United States Court of Appeals
For the First Circuit
Nos. 01-1176
01-1332
SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION,
Plaintiff, Appellant,
v.
SG LTD. ET AL.,
Defendants, Appellees.
APPEALS FROM THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
FOR THE DISTRICT OF MASSACHUSETTS
[Hon. Joseph L. Tauro, U.S. District Judge]
Before
Boudin, Chief Judge,
Selya and Lipez, Circuit Judges.
Mark Pennington, Assistant General Counsel, with whom David
M. Becker, General Counsel, Jacob H. Stillman, Solicitor, and
Meyer Eisenberg, Deputy General Counsel, were on brief, for
appellant.
Daniel I. Small, with whom Meaghan E. Barrett and Butters,
Brazilian & Small, LLP were on brief, for appellees.
September 13, 2001
SELYA, Circuit Judge. These appeals — procedurally,
there are two, but for all practical purposes they may be
treated as one — require us to determine whether virtual shares
in an enterprise existing only in cyberspace fall within the
purview of the federal securities laws. SG Ltd., a Dominican
corporation, and its affiliate, SG Trading Ltd. (collectively,
"SG" or "defendants"), asseverate that the virtual shares were
part of a fantasy investment game created for the personal
entertainment of Internet users, and therefore, that those
shares do not implicate the federal securities laws. The
Securities and Exchange Commission ("the SEC"), plaintiff below
and appellant here, counters that substance ought to prevail
over form, and that merely labeling a website as a game should
not negate the applicability of the securities laws. The
district court accepted the defendants' view and dismissed the
SEC's complaint. SEC v. SG Ltd., 142 F. Supp. 2d 126 (D. Mass.
2001). Concluding, as we do, that the SEC alleged sufficient
facts to state a triable claim, we reverse.
I. BACKGROUND
We take the facts as alleged in the SEC's first amended
complaint (shorn, however, of empty rhetoric). Aulson v.
Blanchard, 83 F.3d 1, 3 (1st Cir. 1996).
-3-
The underlying litigation was spawned by SG's operation
of a "StockGeneration" website offering on-line denizens an
opportunity to purchase shares in eleven different "virtual
companies" listed on the website's "virtual stock exchange." SG
arbitrarily set the purchase and sale prices of each of these
imaginary companies in biweekly "rounds," and guaranteed that
investors could buy or sell any quantity of shares at posted
prices. SG placed no upper limit on the amount of funds that an
investor could squirrel away in its virtual offerings.
The SEC's complaint focused on shares in a particular
virtual enterprise referred to by SG as the "privileged
company," and so do we. SG advised potential purchasers to pay
"particular attention" to shares in the privileged company and
boasted that investing in those shares was a "game without any
risk." To this end, its website announced that the privileged
company's shares would unfailingly appreciate, boldly
proclaiming that "[t]he share price of [the privileged company]
is supported by the owners of SG, this is why its value
constantly rises; on average at a rate of 10% monthly (this is
approximately 215% annually)." To add plausibility to this
representation and to allay anxiety about future pricing, SG
published prices of the privileged company's shares one month in
advance.
-4-
While SG conceded that a decline in the share price was
theoretically possible, it assured prospective participants that
"under the rules governing the fall in prices, [the share price
for the privileged company] cannot fall by more than 5% in a
round." To bolster this claim, it vouchsafed that shares in the
privileged company were supported by several distinct revenue
streams. According to SG's representations, capital inflow from
new participants provided liquidity for existing participants
who might choose to sell their virtual shareholdings. As a
backstop, SG pledged to allocate an indeterminate portion of the
profits derived from its website operations to a special reserve
fund designed to maintain the price of the privileged company's
shares. SG asserted that these profits emanated from four
sources: (1) the collection of a 1.5% commission on each
transaction conducted on its virtual stock exchange; (2) the
bid-ask spread on the virtual shares; (3) the "skillful
manipulation" of the share prices of eight particular imaginary
companies, not including the privileged company, listed on the
virtual stock exchange; and (4) SG's right to sell shares of
three other virtual companies (including the privileged
company). As a further hedge against adversity, SG alluded to
the availability of auxiliary stabilization funds which could be
-5-
tapped to ensure the continued operation of its virtual stock
exchange.
