position is not so extreme as it sounds. EPA's rule allows ton-for-ton emissions trading between firms based on allowances deter- mined by each state. See 63 Fed. Reg. 57,456. Obviously the firms with the highest emission reduction costs will, if permit- ted by their states, buy up pollution allowances from firms that are granted allowances because they have over- controlled for NOx--firms, obviously, with low reduction costs. If transaction costs were zero, the only effect of the initial assignment of cutbacks would be distributional: firms would make only the cheaper cutbacks, but firms with high emission-reduction costs would buy allowances from those with low costs and thereby transfer wealth to them. See Ronald H. Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J. L. & Econ. 1 (1960). But transaction costs notoriously are not zero;3 so the likely effect of the proposed statutory interpretation would be that any aggregate cutback would be achieved at considerably higher cost than under EPA's reading of s 110(a)(2)(D)(i)(I), with absolutely no offsetting environmen- tal benefit to the public. Of course we are able to assume the existence of EPA's allowance trading program only because no one has challenged its adoption. As the program seems to have no rationale other than cost reduction, see 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,457, it would presumably be invalid under petitioners' proposed reading of s 110(a)(2)(D)(i)(I), in which case the states' position really is as extreme as it sounds. Returning to the positions of the parties, we find Indus- try/Labor engaging in a migration comparable to that of the states, though in the opposite direction. In its opening and reply brief Industry/Labor argued that "s 110(a)(2)(D) re- quires consideration of only air quality impacts in determin- ing the significance of any contribution." However, at oral argument Industry/Labor offered a construction of the stat- ute that seemed to restore to EPA via s 110(k)(5) what it would take away via s 110(a)(2)(D). Industry/Labor claimed __________ 3 A glance at EPA's regulations for allowance trading will con- vince any doubter that transaction costs can safely be expected to be substantial. See 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,457-75. that costs could be considered when EPA determines if a SIP is "adequate" under s 110(k)(5). Transcript of Oral Argu- ment at 28. The states actually offered this same reading of s 110(k)(5) in their reply brief (back when they thought EPA could consider costs) but appeared to abandon it at oral argument in favor of a flat prohibition on EPA cost consider- ations. The argument that costs may be considered under s 110(k)(5) seems to concede that the structure of the statu- tory scheme manifests no intention to bar the consideration of costs. And so we are indeed presented with the question whether s 110(a)(2)(D) bars consideration of costs, but it is presented to us with the caveat that costs can be considered later on in the process, and accompanied by a false start by the states, who initially said that EPA could consider costs, just not too much. Against this backdrop, it would be at the very least ironic for us to say there is "clear congressional intent to preclude consideration of cost" under s 110(a)(2)(D). See Natural Resources Defense Council v. EPA, 824 F.2d 1146, 1163 (D.C. Cir. 1987) (en banc). For convenience we repeat the statutory language. Section 110(a)(2)(D)(i)(I) provides that SIPs must contain provisions adequately prohibiting any source or other type of emissions activity within the State from emitting any air pollutant in amounts which will ... contribute significantly to nonattainment in, or interfere with maintenance by, any other State with respect to any such national primary or secondary am- bient air quality standard. 42 U.S.C. s 7410(a)(2)(D)(i)(I) (emphasis added). By its terms the statute is focused on "amounts" of "emissions activity" that "contribute significantly to nonattainment." The fundamental dispute is over the clarity of the phrase "contribute significantly." Must EPA simply pick some flat "amount" of contribution, based exclusively on health con- cerns, such that any excess would put a state in the forbidden zone of "significance"?4 Or was it permissible for EPA to consider differences in cutback costs, so that, after reduction of all that could be cost-effectively eliminated, any remaining "contribution" would not be considered "significant"? In deciding on the permissible ceiling, EPA used "significant" in the second way. The term "significant" does not in itself convey a thought that significance should be measured in only one dimension-- here, in the petitioners' view, health alone. Indeed, "signifi- cant" is a very odd choice to express unidimensionality; consider the phrase "significant other." In some contexts, "significant" begs a consideration of costs. In finding a threshold requirement of "significant risk" in s 3(8) of the Occupational Health and Safety Act, 29 U.S.C. s 652(8), a plurality of the Supreme Court understood a "significant" risk as something more than a "mathematical straitjacket," and held that "[s]ome risks are plainly acceptable and others are plainly unacceptable." Industrial Union Dept., AFL-CIO v. American Petroleum Institute ("Benzene"), 448 U.S. 607, 655 (1980) (plurality opinion). The plurality withheld judgment on whether the Act required a "reasonable correlation be- tween costs and benefits," id. at 615, but the upshot of inserting the adjective "significant" was a consideration of which risks are worth the cost of elimination. OSHA has since interpreted s 3(8) and regulation of "significant risk" to require "cost-effective protective measures" and set stan- dards with an eye toward "the costs of safety standards [being] reasonably related to their benefits." See Interna- tional Union v. OSHA (Lockout/Tagout II), 37 F.3d 665, 668- 69 (D.C. Cir. 1994) (quoting OSHA's final rule). OSHA's reaction to the term "significant" seems to confirm what some commentators have asked rhetorically: "[C]an an agency sensibly decide whether a risk is 'significant' without also examining the cost of eliminating it?" Stephen G. Breyer, __________ 4 We deal below with a related question: Did EPA act irrationally in setting the level of significance without regard for varying levels of downwind impact? See part I.C.3 below. Richard B. Stewart, Cass R. Sunstein & Matthew L. Spitzer, Administrative Law and Regulatory Policy 65 (4th ed. 1999). Petitioners conspicuously fail to describe the intellectual process by which EPA would determine "significance" if it may consider only health. EPA has determined that ozone has some adverse health effects--however slight--at every level. See National Ambient Air Quality Standards for Ozone, 62 Fed. Reg. 38,856 (1997). Without consideration of cost it is hard to see why any ozone-creating emissions should not be regarded as fatally "significant" under s 110(a)(2)(D)(i)(I). Perhaps EPA might (under such a rule) let the upwind states off at the stringency level of the programs imposed on non-attainment areas, but petitioners do not explain how "significance" can exclude cost but admit equity. Although the ambiguity of the word "significant" and the implications of a health-only reading are potentially fatal flaws in petitioners' theory (aside from their own inability to discern the "plain language" consistently), the most formida- ble obstacle is the settled law of this circuit. It is only where there is "clear congressional intent to preclude consideration of cost" that we find agencies barred from considering costs. NRDC, 824 F.2d at 1163; see also George E. Warren Corp. v. EPA, 159 F.3d 616, 622-24 (D.C. Cir. 1998), reh'g granted, 164 F.3d 676 (D.C. Cir. 1999); Grand Canyon Air Tour Coalition v. FAA, 154 F.3d 455, 475 (D.C. Cir. 1998), cert. denied, 119 S. Ct. 2046 (1999); NRDC v. EPA, 937 F.2d 641, 643-46 (D.C. Cir. 1991); cf. International Bhd. of Teamsters v. United States, 735 F.2d 1525, 1528-29 (D.C. Cir. 1984) (construing mandate to adopt "reasonable requirements" for safety as allowing consideration of cost). In NRDC we considered s 112 of the Clean Air Act, requiring EPA to set an air quality standard for hazardous pollutants with an "ample margin of safety" to protect the public health. We held that this phrase did not preclude a consideration of costs. 824 F.2d at 1155, 1163. In George E. Warren Corp. we acknowledged that the statutory scheme for the reformulated gasoline program had the "overall goal" of improving air quality and "reducing air pollution." 159 F.3d at 622. But because there was nothing "in the text or structure of the statute to indicate that the Congress intend- ed to preclude the EPA from considering the effects a proposed rule might have upon the price and supply of gasoline," id. at 623, we found no such preclusion even though the provision at issue contained no allusion whatever to such effects. Similarly, in Grand Canyon Air Tour the statute required the FAA to devise a plan for "substantial restoration of the natural quiet" in the Grand Canyon area, but we found nothing impermissible in the FAA's consideration of costs to the air tourism industry in deciding how "substantial" that restoration must be. 154 F.3d at 475. In NRDC v. EPA we considered whether EPA permissibly used cost-benefit analy- sis in refusing to classify a particular polluting source as "major." The petitioners argued that cost considerations were precluded, and we stated: "[W]hile the statutory lan- guage and legislative history do not bar petitioners' construc- tion, they provide little support and no necessity for it." 937 F.2d at 645. We affirmed EPA's use of cost-benefit analysis. These cases are unexceptional in their general view that preclusion of cost consideration requires a rather express congressional direction. See Edward W. Warren & Gary E. Marchant, "More Good Than Harm": A First Principle for Environmental Agencies and Reviewing Courts, 20 Ecology L.Q. 379, 421 (1993) ("The need to compare benefits and costs has long played a role in judicial review of agency actions regulating health and safety risks."); Cass R. Sunstein, Inter- preting Statutes in the Regulatory State, 103 Harv. L. Rev. 405, 487 (1989) (suggesting an "interpretive principle" drawn from case law, including NRDC v. EPA, 824 F.2d 1146, that reviewing courts will read statutes as authorizing regulations with benefits at least "roughly commensurate with their costs, unless there is a clear legislative statement to the contrary"). Three of the cases, moreover--the two NRDC cases and Grand Canyon--, involve statutory language with just the same structure as here. A mandate directed to some envi- ronmental benefit is phrased in general quantitative terms ("ample margin of safety," "substantial restoration," and "ma- jor"), and contains not a word alluding to non-health trade- offs; in each case we found that in making its judgments of degree the agency was free to consider the costs of demand- ing higher levels of environmental benefit. So too here. Petitioners point to no evidence of the requisite "clear congressional intent to preclude consideration of cost." NRDC, 824 F.2d at 1163. The text, we have already seen, works no such preclusion. As for the statutory structure, petitioners willingly concede that costs may be considered under s 110(k)(5) in determining the adequacy of a state plan. Why would a Congress intent on precluding cost consider- ations allow such an escape hatch? The petitioners cite no legislative history suggesting that cost considerations should be barred. In sum, there is nothing in the text, structure, or history of s 110(a)(2)(D) that bars EPA from considering cost in its application. 3. Uniform Controls As we have seen, EPA required that all of the covered jurisdictions, regardless of amount of contribution, reduce their NOx by an amount achievable with "highly cost-effective controls." Petitioners claim that EPA's uniform control strategy is irrational in two distinct ways. First, they ob- serve that where two states differ considerably in the amount of their respective NOx contributions to downwind nonattain- ment, under the EPA rule even the small contributors must make reductions equivalent to those achievable by highly cost-effective measures. This of course flows ineluctably from the EPA's decision to draw the "significant contribu- tion" line on a basis of cost differentials. Our upholding of that decision logically entails upholding this consequence. The second objection is that because of distance and the vagaries of pollutant migration and ozone formation, a mole- cule of NOx emitted in Indiana (for example) may cause far less adverse health impact than a molecule emitted in eastern Pennsylvania. EPA acknowledges that "[s]ources that are closer to the nonattainment area tend to have much larger effects on air quality than sources that are far away." 63 Fed. Reg. at 25,919. While EPA's cost-effectiveness standard and emissions trading seem to mean that EPA will secure the resulting aggregate NOx reduction at roughly the lowest possible cost, they do not necessarily mean that it will have secured the resulting aggregate health benefits at the lowest cost. Petitioners ask, in effect, why EPA did not, by one means or another (e.g., in the emissions trading system), make reductions from sources near the nonattainment areas (or otherwise more damaging, molecule for molecule) more valuable than ones from distant sources? EPA considered this approach, modeling the efficacy of regional alternatives compared to its uniform strategy. See Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,423. Its researchers found that non-uniform regional approaches by comparison did not "provide either a significant improvement in air quality or a substantial reduction in cost." Id. The complaining states offer no material critique of EPA's methodology in reaching this answer, which in fact some independent investigators have confirmed. See Krupnick & Anderson, A Dilemma Downwind, 137 Resources for the Future 5, 6 (1999) ("[Even with] spatial differences, when viewed across the entire study region, RFF concluded that there was no clear benefit to an exposure-based trading system, compared with simple ton- for-ton NOx trading. Public health benefits would be approx- imately the same, and there would be no significant difference in costs to the utilities."). We have no basis to upset EPA's judgment. 4. Nondelegation In their opening brief and more prominently in their reply brief, state petitioners argue that EPA has not determined "significant contribution" based on any intelligible principles. Petitioners rely heavily on our decision in American Truck- ing Ass'ns, Inc. v. EPA, 175 F.3d 1027, reh'g granted in part, den'd in part 195 F.3d 4 (D.C. Cir. 1999), essentially arguing that nothing about EPA's analysis explains how much of a NOx contribution was too much (i.e., worthy of a SIP call). We must recognize here that EPA's cost-effectiveness cri- terion is a radically incomplete line-drawing device. EPA has effectively ruled that each affected state must get down to the NOx emissions levels that would prevail if it removed all NOx emissions costing $2000/ton or less to remove. This satisfies its "cost-effectiveness" criterion because (if states also seek to minimize costs subject to the EPA's constraint) only these relatively low-cost tons will be removed. But while EPA indicates that it rested the $2000/ton figure on "NOx emis- sions controls that are available and of comparable cost to other recently undertaken or planned NOx measures," Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,400, it neither rests that benchmark on anything in the language or function of s 110(a)(2)(D)(i)(I), nor otherwise explains why the resulting cut-off point repre- sents the right degree of "cost-effectiveness" (i.e., why "high- ly cost-effective" should be at that "height"). Accordingly, we must read EPA as having understood that its selection of the cut-off point was essentially unbounded. But petitioners have ignored a limit to the nondelegation doctrine that we relied on in American Trucking and even more emphatically in its immediate precursor, International Union, UAW v. OSHA ("Lockout/Tagout I"), 938 F.2d 1310 (D.C. Cir. 1991). There we noted that the scope of the agency's "claimed power to roam" was "immense, encompass- ing all American enterprise." Id. at 1317. Quoting verbatim from Synar v. United States, 626 F. Supp. 1374, 1383 (D.D.C. 1986) (three-judge panel), aff'd sub nom. Bowsher v. Synar, 478 U.S. 714 (1986), we said, "When the scope increases to immense proportions, as in [A.L.A. Schecter Poultry Corp. v. United States, 295 U.S. 495 (1935)], the standards must be correspondingly more precise." Lockout/Tagout I, 938 F.2d at 1317. We noted that a mass of cases in courts had upheld delegations of effectively standardless discretion, and distin- guished them precisely on the ground of the narrower scope within which the agencies could deploy that discretion. Id. American Trucking, perhaps too succinctly for petitioners to notice, incorporated the Lockout/Tagout I discussion of the point. American Trucking, 175 F.3d at 1037. Nominally, of course, s 110(a)(2)(D)(i)(I) encompasses "all American enterprise." But as a practical matter EPA must make a number of threshold determinations that in practice appear to have confined the statute to a modest role. Before assessing "significance," EPA must find (1) emissions activity within a state; (2) show with modeling or other evidence that such emissions are migrating into other states; and (3) show that the emissions are contributing to nonattainment. We do not mean to minimize the scope of EPA's action in the present case. Nearly half of the nation is affected and control costs will be substantial. And it may ultimately prove that the dam constituted by these criteria will burst, subject- ing "all American industry" to EPA's s 110(a)(2)(D)(i)(I) dis- cretion. But in practice, so far, these threshold criteria appear to have so limited EPA's activity under the section as to make the rule in question here the sole example of s 110(a)(2)(D)(i)(I) rulemaking. Accordingly, the grounds on which we remanded in Lockout-Tagout I and American Trucking for confining agency constructions are absent here. II. Inclusion of Specific States A. Wisconsin Wisconsin industry petitioners separately challenge Wis- consin's inclusion in the SIP call. The Wisconsin petitioners argue that the emissions from the state do not contribute significantly to nonattainment in any other state. Section 110(a)(2)(D)(i)(I) requires that a state "contribute significantly to nonattainment in ... any other State" in order to be included in the challenged SIP call. 42 U.S.C. s 7410(a)(2)(D)(i)(I) (emphasis added). As explained below, EPA erroneously included Wisconsin in the SIP call because EPA failed to explain how Wisconsin contributes to nonattain- ment in any other state. EPA contends that Wisconsin contributes significantly to other states' nonattainment because the state significantly contributes ozone over the Lake Michigan region. Despite EPA's Lake Michigan concerns, the agency does not show on the record that Wisconsin's ozone contribution affects any onshore state nonattainment. At oral argument, counsel for EPA conceded that "[t]he part that's missing [from the record] is a thorough explanation to support our modeling data and things of that nature between the Lake Michigan receptor area and the onshore states." Oral Arg. Tr. at 107. When asked for more, counsel could only respond that "the best evidence ... is simply the narrative statements in the [final rule's] preambles.... There's nothing else there." Id. Because EPA conceded at oral argument that it has no record evidence directly linking Wisconsin's ozone contribution over Lake Michigan to nonattainment in any state and because EPA must "demonstrate[ ] a reasonable connection between the facts on the record and its decision" made pursuant to its statutory authority, Ethyl Corp. v. EPA, 51 F.3d 1053, 1064 (D.C. Cir. 1995), we hold that EPA acted unlawfully by including Wisconsin in a SIP call limited by statute to states contributing significantly to nonattainment in any other state and therefore set aside Wisconsin's inclusion in the SIP call. See 5 U.S.C. s 706(2)(A), (C) (1994) ("The reviewing court shall ... hold unlawful and set aside agency action ... found to be ... arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of discretion, or otherwise not accordance with law [or] in excess of statutory jurisdiction, authority, or limitations, or short of statutory right."). B. Missouri and Georgia Missouri