SG's website contained lists of purported "big
winners," an Internet bulletin board featuring testimonials from
supposedly satisfied participants, and descriptions of incentive
programs that held out the prospect of rewards for such
activities as the referral of new participants (e.g., SG's
representation that it would pay "20, 25 or 30% of the referred
player's highest of the first three payments") and the
establishment of affiliate websites.
At least 800 United States domiciliaries, paying real
cash, purchased virtual shares in the virtual companies listed
on the defendants' virtual stock exchange. In the fall of 1999,
over $4,700,000 in participants' funds was deposited into a
Latvian bank account in the name of SG Trading Ltd. The
following spring, more than $2,700,000 was deposited in Estonian
bank accounts standing in the names of SG Ltd. and SG Perfect
Ltd., respectively.
In late 1999, participants began to experience
difficulties in redeeming their virtual shares. On March 20,
2000, these difficulties crested; SG unilaterally suspended all
pending requests to withdraw funds and sharply reduced
participants' account balances in all companies except the
-6-
privileged company. Two weeks later, SG peremptorily announced
a reverse stock split, which caused the share prices of all
companies listed on the virtual stock exchange, including the
privileged company, to plummet to 1/10,000 of their previous
values. At about the same time, SG stopped responding to
participant requests for the return of funds, yet continued to
solicit new participants through its website.
The SEC undertook an investigation into SG's
activities, which culminated in the filing of a civil action in
federal district court. The SEC's complaint alleged, in
substance, that SG's operations constituted a fraudulent scheme
in violation of the registration and antifraud provisions of the
federal securities laws. See Securities Act of 1933 § 5(a),
(c), 15 U.S.C. § 77e(a), (c) (offer, sale, or delivery of
unregistered securities); id. § 17(a), 15 U.S.C. § 77q(a) (fraud
in offer or sale of securities); Securities Exchange Act of
1934 § 10(b), 15 U.S.C. § 78j(b); SEC Rule 10b-5, 17 C.F.R.
240.10b-5 (fraud in connection with purchase or sale of
securities). The SEC sought injunctive relief, disgorgement,
and civil penalties.
The district court entered a temporary restraining
order (subsequently converted to a preliminary injunction)
blocking SG's operation of the website pendente lite. The court
-7-
also instituted an asset freeze that infrigidated approximately
$5,500,000. The SEC's success was short-lived; after some
skirmishing, not relevant here, the district court granted SG's
motion to dismiss the complaint for failure to state a
cognizable claim on the ground that the virtual shares were a
clearly marked and defined game lacking a business context. See
SEC v. SG Ltd., 142 F. Supp. 2d at 131. The SEC immediately
appealed, and we issued a stay keeping both the preliminary
injunction and the asset freeze in place for the time being.
These appeals hinge on whether the district court erred
in ruling that transactions in the privileged company's shares
did not constitute transactions in securities. In the pages
that follow, we explore the makeup of that particular type of
security known as an investment contract; examine the district
court's rationale; and apply the tripartite "investment
contract" test to the facts as alleged. Because the lower court
dismissed the SEC's first amended complaint for failure to state
a claim upon which relief might be granted, Fed. R. Civ. P.
12(b)(6), we conduct a de novo review, "accepting as true all
well-pleaded factual averments and indulging all reasonable
inferences in the plaintiff's favor." Aulson, 83 F.3d at 3. If
the facts contained in the complaint, viewed in this favorable
light, justify recovery under any applicable legal theory, we
-8-
must set aside the order of dismissal. Conley v. Gibson, 355
U.S. 41, 45-46 (1957); Aulson, 83 F.3d at 3.
II. THE LEGAL LANDSCAPE
These appeals turn on whether the SEC alleged facts
which, if proven, would bring this case within the
jurisdictional ambit of the federal securities laws.
Consequently, we focus on the type of security that the SEC
alleges is apposite here: investment contracts.
A. Investment Contracts.
The applicable regulatory regime rests on two
complementary pillars: the Securities Act of 1933, 15 U.S.C. §§
77a-77aa, and the Securities Exchange Act of 1934, 15 U.S.C. §§
78a-78mm. These statutes employ nearly identical definitions of
the term "security." See Securities Act of 1933 § 2(a)(1), 15
U.S.C. § 77b(a)(1); Securities Exchange Act of 1934 § 3(a)(10),
15 U.S.C. § 78c(a)(10). Congress intended these sweeping
definitions, set forth in an appendix hereto, to encompass a
wide array of financial instruments, ranging from well-
established investment vehicles (e.g., stocks and bonds) to much
more arcane arrangements. SEC v. C. M. Joiner Leasing Corp.,
320 U.S. 344, 351 (1943). Included in this array is the
elusive, essentially protean, concept of an investment contract.