and Georgia were on the geographical perimeter of EPA's SIP call. No state west of Missouri was included, nor were the two states directly to its north (Iowa and Minnesota) and south (Arkansas). Georgia was a bit more in the thick of things, surrounded on three sides by included states--Alabama, Tennessee, North Carolina, and South Car- olina; but the southern portion of Georgia borders the ex- cluded state of Florida. Industrial petitioners within Mis- souri and Georgia challenge EPA's decision to calculate NOx budgets for these two states based on the entirety of NOx emissions in each state. Petitioners argue that there is record support only for the proposition that emissions from, roughly speaking, the eastern half of Missouri and the north- ern two-thirds of Georgia "contribute" to downwind concen- trations; accordingly, they say, the NOx budgets for Missouri and Georgia should be based solely on those emissions. We must here explain how EPA calculated NOx budgets. It projected the total amount of NOx emissions that sources in a state would emit in the year 2007, in light of expected growth and other controls required by the CAA. EPA then projected total NOx emissions if "highly cost-effective con- trols" were implemented. The resulting calculation became the state's NOx budget, with the difference between the base case and the controlled case being the "significant" contribu- tion discussed above. Obviously a state's NOx budget will vary depending on whether EPA considers all of the NOx emissions in the state, or instead considers only emissions located in a smaller portion of the state (assuming emissions are dispersed throughout the state, which is the case here and without which the issue would be immaterial, as nonexis- tent emissions need not be controlled). For Missouri and Georgia, as for all other included states, NOx budgets were calculated using all NOx emissions in the state. The challenge basically stems from the character of OTAG's modeling, and its resulting recommendations to EPA. OTAG's ozone transport model used grids drawn across most of the eastern half of the United States. The first grid was the most precise, with grid cells of 12 kilometers squared (244 square kilometers)--the "fine grid." A second grid extended beyond the perimeter of the fine grid and had cells of 36 kilometers squared resolution--the "coarse grid." For a variety of reasons to be discussed shortly, the fine grid did not track state boundaries, and Missouri and Georgia were among several states that were split between the fine and coarse grids. OTAG then ran modeling for both grids, but in the final analysis did not find emissions from the coarse grid worthy of special concern. OTAG's executive summary stat- ed: "[T]he focus on ozone air quality impacts in the fine grid raised questions about the need for controls in the coarse grid. The recommendations adopted by the Policy Group recognize that the OTAG analyses demonstrated that trans- port impacts of the coarse grid areas on the fine grid are minimal and therefore, do not include the coarse grid areas for recommended control measures other than those that would be applied nationally." Petitioners argue that EPA should base NOx budgets for Missouri and Georgia only on portions of these states within the fine grid. EPA offers three reasons for including the entire states of Missouri and Georgia: (1) The division of individual States by OTAG was based, in part, on computational limitations in OTAG's modeling analyses; (2) the additional upwind emissions from full, as opposed to partial, States would provide additional benefit to downwind nonattainment areas; and, (3) State- wide emissions budgets create fewer administrative diffi- culties than a partial-State budget. Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,424. We review deferentially, searching for the reasonableness of EPA's action, Appala- chian Power, 135 F.3d at 802, whether that be EPA's inter- pretation of the statute, see Chevron, 467 U.S. at 842-43, or EPA's explanation for its policy choice, see Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Ass'n v. State Farm Mutual Auto. Ins. Co., 463 U.S. 29, 43 (1983). The two inquiries can and do overlap. See Animal Legal Defense Fund v. Glickman, No. 97-5009, slip op. at 9 (D.C. Cir. Feb. 1, 2000). On its face the statute neither mandates nor prohibits an all-or-nothing statewide perspective. It directs EPA to make sure that SIPs (which of course are state plans) adequately prohibit "any source or other type of emissions activity within the State from emitting" in excess of the substantive limit. The critical issue is whether the targeted "source" or "emis- sions activity" "contribute[s] significantly to nonattainment" in another state. EPA's first argument is that the fine grid split Missouri and Georgia in part because of computer limitations--every extension of the fine grid modeling was costly in terms of both computer memory and data collection. Document No. II-A-14, Draft OTAG Final Report Regional and Urban Scale Modeling--Chapter 2, 2-7 (undated). But the OTAG modelers allocated their scarce resources purposefully, by reference to known air quality data, explicitly taking into consideration the "locale of various problem areas (as repre- sented by urban-area modeling domains), and emissions den- sity." Id. Thus it was no mere techno-fortuity that the fine grid included enough of Missouri to include the city of St. Louis and enough of Georgia to include Atlanta: both cities are designated nonattainment areas for ozone under the 1-hour NAAQS. See Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,359. Moreover, the fine grid portions of both states are the closest to other nonattainment areas, such as Chicago and Birming- ham, and generally higher ozone density. Of course the fine grid modeling of parts of Missouri and Georgia showed emissions in the aggregate meeting the EPA's threshold "contribution" criteria. Thus fine grid mod- eling of each in its entirety would presumably also have done so. But that is a simple arithmetic necessity (a state is necessarily composed of its parts) and provides no reason for EPA to ignore the very air quality factors that influenced the design of the modeling that did occur. OTAG itself clearly did not think those factors magically lost their force, for it recommended against controlling the rump areas. And EPA itself acknowledged part of the reason this should be so when it observed, "Sources that are closer to the nonattainment area tend to have much larger effects on air quality than sources that are far away." 63 Fed. Reg. at 25,919. Indeed, even if the line between areas for which there was evidence and ones for which there was none were explained solely by fortuity, EPA would still be required to act upon the evidence that was generated. See Chemical Manufacturers Ass'n v. EPA, 859 F.2d 977, 989 (D.C. Cir. 1988) (holding that EPA must consider "all the evidence--including the industry evi- dence"). This leads us to EPA defenses other than modeling design. The first is that "the larger the geographic area that is controlled, the greater the downwind benefits." Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,424. This reason can only stand if the emissions at issue contribute significantly to nonattainment in another state. OTAG concluded they did not. Id. EPA claims that its state-specific modeling, which supplemented OTAG's more regional modeling, supports including the coarse grid areas. See id. Yet EPA's explanation and technique make clear that emissions from the fine grid areas may have been the sole source of the finding. Indeed, EPA says as much: "[I]f emissions from part of a State contribute significantly to downwind nonattainment or maintenance problems, emissions from the entire State contribute signifi- cantly to downwind nonattainment or maintenance problems." Id. This of course is also true as a matter of logic (a state is the sum of its parts). But it is completely consistent with the rump portion being innocent of downwind effect, and thus is scarcely a reason for ruling that significant contributions from a border city should rope in the entire state. Aware of this problem, EPA simply throws the burden of persuasion onto the states. "[T]here is no peculiar meteoro- logical phenomenon that would indicate that emissions from some portion of [each of the affected states] would not impact downwind nonattainment or maintenance problems." Id. In addition, "the atmosphere is constantly in motion and has no limitations at geo-political boundaries." Id. If this is "evi- dence" of contribution, it proves too much. If the simple proposition that the prevailing westerlies carry pollutants eastward were enough, EPA could, on the basis of a plant in Pennsylvania, use s 110(a)(2)(D)(i)(I) to control all NOx emis- sions east of the Rocky Mountains. While we uphold EPA's determination that a "significant" contribution is a cost- effectively controllable contribution, EPA must first establish that there is a measurable contribution. Interstate contribu- tions cannot be assumed out of thin air. In the end administrative convenience is EPA's only real defense for basing NOx budgets on the entirety of a state's emissions. There seem to be two species of this argument. First, EPA seems to claim that it is just easier to calculate a NOx budget based on all the emissions in the state instead of only a portion of such emissions. EPA provides no explana- tion of why this is so, and it seems dubious. Within a state are counties, air quality control regions, and for some unfor- tunate states, nonattainment areas. EPA also has emissions data on specific sources, some of which may be susceptible of "highly cost-effective controls," and others of which may not be. See, e.g., Emissions Data For Power Plants, (visited January 26, 2000). Without data from such state subdivisions and specific sources, EPA could never have performed modeling or even set a statewide budget. EPA has not explained how calcula- tion of a budget for sources in only half of the state would be any more onerous than for all sources in the state. Unless it is relying on data that exist only for the state as a whole, calculation seems on its face easier for a half than for a whole. EPA offers a second administrative problem. If the con- cern for not allowing s 110(a)(2)(D)(i)(I) to encompass