-9-
Judicial efforts to delineate what is — and what is not
— an investment contract are grounded in the seminal case of SEC
v. W. J. Howey Co., 328 U.S. 293 (1946). The Howey Court
established a tripartite test to determine whether a particular
financial instrument constitutes an investment contract (and,
hence, a security). This test has proven durable. Under it, an
investment contract comprises (1) the investment of money (2) in
a common enterprise (3) with an expectation of profits to be
derived solely from the efforts of the promoter or a third
party. Id. at 298-99. This formulation must be applied in
light of the economic realities of the transaction. United
Hous. Found., Inc. v. Forman, 421 U.S. 837, 851-52 (1975);
Tcherepnin v. Knight, 389 U.S. 332, 336 (1967); Futura Dev.
Corp. v. Centex Corp., 761 F.2d 33, 39 (1st Cir. 1985). In
other words,
substance governs form, and the substance of
an investment contract is a security-like
interest in a "common enterprise" that,
through the efforts of the promoter or
others, is expected to generate profits for
the security holder, either for direct
distribution or as an increase in the value
of the investment.
Rodriguez v. Banco Cent. Corp., 990 F.2d 7, 10 (1st Cir. 1993)
(citations omitted).
The Supreme Court has long espoused a broad
construction of what constitutes an investment contract,
-10-
aspiring "to afford the investing public a full measure of
protection." Howey, 328 U.S. at 298. The investment contract
taxonomy thus "embodies a flexible rather than a static
principle, one that is capable of adaptation to meet the
countless and variable schemes devised by those who seek the use
of the money of others on the promise of profits." Id. at 299.
The Howey test has proven to be versatile in practice.
Over time, courts have classified as investment contracts a
kaleidoscopic assortment of pecuniary arrangements that defy
categorization in conventional financial terms, yet nonetheless
satisfy the Howey Court's three criteria. See, e.g., id.
(holding that sale of citrus groves, in conjunction with service
contract, qualifies as an investment contract); Teague v.
Bakker, 35 F.3d 978, 981, 990 (4th Cir. 1994) (same re purchase
of life partnership in evangelical community); Long v. Shultz
Cattle Co., 881 F.2d 129, 132 (5th Cir. 1989) (same re cattle-
feeding and consulting agreement); Miller v. Cent. Chinchilla
Group, 494 F.2d 414, 415, 418 (8th Cir. 1974) (same re
chinchilla breeding and resale arrangement).
B. The District Court's Rationale.
We pause at this juncture to address the district
court's rationale. Relying upon a dictum from Howey discussing
-11-
"the many types of instruments that in our commercial world fall
within the ordinary concept of a security," 328 U.S. at 299
(quoting legislative history), the district court drew a
distinction between what it termed "commercial dealings" and
what it termed "games." SEC v. SG Ltd., 142 F. Supp. 2d at 131.
Characterizing purchases of the privileged company's shares as
a "clearly marked and defined game," the court concluded that
since that activity was not part of the commercial world, it
fell beyond the jurisdictional reach of the federal securities
laws. Id. In so ruling, the court differentiated SG's
operations from a classic Ponzi or pyramid scheme on the ground
that those types of chicanery involved commercial dealings
within a business context. Id.
We do not gainsay the obvious correctness of the
district court's observation that investment contracts lie
within the commercial world. Contrary to the district court's
view, however, this locution does not translate into a dichotomy
between business dealings, on the one hand, and games, on the
other hand, as a failsafe way for determining whether a
particular financial arrangement should (or should not) be
characterized as an investment contract. Howey remains the
touchstone for ascertaining whether an investment contract
exists — and the test that it prescribes must be administered
-12-
without regard to nomenclature. See Int'l Bhd. of Teamsters v.
Daniel, 439 U.S. 551, 561 (1979); see also Forman, 421 U.S. at
851-52 (warning against reliance on "the names that may have
been employed by the parties" to identify a particular
investment); cf. William Shakespeare, Romeo & Juliet, act 2, sc.
2 (circa 1597) ("A rose by any other name would smell as
sweet."). As long as the three-pronged Howey test is satisfied,
the instrument must be classified as an investment contract.