un- proven areas compels an insistence on proof of contribution from ever smaller geographic subdivisions, any area's specific contribution may appear insubstantial, even though collective- ly there are significant contributions. In other words, unlike bologna, which remains bologna no matter how thin you slice it, significant contribution may disappear if emissions activity is sliced too thinly. While this argument was stressed on appeal, it is nowhere to be found in the proposed or final rule, except insofar as it may have lurked behind the vague invocation of "administra- tive difficulties." See Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,424; Proposed Rule, 62 Fed. Reg. at 60,342. As a result it is quite undeveloped. But it appears to be based on a distortion of the claims of Missouri and Georgia. They are not asserting a right to bologna tactics, to slice down the unit of measure- ment to a point of insignificance. All they are claiming is that where the data--calculated under EPA's supervision--incul- pate part of a state and not another, EPA should honor the resulting findings. Such a proposition would of course leave EPA free to select states as the unit of measurement. In turn, states (or the areas of states that believed themselves innocent of material contributions, or sources located therein), might respond by offering finer-grained computations. Such a process seems more like a healthy search for truth than the collapse into infinite regress that EPA claims to fear. EPA also points to state flexibility: "Since each State has the flexibility to determine which sources to control in order to meet the budget, a State can structure its control strategy to require fewer reductions in certain portions of the State and greater controls in other areas." Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,424. This theory presents at least two difficulties. First, it overlooks the fact that state budgets not only encom- pass the whole state but are calculated on the basis of hypothesized cutbacks from areas that have not been shown to have made significant contributions. Thus the "flexibility" comes at the cost of a burden that is heavier in the aggregate, where the added weight accomplishes no purpose relevant to s 110(a)(2)(D)(i)(I). Second, a state's use of flexibility to pursue a purely in-state set of tradeoffs between cost and benefit (and thus unrelated to the goals of s 110(a)(2)(D)(i)(I)) may actually diminish the cutbacks in areas that are making a contribution to other states' nonattainment. Thus nowhere has EPA reasonably explained why NOx budgets based on every state source are the best stopping point with respect to states on the perimeter of the ozone problem. Therefore we vacate EPA's final rule with respect to Missouri and Georgia and remand to the agency for reconsid- eration in light of this opinion. C. South Carolina Petitioner Santee Cooper challenges South Carolina's inclu- sion in the SIP call by alleging that the state's downwind ozone nonattainment impact is "minuscule" and therefore not significant. We will hold unlawful EPA's decision to include South Carolina in the SIP call if we find EPA's decision "arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of discretion, or otherwise not accordance with law." 5 U.S.C. s 706(2)(A). In order for EPA's decision to include South Carolina in the SIP call to survive review, the agency must "demonstrate[ ] a reasonable connection between the facts on the record and its decision," Ethyl Corp., 51 F.3d at 1064. We conclude that the record supports EPA's decision to include the state as a significant contributor to downwind nonattainment. See Proposed Rule, 62 Fed. Reg. at 60,337-339. EPA considered the analyses submitted by the objecting petitioner but disagreed with the petitioner's conclusions as drawn from the relevant informa- tion. Specifically, EPA conducted additional modeling and interpreted the data in context and found that South Carolina significantly contributed to ozone nonattainment. See id.; Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,394-396. For example, under the 1-hour standard, the UAM-V zero- out modeling results indicated that South Carolina had a high maximum contribution (16 ppb) and a high frequency of contribution (at least 2 ppb to 15% of the exceedences and at least 10 ppb to 5% of the exceedences) to Atlanta. See Office of Air and Radiation, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Doc. No. VI-B-11, Air Quality Modeling Technical Support Document for the NOx SIP Call C-5, H-2 (1998). The CAMx modeling results were comparable (25 ppb maxi- mum contribution and a frequency of at least 2 ppb to 30% of the exceedences). See id. at C-5, G-6. Among the upwind states, only Alabama had a higher maximum contribution. See id. at Apps. G & H. Moreover, South Carolina's contribu- tion to 1-hour nonattainment in Atlanta was no more "insig- nificant" than many of the other linkages that were found to be significant (e.g., Indiana's contribution to New York City). See id. at C-13, H-16. In contrast, the petitioner seeks to show that the data, when viewed in isolation, makes South Carolina's contribution appear insignificant. In the end, we reject the challenge made on behalf of South Carolina because the petitioner attacks, not so much the accuracy of EPA's data, but rather EPA's reasonable analysis and application of the data. III. Federalism and Regulatory Flexibility Act A. NOx Budgets Building on OTAG's work, EPA ordered the challenged SIP call under the authority of section 110(k)(5) in order to address significant contribution to 1-hour ozone nonattain- ment as described under section 110(a)(2)(D).5 In fashioning the SIP call, EPA focused on OTAG's determination that "[r]egional NOx emissions reductions are effective in produc- ing ozone benefits." Proposed Rule, 62 Fed. Reg. 60,318, at 60,320. EPA also took into consideration OTAG's conclusion that while NOx controls are effective in addressing regional ozone problems, VOC controls are most effective locally and are most advantageous to urban nonattainment areas. See id. Because OTAG concluded that NOx reductions provide the key to addressing regional ozone problems, EPA's SIP call addresses regional ozone nonattainment through NOx emis- sions "budgets" established by the agency for each covered state. The budgets represent the amount of allowable NOx emissions remaining after a covered state prohibits the NOx amount contributing significantly to downwind nonattainment. See Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. 57,356, at 57,368. While EPA calculated the budgets using highly cost-effective emission controls, the agency allows the states to choose the control measures necessary to bring their emissions within the bud- get requirements. See id. at 57,377; id. at 57,400. Under EPA's budget plan, a state "may choose from a broader menu of cost-effective, reasonable alternatives" including alterna- tives that "may even be more advantageous in light of local concerns." Id. at 57,369-370. In fact, EPA has stated that the states have "full discretion in selecting the controls, so that [the states] may choose any set of controls that would assure achievement of the budget." Id. at 57,378. In addi- tion, each state has the option of adopting an interstate trading program that allows it to purchase NOx "allowances" from sources that have elected to over-control. Id. at 57,430. The SIP call also gives the states the option in some circum- stances to use "banked" allowances (i.e. allowances from prior years) to comply with emissions limits. See id. Petitioners assert that EPA's NOx budget program imper- missibly intrudes on the statutory right of the states to __________ 5 As noted above, we will not address the 8-hour portion of the SIP call. fashion their SIP submissions in the first instance. In sup- port of this position, the petitioners primarily rely on our decision in Virginia v. EPA, 108 F.3d 1397 (D.C. Cir.), modified on other grounds, 116 F.3d 499 (D.C. Cir. 1997), where we held that EPA may not use a section 110(k)(5) SIP call to order states to adopt a particular approach to achiev- ing the SIP requirements listed in section 110. Under the rule at issue in Virginia, EPA required states to adopt California's vehicle emission program and in effect set the numerical emissions limitations and mandated the means for the states to achieve the necessary emissions reductions. That case involved an EPA rule that required several states to reduce ozone precursors by a particular program and only allowed states to implement a more stringent program as an alternative or substitute. We held that EPA's approach exceeded its authority under section 110 because each state retains the authority to determine in the first instance the necessary and appropriate control measures needed to satisfy section 110's standards. See id. at 1407-09 (citing Train v. NRDC, 421 U.S. 60, 78-79 (1975)). Our holding in Virginia was mandated by the Supreme Court's decision in Train v. NRDC, 421 U.S. 60 (1975). Train involved a challenge to Georgia's procedures for revis- ing source-specific emission limits adopted in a SIP. See id. at 68-71. The Train Court held that states have the au- thority under the CAA to initially propose specific emission limitations. See id. at 79. The Court defined "emission lim- itations" as "regulations of the composition of substances emitted into the ambient air from such sources as power plants, service stations, and the like. They are the specific rules to which operators of pollution sources are subject, and which if enforced should result in ambient air which meets the national standards." Id. at 78 (emphasis added). The Court further held that EPA has only "a secondary role in the process of determining and enforcing the specific, source-by-source emission limitations." Id. at 79 (emphasis added). The Train decision and subsequent precedent make clear that section 110 left to the states "the power to [initial- ly] determine which sources would be burdened by regula- tion and to what extent." Union Elec. Co. v. EPA, 427 U.S. 246, 269 (1976) (emphasis added); cf. Virginia, 108 F.3d at 1399, 1401, 1408 (involving a source-specific program); Riv- erside Cement Co. v. Thomas, 843 F.2d 1246, 1247-48 (9th Cir. 1988) (citing Train and noting EPA's secondary role in enforcing source-by-source emissions limitations). As we elaborated in Virginia, "the Supreme Court decided ... that [section 110] did not confer upon EPA the authority to condition approval of [a state's] implementation plan ... on the state's adoption of a specific control measure." Virgi- nia, 108 F.3d at 1408. For the reasons set forth below, we conclude that the NOx budgets do not fall within the realm of impermissible SIP call regulation as defined in Virginia and Train. Given the Train and Virginia precedent, the validity of the NOx budget program underlying the SIP call depends in part on whether the program in effect constitutes an EPA-imposed control measure or emission limitation triggering the Train- Virginia federalism bar: in other words, on whether the program constitutes an impermissible source-specific means rather than a permissible end goal. However, the program's validity also depends on whether EPA's budgets allow the covered states real choice with regard to the control measure options available to them to meet the budget requirements. Section 110(a)(2)(D) requires SIPs to contain adequate provisions prohibiting emissions from "any source or other type of emissions activity within the State" that "contribute significantly" to NAAQS nonattainment in another state. Here, EPA mandates that 22 states and the District of Columbia implement section 110(a)(2)(D) using its NOx bud- get system. In essence, the NOx budget in question is an EPA mandate prohibiting NOx emissions in the 23 jurisdic- tions from exceeding a tonnage specific to that jurisdiction. See 63 Fed. Reg. 57,356 at 57,491-493 (1998). Of concern to petitioners, the budget rule prohibits states from seeking compliance, in whole or part, by controlling VOC emissions even though VOCs as well as NOx emissions contribute to ozone problems. See, e.g., id. at 57,359; see also 40 C.F.R. s 52.31(b)(7) (1998) (defining ozone precursors). Yet, the budget plan's defining aspects do not necessarily cause the program to conflict with the limiting principles contained in Train and Virginia. Analyzing the budget rule together with the relevant precedent, we hold that based on section 110's silence, EPA reasonably interpreted section 110 as providing it with the authority to determine a state's NOx significant contribution level and agree with EPA that the NOx budget plan does no more than project whether states have reduced emissions sufficiently to mitigate interstate transport. See 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,368. Under section 110, EPA must "approve a [SIP] submittal as a whole if it meets all of the applicable requirements of [the Act]." 42 U.S.C. s 7410(k)(3). While the states have considerable latitude in fashioning SIPs, the CAA "nonethe- less subject[s] the States to strict minimum compliance re- quirements" and gives EPA the authority to determine a state's compliance with the requirements. Union Elec. Co., 427 U.S. at 256-57 (referring to the requirements contained in the statute). Given EPA's authority to ensure that submit- ted SIPs adequately prohibit significantly contributing emis- sions, EPA permissibly relied on its general rulemaking authority to prospectively inform the states of EPA's signifi- cance determinations. Moreover, EPA does not tell the states how to achieve SIP compliance. Rather, EPA looks to section 110(a)(2)(D) and merely provides the levels to be achieved by state-determined compliance mechanisms. Specifically, EPA set NOx reduction levels based, in part, on assumptions about reductions obtain- able through highly cost-effective controls. See Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,426. However, EPA made clear that states do not have to adopt the control scheme that EPA assumed for budget-setting purposes. See id. at 57,369-370. States can choose from a myriad of reasonably cost-effective options to achieve the assigned reduction levels. See, e.g., id. at 57,438 (noting possibilities with regard to mobile sources); id. at 57, 378 (noting possibilities with regard to stationary sources); id. at 57,416. While EPA bases the budgets here on "highly cost-effective" control measures, the states remain free to implement other "cost-effective" or "reasonably cost- effective" measures in place of the ones identified by EPA. See id. at 57,378; 63 Fed. Reg. 60,318 at 60,328 (1997) (noting that "one State may choose to primarily achieve emissions reductions from stationary sources while another State may focus on emissions reductions from the mobile source sec- tor"). More importantly, EPA went so far as to give the states "full discretion in selecting ... controls," 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,378, thereby allowing states to attain their budgets by imposing even quite unreasonable, very cost-ineffective con- trols. In Virginia, we did not bar EPA from permitting more costly alternatives but rather alternatives states would consider "unreasonable or impracticable." Here, EPA ac- commodates Virginia's mandate by allowing reasonable con- trol alternatives and allowing states to focus reduction efforts based on local needs or preferences. See 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,369; id. at 57,399-405; 62 Fed. Reg. at 60,328. Thus, real choice exists for the covered states. Regarding EPA's decision not to rely on VOC reductions, EPA reasonably concluded that long-range ozone transport can only be addressed adequately through NOx reductions. Petitioners' reliance and emphasis on VOC reductions in lieu of NOx reductions ignores the scientific basis for EPA's rule. OTAG and EPA concluded that VOC controls would not effectively address interstate ozone transport. Furthermore, states can cure any NOx reduction "disbenefits" with corre- sponding optional VOC controls. See 62 Fed Reg. at 60,344- 345; 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,425. Thus, the SIP call cannot be invalidated merely because EPA reasonably chose not to regulate VOCs. In sum, we conclude that EPA's NOx budget program reasonably establishes reduction levels and leaves the control measure selection decision to the states. In addition, unlike the rule invalidated in Virginia, states implementing alterna- tive control measures will not be penalized with more strin- gent emissions targets. Since the challenged budget pro- gram does not mandate a "specific, source-by-source emission limitation[ ]," the NOx budget plan does not run afoul of Train or Virginia. B. Regulatory Flexibility Act The Regulatory Flexibility Act ("RFA"), 5 U.S.C. ss 601- 612, as amended in 1996 by the Small Business Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act ("SBREFA"), Pub. L. No. 114-121, Title II, 110 Stat. 847, 857-74, ss 201-253 (codified at 5 U.S.C. ss 601-612 (1994 & Supp. II 1996)), requires an agency, when proposing a rule for notice and comment, to "prepare and make available for public comment an initial regulatory flexibility analysis.... [that] describe[s] the im- pact of the proposed rule on small entities," 5 U.S.C. s 603(a), including small businesses, small organizations, and small governmental jurisdictions. See id. s 601(6). In addition, when promulgating a final rule, an agency must "prepare a final regulatory flexibility analysis" that describes, among other things, "a summary of the significant issues raised by the public comments in response to the initial regulatory flexibility analysis, a summary of the assessment of the agency of such issues," and "the steps the agency has taken to minimize the significant economic impact on small entities." Id. s 604(a). However, these analyses are not required if the agency "certifies that the rule will not, if promulgated, have a signifi- cant economic impact on a substantial number of small enti- ties." Id. s 605(b). In the instant case, EPA certified that the proposed and final rule will not have a significant econom- ic impact on a substantial number of small entities and, accordingly, did not perform any regulatory flexibility analy- sis. See Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,478; Proposed Rule, 62 Fed. Reg. at 60,375. RFA petitioners contend that EPA's certification was improper and in violation of the RFA. We disagree. The court has consistently held that the RFA imposes "no obligation to conduct a small entity impact analysis of effects on entities which it does not regulate." Motor & Equip. Mfrs. Ass'n. v. Nichols, 142 F.3d 449, 467 (D.C. Cir. 1998) (quoting United Distribution Cos. v. FERC, 88 F.3d 1105, 1170 (D.C. Cir. 1996)); see also American Trucking, 175 F.3d at 1044. Therefore, the key issue in evaluating EPA's s 605(b) certification is whether the NOx SIP call "regulates" small entities. EPA based its certification on its view that the NOx SIP call "would not establish requirements applicable to small entities" because "it would require States to develop, adopt, and submit SIP revisions that would achieve the necessary NOx reductions and would leave to the States the task of determining how to obtain those reductions, including which entities to regulate." Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,478. We agree with EPA's statement that the SIP call does not directly regulate individual sources of emissions. The instant case is thus analogous to American Trucking, which upheld EPA's certification under s 605(b) because the revised NAAQS at issue "regulate small entities only indirectly--that is, insofar as they affect the planning decision of the States." American Trucking, 175 F.3d at 1044. Therefore, we con- clude that EPA's certification under s 605(b) is justified. IV. Remaining Claims A. Definition of "NOx Budget Unit" RFA petitioners also contend that EPA arbitrarily revised the definition of a "NOx budget unit" to bring certain small sources within the scope of the core group of emission- producing sources to which the NOx Budget Trading Rule ("model trading rule") applies.6 This contention is meritless. __________ 6 To assist states in meeting their budgets and to facilitate the most cost-effective reductions, the SIP call established a model rule for interstate trading of NOx "allowances." Each state can choose whether to adopt the model rule, which will be administered by EPA, to adopt its own trading program, or to have no trading program at all. See Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,456-58. The core group definition is used to set the minimum require- ments that a State would have to include in its trading rule in order to participate in the EPA-managed multi-state trading program. See id. at 57,461. EPA viewed that setting such requirements was necessary for controlling the administrative costs of managing the trading program. See id. In the proposed rule, a "NOx budget unit" was defined as a boiler that either serves electricity generators with a capacity greater than 25 megawatts ("MW") or does not serve genera- tors but has a design heat capacity of greater than 250 million Btu/hr ("mmBTu/hr"). See Supplemental Notice for the Finding of Significant Contribution and Rulemaking for Cer- tain States in the Ozone Transport Assessment Group Region for Purposes of Reducing Regional Transport of Ozone ("Sup- plemental Notice of Proposed Rule"), 63 Fed. Reg. 25,902, 25,978 (1998). EPA sought comment on "the appropriateness of including [such] categories ..., whether the size cut-offs should be higher or lower for these source categories, and the appropriateness of including other source categories in the core group." Id. at 25,923. In the final rule, EPA discussed and revised the definition to expand the core group by including large boilers--those with design heat capacity of greater than 250 mmBtu/hr--even if they served generators with a capacity less than 25 MW. See Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,518. EPA explained that it was making this change in order to address the concern raised in the com- ments about excluding large boilers with high levels of emis- sion just because they happen to serve small generators. See id. at 57,461. EPA's revision is reasonable. The only argument that RFA petitioners seem to have against the change is that it contradicts EPA's statement elsewhere that "small electrical generators less than 25 MW ... will be exempt under the final model rule." Id. at 57,463. It is unclear why this statement renders EPA's final action arbitrary. EPA's defi- nition of a NOx budget unit and the reasons for its change are set forth in the preamble to the final rule, and the most that the RFA petitioners have demonstrated is that EPA made at least one statement that was, as EPA concedes in its brief, "incomplete in that it did not address the case of large boilers with small generators." Such a minor oversight in the draft- ing of the preamble to the final rule does not render the substantive decision by EPA arbitrary. B. Council of Industrial Boiler Owners 1. Introduction In the rulemaking, EPA distinguished between electricity generating units ("EGUs") and non-electricity generating units ("non-EGUs"). Council of Industrial Boiler Owners ("CIBO"), a trade association whose membership consists of companies and universities operating industrial boilers and turbines ("industrial boilers"), which constitute one category of non-EGUs, challenges the NOx SIP call for being based on the following arbitrary and capricious actions by EPA: EPA's failure to determine whether non-EGUs are significant con- tributors, EPA's flawed cost assumptions in its determination of cost-effective control measures for non-EGUs, EPA's erro- neous calculation of non-EGU budgets, and EPA's arbitrary redefinition of the term "EGU." We agree only that EPA's redefinition of EGUs was arbitrary and capricious. 2. Significant Contribution of Industrial Boilers CIBO challenges EPA's decision to include non-EGU boil- ers in the rule without having isolated non-EGU emissions to determine whether they "significantly contribute" to the in- terstate ozone transport problem and whether implementing highly cost-effective emissions reduction measures on indus- trial boilers would ameliorate nonattainment in downwind states. CIBO maintains that non-EGU boilers typically have significantly shorter stacks than EGUs and that their emis- sions, as a result, fall below the "mixing layer" that promotes long-range NOx transport. Therefore, CIBO contends, indus- trial boilers as a group can have no impact on long-range ozone transport. However, this factual claim fails in view of contrary evidence in the record. OTAG's Executive Report states as one of its major conclusions that "[b]oth elevated (from tall stacks) and low-level NOx reductions are effective." Executive Report at 4. EPA reiterated this finding by OTAG in the NPRM, see Proposed Rule, 62 Fed. Reg. at 60,332, it relied on the finding, and it appears that members of CIBO never challenged it during the comment period. Therefore, we cannot say EPA's inclusion of non-EGUs in the group of significantly contributing sources was arbitrary. 3. Cost-Effectiveness Calculation for Industrial Boilers' Control Measures CIBO also challenges EPA's conclusion that industrial boil- ers could achieve a 60% emissions reduction using highly cost-effective control measures, see Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,418, as based on flawed cost calculations. More specifi- cally, CIBO lists the following alleged problems in EPA's cost assumptions: - EPA's assumption of 10 years as the lifetime of all control measures for industrial boilers, except for selective catalytic reduction and selective non-catalytic reduction con- trols, for which 20 years was assumed. - EPA's use of a 10% discount rate, not 7%, in its cost- effectiveness analysis. - EPA's failure to take into account the fact that control effectiveness can vary by as much as 10% to 20%. - EPA's failure to take into account cost and feasibility implications of load variability and firing of multiple fuels. - EPA's assumption of NOx emission allowance costs of $2,000 per ton, when emission allowances trade for $5,500 to $6,300 per ton. The general problem of these criticisms is that CIBO merely lists several items as problems and labels all of them "irrational" without explaining why its claims should concern the court. Given that almost all of CIBO's challenges involve technical details on which the court generally defers to the agency's expertise, CIBO's failure to explain why the so- called problems it identifies amount to an arbitrary and capricious decisionmaking is fatal to its claims.7 Therefore, __________ 7 For instance, the last item on the list, that it is arbitrary and capricious for EPA to assume NOx emission allowance costs of $2,000 per ton when emission allowances now trade for $5,500 to $6,300 per ton, is insufficiently explained. Of course, if the firms in the market generating entitlement prices of $5,500 to $6,300 per ton were regulated at the same degree of stringency as EPA contem- plates for firms expected to be burdened under the present rule, the we reject CIBO's claims regarding EPA's underlying cost assumptions about industrial boilers. 4. Determination of Non-EGU Component of State NOx Budgets CIBO contends that EPA's calculation of the non-EGU component for the State NOx budget lacks adequate support in the record and lists the following as problems: - Non-EGU inventories had errors. - EPA's use of Bureau of Economic Analysis growth factor to project 2007 emission levels have "inherent error." - EPA employed "crude extrapolations" to identify large non-EGU boilers. - The "default boiler capacity file" is not in the record and the record does not reveal how EPA manipulated the data. - The source of Bureau of Economic Analysis growth factors is not identified in the record, and the record does not show how EPA manipulated the data. - It is unknown whether EPA credited NOx reductions from fluidized-bed combustion technology. Again, CIBO merely presents a list of problems without explaining why these alleged errors render EPA's rulemaking arbitrary or capricious. In addition, CIBO members had repeated opportunities to provide correct information for some of these items during the rulemaking process. CIBO's poorly articulated, blanket accusations at this late stage con- tribute little to improve the quality of agency rulemaking; therefore, we reject CIBO's challenges regarding EPA's cal- culation of NOx budgets for non-EGUs. __________ market price would be strong evidence that compliance would cost far more than the $2,000 per ton figure that EPA has used. No one would pay $6,000 for an entitlement to emit a ton that he could remove at a cost of $2,000; the price of an entitlement could not exceed the marginal removal cost. But if the prices to which CIBO points arose among firms more stringently regulated, there would be no such contradiction. CIBO has not even endeavored to show equivalent stringency. 5. Definition of EGU More persuasively, CIBO contends that EPA revised the definition of "EGU" without adequate notice. Throughout the rulemaking, EPA defined an EGU as it did under the acid rain program, which excludes from the category of "utility units" those cogeneration units that sell less than one-third of their potential electrical output capacity or less than 25 MW per year. See 42 U.S.C. s 7651a(17)(C). However, two months after the promulgation of the rule, EPA redefined an EGU as a unit that serves a "large" generator (greater than 25MW) that sells electricity. CIBO contends that EPA did not provide sufficient notice and opportunity to comment on this revision, especially considering that the industrial boilers have relied on the previous definition for a number of years. We agree. EPA maintains that it provided adequate notice in the May 1998 supplemental notice, stating that "deregulation of elec- tric utilities" means that "it is not clear how ownership of the electricity generating facilities will evolve." Supplemental Notice of Proposed Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 25,923. Given that "there is no relevant physical or technological difference between utilities and other power generators," EPA pro- posed, "all large electricity generating sources, regardless of ownership," should be treated the same. Id. There are several problems with EPA's response. First, it is undisput- ed that EPA was departing from the definition of EGUs as used in prior regulatory contexts, and EPA was not explicit about the departure from the prior practice until two months after the rule was promulgated. Neither the proposed rule- making in November 1997 nor the final rule in October 1998 introduced the new definition. EPA waited until the Decem- ber 1998 correction notice to announce that it will "classify as an EGU any boiler ... that is connected