Howey, 328 U.S. at 301. Once that has occurred, "it is
immaterial whether the enterprise is speculative or non-
speculative or whether there is a sale of property with or
without intrinsic value." Id. It is equally immaterial whether
the promoter depicts the enterprise as a serious commercial
venture or dubs it a game.
A fairly recent Supreme Court opinion demonstrates that
the "commercial world" to which the Howey Court alluded actually
encompasses the total universe of financial instruments
available to investors, rather than the subset of financial
instruments envisioned by the district court (i.e., "commerce"
as opposed to "games"). In that case, Justice Marshall wrote:
In defining the scope of the market that it
wished to regulate, Congress painted with a
broad brush. It recognized the virtually
limitless scope of human ingenuity,
especially in the creation of "countless and
variable schemes devised by those who seek
-13-
the use of the money of others on the
promise of profits," and determined that the
best way to achieve its goal of protecting
investors was "to define 'the term
"security" in sufficiently broad and general
terms so as to include within that
definition the many types of instruments
that in our commercial world fall within the
ordinary concept of a security.'" Congress
therefore did not attempt precisely to cabin
the scope of the Securities Acts. Rather,
it enacted a definition of "security"
sufficiently broad to encompass virtually
any instrument that might be sold as an
investment.
Reves v. Ernst & Young, 494 U.S. 56, 60-61 (1990) (citations
omitted). This expansive language, coupled with Congress's
sweeping definitions of "security," persuade us to reject the
district court's use of Howey's "commercial world" reference as
a limiting principle.
To sum up, Howey supplies the appropriate template for
identifying investment contracts within the overarching ambit of
the federal securities laws. Contrary to the district court's
conclusion, this template admits of no exception for games or
gaming. Thus, the language on SG's website emphasizing the
game-like nature of buying and selling virtual shares of the
privileged company does not place such transactions beyond the
long reach of the federal securities laws.
III. ADMINISTERING THE TRIPARTITE TEST
-14-
What remains is to analyze whether purchases of the
privileged company's shares constitute investment contracts. We
turn to that task, taking the three Howey criteria in sequence.
A. Investment of Money.
The first component of the Howey test focuses on the
investment of money. The determining factor is whether an
investor "chose to give up a specific consideration in return
for a separable financial interest with the characteristics of
a security." Daniel, 439 U.S. at 559. We conclude that the
SEC's complaint sufficiently alleges the existence of this
factor.
To be sure, SG disputes the point. It argues that the
individuals who purchased shares in the privileged company were
not so much investing money in return for rights in the virtual
shares as paying for an entertainment commodity (the opportunity
to play the StockGeneration game). This argument suggests that
an interesting factual issue may await resolution — whether
participants were motivated primarily by a perceived investment
opportunity or by the visceral excitement of playing a game.
Nevertheless, this case comes to us following a dismissal under
Rule 12(b)(6), and the SEC's complaint memorializes, inter alia,
-15-
SG's representation that participants could "firmly expect a 10%
profit monthly" on purchases of the privileged company's shares.
That representation plainly supports the SEC's legal claim that
participants who invested substantial amounts of money in
exchange for virtual shares in the privileged company likely did
so in anticipation of investment gains. Given the procedural
posture of the case, no more is exigible to fulfill the first
part of the Howey test.
B. Common Enterprise.
The second component of the Howey test involves the
existence of a common enterprise. Before diving headlong into
the sea of facts, we must dispel the miasma that surrounds the
appropriate legal standard.
1. The Legal Standard. Courts are in some disarray
as to the legal rules associated with the ascertainment of a
common enterprise. See generally II Louis Loss & Joel Seligman,
Securities Regulation 989-97 (3d ed. rev. 1999). Many courts
require a showing of horizontal commonality — a type of
commonality that involves the pooling of assets from multiple
investors so that all share in the profits and risks of the
enterprise. See SEC v. Infinity Group Co., 212 F.3d 180, 187-88
(3d Cir. 2000), cert. denied, 121 S. Ct. 1228 (2001); SEC v.
Life Partners, Inc., 87 F.3d 536, 543 (D.C. Cir. 1996); Wals v.
-16-
Fox Hills Dev. Corp., 24 F.3d 1016, 1018 (7th Cir. 1994); Revak
v. SEC Realty Co., 18 F.3d 81, 87 (2d Cir. 1994); Curran v.
Merrill Lynch, Pierce, Fenner & Smith, 622 F.2d 216, 222, 224
(6th Cir. 1980), aff'd on other grounds, 456 U.S. 353 (1982).
Other courts have modeled the concept of common enterprise
around fact patterns in which an investor's fortunes are tied to
the promoter's success rather than to the fortunes of his or her
fellow investors. This doctrine, known as vertical commonality,
has two variants. Broad vertical commonality requires that the
well-being of all investors be dependent upon the promoter's
expertise. See Villeneuve v. Advanced Bus. Concepts Corp., 698
F.2d 1121, 1124 (11th Cir. 1983), aff'd en banc, 730 F.2d 1403
(11th Cir. 1984); SEC v. Koscot Interplanetary, Inc., 497 F.2d
473, 478-79 (5th Cir. 1974). In contrast, narrow vertical
commonality requires that the investors' fortunes be "interwoven
with and dependent upon the efforts and success of those seeking
the investment or of third parties." SEC v. Glenn W. Turner
Enters., 474 F.2d 476, 482 n.7 (9th Cir. 1973).
Courts also differ in the steadfastness of their
allegiance to a single standard of commonality. Two courts of
appeals recognize only horizontal commonality. See Wals, 24
F.3d at 1018; Curran, 622 F.2d at 222, 224. Two others adhere
-17-
exclusively to broad vertical commonality.1 See Villeneuve, 698
F.2d at 1124; Koscot, 497 F.2d at 478-79. The Ninth Circuit
recognizes both horizontal commonality and narrow vertical
commonality. See Hocking v. Dubois, 885 F.2d 1449, 1459 (9th
Cir. 1989) (en banc). To complicate matters further, four
courts of appeals have accepted horizontal commonality, but have
not yet ruled on whether they also will accept some form of
vertical commonality. See Infinity Group, 212 F.3d at 187 n.8;
Life Partners, 87 F.3d at 544; Teague, 35 F.3d at 986 n.8;
Revak, 18 F.3d at 88. At least one of these courts, however,
has explicitly rejected broad vertical commonality. See Revak,
18 F.3d at 88.
Thus far, neither the Supreme Court nor this court has
authoritatively determined what type of commonality must be
present to satisfy the common enterprise element. We came close
in Rodriguez, in which we hinted at a preference for horizontal
commonality. There, promoters selling parcels of land made
"strong and repeated suggestions that the surrounding area would
develop into a thriving residential community." 990 F.2d at 11.
Although we held that the financial arrangement did not
1We note that broad vertical commonality is an expansive
concept which typically overspreads other types of commonality.
See Mordaunt v. Incomco, 469 U.S. 1115, 1115-16 (1985) (White,
J., dissenting from denial of certiorari).
-18-
constitute a security, we implied that an actual commitment by
the promoters to develop the community themselves, coupled with
the buyers' joint financing of the enterprise, could constitute
a common enterprise. See id.
The case at bar requires us to take a position on the
common enterprise component of the Howey test. We hold that a
showing of horizontal commonality — the pooling of assets from
multiple investors in such a manner that all share in the
profits and risks of the enterprise — satisfies the test. This
holding flows naturally from the facts of Howey, in which the
promoter commingled fruit from the investors' groves and
allocated net profits based upon the production from each tract.
See Howey, 328 U.S. at 296. Adopting this rule also aligns us
with the majority view and confirms the intimation of Rodriguez.
Last, but surely not least, the horizontal commonality standard
places easily ascertainable and predictable limits on the types
of financial instruments that will qualify as securities.2
2. Applying the Standard. Here, the pooling element
of horizontal commonality jumps off the screen. The defendants'
website stated that: "The players' money is accumulated on the
2 Since the complaint in this case alleges facts sufficient
to establish horizontal commonality, see infra Part III(B)(2),
we take no view as to whether vertical commonality, in either of
its iterations, also may suffice to satisfy the "common
enterprise" requirement.
-19-
SG current account and is not invested anywhere, because no
investment, not even the most profitable one, could possibly
fully compensate for the lack of sufficiency in settling
accounts with players, which lack would otherwise be more
likely." Thus, as the SEC's complaint suggests, SG
unambiguously represented to its clientele that participants'
funds were pooled in a single account used to settle
participants' on-line transactions. Therefore, pooling is
established.