to a generator greater than 25 MWe from which any electricity is sold." Correction and Clarification to the Finding of Significant Contribution and Rulemaking for Purposes of Reducing Re- gional Transport of Ozone ("Correction Notice to Final Rule"), 63 Fed. Reg. 71,220, 71,223 (1998). After the Decem- ber correction notice, EPA reopened the comment period for sixty days for comments on this and other issues. In EPA's May 1999 response to the comments, EPA, for the first time, discussed why the change was necessary and offered a justifi- cation largely based on recent changes in the electric power industry. See Responses to the 2007 Baseline Sub-Inventory Information and Significant Comments for the Final NOx SIP Call 10-12 (May 1999) ("Responses to Final Comments"). As to the statement in the May 1998 supplemental notice that EPA claims constitutes notice, this statement was given in EPA's discussion of how the core group of sources for the model trading rule should be defined, and not in the context of a discussion about the general distinction between EGUs and non-EGUs for the purposes of calculating state budgets. Cf. Small Refiner Lead Phase-Down Task Force v. EPA, 705 F.2d 506, 550 (D.C. Cir. 1983). Moreover, EPA also explicitly observed in the same May notice discussion about the model trading rule that "[m]any of the definitions ... are the same as those used in ... the Acid Rain Program regulations, in order to maintain consistency among programs." Supple- mental Notice of Proposed Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 25,923. Given the vague and conflicting signals that EPA was send- ing, it is an exaggeration to state that some general "theme" of the regulatory consequences of deregulation of the utility industry throughout rulemaking meant that EPA's last- minute revision of the definition of EGU should have been anticipated by industrial boilers as a "logical outgrowth" of EPA's earlier statements. See American Water Works Ass'n. v. EPA, 40 F.3d 1266, 1274-75 (D.C. Cir. 1994). EPA contends that even assuming that CIBO did not have adequate notice and opportunity to comment on the EGU definition, the error has been cured because it reopened the comment period on this issue after its announcement of the revision. See Correction Notice to Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 71,221-23. This response is to no avail. During the new comment period, some commenters complained that there had not been sufficient notice and opportunity to comment on the EGU redefinition. See Responses to Final Comment, at 12. EPA's response to this charge primarily relied on the claim that there had been adequate notice prior to the redefinition, see id., and we have already rejected that argument. Therefore, we conclude EPA did not provide sufficient notice and opportunity to comment for its redefinition of EGUs and remand the rulemaking to EPA for further consid- eration in light of this opinion. C. INGAA Interstate Natural Gas Association of America ("INGAA"), a trade association that represents major interstate natural gas transmission companies in the United States, contends that EPA did not provide adequate notice and opportunity to comment on the control level assumed for "large" stationary internal combustion ("IC") engines in its determination of state NOx budgets. We agree. EPA's NPRM in November 1997 assumed a 70% control level for large IC engines, see Proposed Rule, 62 Fed. Reg. at 60,354, after considering and rejecting an 80% control level. See id. at 60,348. Then, in the supplemental notice in May 1998, EPA continued to assume the 70% control level. See Supplemental Notice of Proposed Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 25,908. EPA stated in the same notice that it "intends to further analyze" control approaches for IC engines and said that "[a]s the above analyses are completed, EPA intends to place them in the docket." Id. at 25,909. EPA did not present a new analysis until September 4, 1998, when it concluded that a 90% control level was more appropriate for large IC engines. See Technical Support Document for Sta- tionary International Combustion Engines 2 (September 4, 1998). When the rule was finally promulgated in October 1998, EPA stated that it was assuming a 90% control level. See Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,418. INGAA contends that EPA's switch from 70% to 90% for large IC engines was unanticipated and that EPA should have allowed comments on the issue. Considering EPA's repeated affirmation of the 70% assumption throughout rule- making and rejection of a higher, 80% assumption earlier, a revision in its assumption less than one month before the final rule was promulgated hardly provided adequate notice, espe- cially given the magnitude of the consequences of the pro- posed change on the regulated bodies. Therefore, we remand for further consideration on this issue.8 In addition, INGAA challenges EPA's definition of large IC engines. EPA, in the final rule, distinguished between large and small sources by defining a "cutoff level." 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,414. EPA assumed no control for sources below the cutoff level and defined small sources as units with a capacity less than or equal to 250 mmBtu/hr and with emissions less than or equal to one ton per day. See id. at 57,415. EPA added that "EPA is relying on a capacity approach first and a tons per day approach second (where a capacity data is not available or appropriate)" to define small sources. Id. at 57,416. Then, in the December correction notice, EPA large- ly repeated the same methodology for determining the cutoff level, but added that "[a] stationary internal combustion engine and a cement plant were determined to be 'large' if its 1995 average daily ozone season emissions were greater than one ton." Correction Notice to Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 71,224. INGAA contends that EPA did not follow its own standard in the correction notice and singled out IC engines and cement plants without explanation. Although EPA's various statements on this issue throughout rulemaking have not always been very clear or entirely consistent, EPA went through an extensive comment period on this issue, see Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,415-17, and we agree with EPA that the change that INGAA criticizes for being arbitrary is merely a minor clarification that satisfies the reasonableness standard. __________ 8 INGAA further contends that, even putting aside the notice issue, the documents that EPA relies on do not support EPA's assumption of 90% control level. Because we are remanding on the basis of the conclusion that there was inadequate notice, we do not reach the merits of the issue. D. PP&L 1. EPA's Restrictions on Early Reduction Credits PP&L, an electric utility that owns several generating stations in Pennsylvania, contends that EPA arbitrarily limit- ed the number of "early reduction credits" ("ERCs"). We disagree. Under the SIP call, a source can generate ERCs if it reduces its NOx emissions before May 2003 to a level below that is required by any regulatory scheme. ERCs can then be used to compensate for emitting emissions above required levels in a later time period. See Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,430. EPA limited the amount of available ERCs for each state to the size of each state's compliance supplement pool ("CSP"). See id. at 57,474. The CSP is an additional allow- ance of emissions that allows states to emit 200,000 tons of NOx in the 2003-2004 ozone seasons over the state emissions budgets. Id. at 57,428. EPA created the CSP in response to the comments that if all utilities had to install pollution control equipment by May 1, 2003, there might be disruptions in electricity supply. See id. If a state chooses to use the CSP, it can either provide ERCs or distribute the allowances to sources that demonstrate a need for the compliance supple- ment. See id. at 57,429-30. PP&L contends that imposing this limit on the number of ERCs is arbitrary and capricious because placing any limit on ERCs is environmentally counterproductive. We do not find this contention persuasive. EPA noted during the comment period that ERCs, although generally beneficial, can be costly in that they allow states to exceed their budgets. See Re- sponses to Significant Comments on the Proposed Finding of Significant Contribution and Rulemaking for Certain States in the Ozone Transport Assessment Group (OTAG) Region for Purposes of Reducing Regional Transport of Ozone 346 (September 1998) ("Responses to Comments"). EPA noted further that the CSP, by establishing a cap on the number of allowances to be distributed, limited such potential costs. Id. EPA's decision is thus reasonable. PP&L also contends that EPA has not demonstrated why the "flow control mechanism" is not sufficient to address its concern. Under the flow control mechanism, the use of banked allowances exceeding 10% of the emissions budget for sources in the trading program is either flatly prohibited or discouraged by discounting the value of ERCs used as such, and states can choose between either method. See Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,431-32. This complaint by PP&L overlooks the fact that EPA included the flow control mecha- nism in the regulatory scheme "[a]s a final safeguard limiting the impact of additional allowances eligible for banking in the system." Responses to Comments, at 346. Therefore, it was a safeguard created in addition to the CSP limitation. It was within EPA's discretion to devise multiple limitations to con- tain the environmental cost of ERCs. PP&L further contends that, even if it is rational for EPA to place a limit on the amount of ERCs, EPA's choice of setting the limit at the same amount as the CSP is arbitrary and capricious. This contention fails as well. The record shows that EPA allowed ERCs merely as a mechanism for managing the CSP, not as an independent program with a purpose separate from that of the CSP. See Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,428-33. Therefore, EPA's decision to limit the amount of ERCs to the size of the CSP was reasonable. 