Of course, horizontal commonality requires more than
pooling alone; it also requires that investors share in the
profits and risks of the enterprise. The SEC maintains that two
separate elements of SG's operations embody the necessary
sharing. First, it asserts that SG was running a Ponzi or
pyramid scheme dependent upon a continuous influx of new money
to remain in operation,3 and argues that such arrangements
3
While the terms "Ponzi" and "pyramid" often are used
interchangeably to describe financial arrangements which rob
Peter to pay Paul, the two differ slightly. In Ponzi schemes —
named after a notorious Boston swindler, Charles Ponzi, who
parlayed an initial stake of $150 into a fortune by means of an
elaborate scheme featuring promissory notes yielding interest at
annual rates of up to 50% — money tendered by later investors is
used to pay off earlier investors. In contrast, pyramid schemes
incorporate a recruiting element; they are marketing
arrangements in which participants are rewarded financially
based upon their ability to induce others to participate. The
SEC alleges that SG's operations aptly can be characterized
under either appellation.
-20-
inherently involve the sharing of profit and risk among
investors. Second, the SEC construes SG's promise to divert a
portion of its profits from website operations to support the
privileged company's shares as a bond that ties together the
collective fortunes of those who have purchased the shares.
While we analyze each of these theories, we note that any one of
them suffices to support a finding of commonality.
We endorse the SEC's suggestion that Ponzi schemes
typically satisfy the horizontal commonality standard. In
Infinity Group, investors contributed substantial sums of money
to a trust established by the defendants and received in
exchange a property transfer agreement guaranteeing stupendous
annual rates of return. 212 F.3d at 184-85. The economic
guarantees were based upon the trust's purported performance
experience, financial connections, and ability to pool large
amounts of money. Id. at 185. Participants were promised that
investing in the trust was a risk-free proposition, and that
their cash infusions would be repaid in full upon demand. Id.
at 184-85. Expected profits were a function of the number of
"capital units" held pursuant to the contract with the trust; in
turn, the number of capital units allocated to each investor was
directly proportional to the size of his or her investment. Id.
at 188-89. On these facts, the Third Circuit held that
-21-
horizontal commonality existed, emphasizing that under the
plan's terms each investor was entitled to receive returns
directly proportionate to his or her investment stake. Id. at
188.
SG's virtual shares bear striking factual similarities
to the financial instruments classified as investment contracts
in Infinity Group. SG's flat 10% guaranteed return applied to
all privileged company shares, expected returns were dependent
upon the number of shares held, the economic assurances were
based on the promoter's ability to keep the ball rolling, the
investment was proclaimed to be free from risk, and participants
were promised that their principal would be repaid in full upon
demand. Like the Third Circuit, we think that these facts
suffice to make out horizontal commonality.
In all events, SG's promise to pay referral fees to
existing participants who induced others to patronize the
virtual exchange provides an alternative basis for finding
horizontal commonality. The SEC argues convincingly that this
shows the existence of a pyramid scheme sufficient to satisfy
the horizontal commonality standard. The most instructive
comparison is to SEC v. Int'l Loan Network, 968 F.2d 1304 (D.C.
Cir. 1992). A key element of the defendants' elaborate,
multifaceted, financial distribution network in that case was a
-22-
pyramid sales program in which participants stood to receive 50%
commissions on membership fees paid by individuals whom they
recruited, plus lesser commissions on sales by those recruited
by their recruits. Id. at 1306. The court of appeals ruled
that this structure satisfied the requirements of horizontal
commonality. Id. at 1308. In the process, it relied heavily
upon the fact that the network generated income only through
constant expansion of membership, which depended on individual
recruiting and the appeal of the promoter's larger marketing
campaign. Id.
Like the investors in Int'l Loan Network,
StockGeneration participants who recruited new participants were
promised bonuses worth 20%-30% of the recruit's payments.
Taking as true the SEC's plausible allegation that the sine qua
non of SG's operations was the continued net inflow of funds,
the investment pool supporting the referral bonus payments was
entirely dependent upon the infusion of fresh capital. Since
all participants shared in the profits and risks under this
pyramidal structure, it furnishes the sharing necessary to
warrant a finding of horizontal commonality.
We will not paint the lily. We conclude, without
serious question, that the arrangement described in the SEC's
complaint fairly can be characterized as either a Ponzi or
-23-
pyramid scheme, and that it provides the requisite profit-and-
risk sharing to support a finding of horizontal commonality.