2. Emissions Multiplier for Low Mass Emission Units PP&L also contends that EPA arbitrarily required "low mass emission units" ("LMEUs") to use a 15% multiplier to calculate their emissions. We disagree. EPA allows LMEUs either to use a generic default NOx or to determine a unit-specific NOx emission rate by conducting a stack test once every five years. Because EPA found that the stack test results can vary by 15% or more depending on atmospheric conditions, EPA requires an LMEU to calculate its emissions rate by adding 15% to the stack test result. See Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. at 57,490. PP&L contends that this is unreasonable because EPA has stated that the testing would likely underestimate emissions during cooler less humid conditions. See id. PP&L reasons that because the SIP call applies only during summer seasons (when ozone forms), that the stack test underestimates emis- sions during the winter cannot justify the 15% multiplier. This contention is to no avail. Because the record contains evidence that NOx rates determined by the stack test can vary widely even during the ozone season, EPA's decision was reasonable. See Docket A-97-35, Item IV-A-1 at 43-54 (August 26, 1998). Conclusion We vacate EPA's final rule with respect to Wisconsin, Missouri, and Georgia (see Part II.A-B). These cases are remanded for further consideration in light of this opinion. We hold that EPA failed to provide adequate notice of a change in the definition of an electric generating unit (see Part IV.B.5), and that EPA did not provide adequate notice of a change in the control level assumed for large stationary internal combustion engines (see Part IV.C). These cases are also remanded. In all other respects, the petitions for review are denied. So ordered. Sentelle, Circuit Judge, dissenting: Unlike the majority's journey through this regulatory scheme, mine is neither lengthy nor complex, because I get off at the first stop. In promulgating the regulations at issue, EPA purported to exercise the authority Congress conferred upon it to enforce the requirements of 42 U.S.C. s 7410(a)(2)(D)(i)(I) which empowers the Administrator to police the contents of State Implementation Plans ("SIPs"), specifically to ensure that such plans contain adequate provisions ... prohibiting ... any source or other type of emissions activity within the State from emitting any air pollutant in amounts which will ... contribute significantly to nonattainment in, or interfere with maintenance by, any other State with respect to any such national primary or secondary ambient air quality standard.... 42 U.S.C. s 7410(a)(2)(D)(i)(I) (1994) (emphasis added). EPA is a federal agency--a creature of statute. It has no constitu- tional or common law existence or authority, but only those authorities conferred upon it by Congress. If there is no statute conferring authority, a federal agency has none. The only statute upon which EPA purports to rely in the current controversy is s 7410(a)(2)(D)(i)(I). That section provides authority for EPA to require States to act in a certain fashion based upon the presence of sources or activities which emit "pollutants in amounts which will ... contribute significantly to nonattainment." It would appear to me that Congress clearly empowered EPA to base its actions on amounts of pollutants, those amounts to be measured in terms of signifi- cance of contribution to downwind nonattainment. Instead, EPA has chosen, doubtless in the pursuit of beneficent ends, to assert authority to require the SIPs to contain provisions based not on the amounts of pollutants, nor even on the relative significance of the contributions of such pollutants to downwind nonattainment, but on the relative cost effective- ness of alleviation. I agree with the State petitioners that it is undeniable that EPA has exceeded its statutory authority. We have before had occasion to remind EPA that its mission is not a roving commission to achieve pure air or any other laudable goal. In American Petroleum Institute v. United States EPA, 52 F.3d 1113 (D.C. Cir. 1995), we re- viewed an EPA rule requiring that thirty percent of the oxygen in reformulated gasoline be derived from renewable sources, such as ethanol. The statutory authority under which EPA operated, 42 U.S.C. s 7545(k)(1) empowered EPA to promulgate regulations achieving "the greatest reduction in emissions of ozone forming volatile organic com- pounds...." 42 U.S.C. s 7545(k)(1). Although EPA ad- vanced commendable goals of economic benefit for its inclu- sion of the additional goal of ethanol market protection, we struck down the overreaching and reminded EPA that "it is axiomatic that an administrative agency's power to promul- gate legislative regulations is limited to the authority delegat- ed by Congress." API, 52 F.3d at 1119 (quoting Bowen v. Georgetown Univ. Hosp., 488 U.S. 204, 208 (1988)). Similarly, in Ethyl Corp. v. EPA, 51 F.3d 1053 (D.C. Cir. 1995), we considered EPA's denial of a Clean Air Act waiver application based on health considerations. We did not sug- gest that EPA acted in bad faith or that health considerations were not important, but we repaired to the statutory grant of authority in 42 U.S.C. s 7545(f)(4), which based the Adminis- trator's authority to deny waiver solely on the property of an additive to "cause or contribute to a failure of any emission control device or system...." 42 U.S.C. s 7545(f)(4). We again granted the petition for review of the Administration's action, reminding EPA that where "the plain language of a provision makes it clear that ... decisions are to be based on one criterion, the EPA cannot base its decision on other criteria," even on a criterion as laudable as the health of the public. Ethyl Corp., 51 F.3d at 1058. For all the majority's discussion of inconsistent arguments by States and the possibility of taking costs into account elsewhere raised by the Administration and adopted by the majority, I do not see why the present controversy does not fall squarely within the four corners of API and Ethyl Corp. Congress set forth one criterion: the emission of an amount of pollutant sufficient to contribute significantly to downwind nonattainment. EPA adopted a different criterion: the cost effectiveness of alleviation. I would remind the agency once more of the lessons of API and Ethyl Corp., allow the petitions for review, and end the case. The majority makes a fundamental mistake by divorcing the adverb "significantly" from the verb it modifies, "contrib- ute." The majority compounds its error by divorcing signifi- cantly from the rest of the statutory provision in issue. Maj. Op. at 19-23. By focusing on "significance" or what it means to be "significant," the majority ignores the fact that the statute permits EPA to address that which is "contribut[ed] significantly." 42 U.S.C. s 7410(a)(2)(D)(i)(I) (emphasis add- ed). And what should EPA look for as being contributed significantly? Congress clearly answered that question for the agency as being an "amount" of an "air pollutant." Id. Considering that Congress expressly gave EPA authority with regard to "any air pollutant in amounts which will ... contribute significantly to nonattainment ...," id. (emphasis added), I marvel at an interpretation that permits cost effec- tiveness to find a place in a statutory provision addressing amounts of air pollutant contribution. While the contribution must affect nonattainment significantly, no reasonable read- ing of the statutory provision in its entirety allows the term significantly to springboard costs of alleviation into EPA's statutorily-defined authority. Given s 7410(a)(2)(D)(i)(I)'s mandate as a whole, it becomes clear that EPA and the majority have to contort the statute's language by isolating the term significantly and ignoring the terms air pollutant, amounts, and contribute in order to work cost considerations into the statute. I just cannot agree with such an unusual exercise in statutory construction. I see nothing in Chevron U.S.A. Inc. v. NRDC, Inc., 467 U.S. 837 (1984), that either compels or counsels the majority's result. EPA argues that Congress did not define significant contribution. True, it did not. Neither did it define amount. But neither EPA nor the majority have offered any reason- able interpretation of those words which makes them depend upon or even relate to the cost effectiveness of alleviation.1 EPA comes close to arguing: Congress has not expressly forbidden us to use this criterion, therefore we may use it. As we said in Ethyl Corp.: To suggest, as the [EPA] effectively does, that Chevron step two is implicated any time a statute does not expressly negate the existence of a claimed administra- tive power ..., is both flatly unfaithful to the principles of administrative law ... and refuted by precedent. 51 F.3d at 1060. Because the majority's deference to EPA's unreasonable statutory interpretation as couched in the agen- cy's scurrilous "second-step" cost effectiveness analysis ven- tures off track, as I said, I am getting off at the first stop. Because I would invalidate the regulatory scheme before us at its inception, I will not address the subsidiary issues pursued by my colleagues. __________ 1 Contrary to the suggestion of the majority, neither of the cases cited by the majority bear any implication that the cost of alleviat- ing or otherwise dealing with risk expressed as a noun or a verb has any effect upon the definition of "significant" or "significantly" used as an adjective or adverb modifying that noun or verb. The portion of Industrial Union Department v. American Petroleum Institute, 448 U.S. 607, 655 (1980) (plurality opinion) quoted by the majority to the effect "that a 'significant' risk ... is not a mathematical straitjacket," (Maj. Op. at 20) does not deal in any fashion with the cost of alleviation. Rather, Justice Stevens in that opinion was contrasting the significance of a one-in-a-billion chance of cancer from drinking chlorinated water against the one-in-a-thousand risk that regular inhalation of certain benzene-containing vapors would be fatal. Obviously, the "significance" of the risk deals with its importance, not the cost of its alleviation. Equally off point is International Union, United Auto Workers v. OSHA, 37 F.3d 665, 668-69 (D.C. Cir. 1994), which concerned the cost-effectiveness of alleviating measures directed at risk theretofore determined to have been significant, not with the use of cost-effectiveness in determin- ing the significance of the risk vel non.