Taking as true the SEC's allegation that SG's ability to fulfill
its pecuniary guarantees was fully predicated upon the net
inflow of new money, the fortunes of the participants were
inextricably intertwined. As long as the privileged company
continued to receive net capital infusions, existing
shareholders could dip into the well of funds to draw out their
profits or collect their commissions. But all of them shared
the risk that new participants would not emerge, cash flow would
dry up, and the underlying pool would empty.
SG's most perfervid argument against a finding of
horizontal commonality consists of a denial that its operations
comprise a Ponzi or pyramid scheme. It says that any such
scheme requires a material misrepresentation of fact and some
element of fraud or deception, and adds that those additional
features are lacking here; to the contrary, the rules of
StockGeneration were fully and accurately disclosed to all
participants. We do not gainsay that considerable disclosure
occurred. SG emphasized that new participants constituted the
sole source of all financial income for its StockGeneration
-24-
website.4 Indeed, in describing the structure and mechanism of
its virtual stock exchange, SG drew a colorful analogy between
the privileged company's shares and an enormous card table with
a mountain of money. According to SG, thousands of participants
continuously threw money onto the table by purchasing shares in
the privileged company, while other participants simultaneously
sold their shares back to the exchange to retrieve their
winnings from the table. SG remarked that the system would
remain stable so long as the size of the mountain either
remained constant or continued to grow.
Despite the fact that SG was relatively candid in
pointing out the fragile structure of the venture, its argument
lacks force. Even if we assume, for argument's sake, that
misrepresentations of fact and badges of fraud are necessary for
the existence of a Ponzi or pyramid scheme, the SEC's complaint
contains allegations sufficient, as a matter of pleading, to
establish both elements. First, the complaint alleges that SG
materially misrepresented the nature of the enterprise by
concealing the fact that the supply of new participants
inevitably would be exhausted, causing the scheme to implode and
4
SG specifically addressed this issue on its website,
declaring that: "New players: that is the only source of all
financial income to any game. It does not and cannot have other
sources of income. Otherwise, the game becomes unprofitable and
therefore simply pointless."
-25-
all existing participants to lose their money.5 Second, the
SEC's complaint plausibly characterized SG's flat guarantee of
a 10% monthly return on the privileged company's shares and its
assurances that it would support those shares as material
misrepresentations of fact. Third, the SEC alleged that SG
deceived participants by failing to disclose its intent to keep
investor money for itself.
Of course, given its "this was only a game" defense,
SG may well have colorable arguments anent materiality and
reliance (i.e., that, based upon its explicit disclosures, no
reasonable investor should have been deceived or misled). But
it is not this court's place to resolve such fact-sensitive
questions in the context of a Rule 12(b)(6) motion for
dismissal. See Cruz v. Melecio, 204 F.3d 14, 21-22 (1st Cir.
2000). For present purposes, it is enough that the SEC's
5As the SEC points out, SG specifically represented on its
website that SG was not a pyramid scheme that would "collapse
inevitably as soon as the inflow of new players stops." It went
on to state:
This is not a pyramid. The similarities are
purely superficial here. A whale might look
like a fish, but there are millions of years
of evolution between the two. The main
fundamental difference is the lack of
critical points in time, namely those of
mass payments. By manipulating profit, an
optimal way of spreading them in time is
successfully found.
-26-
allegations, taken as true, satisfy the common enterprise
component of the Howey test.6
C. Expectation of Profits Solely From the Efforts of Others.
The final component of the Howey test — the expectation
of profits solely from the efforts of others — is itself
divisible. We address each sub-element separately.
1. Expectation of Profits. The Supreme Court has
recognized an expectation of profits in two situations, namely,
(1) capital appreciation from the original investment, and (2)
participation in earnings resulting from the use of investors'
funds. Forman, 421 U.S. at 852. These situations are to be
contrasted with transactions in which an individual purchases a
commodity for personal use or consumption. Id. at 858. The SEC
posits that SG's guarantees created a reasonable expectancy of
profit from investments in the privileged company, whereas SG
maintains that participants paid money not to make money, but,
6
If more were needed — and we doubt that it is — SG's
promise to divert a portion of profits from website operations
to support share prices if the need arose also warrants a
finding of horizontal commonality. Through this arrangement, SG
provided participants with the opportunity to share income
derived from website operations on a pro rata basis. The SEC's
complaint notes these facts and alleges in substance that a
percentage of participants' funds were pooled; that participants
were told of their entitlement to support from this monetary
pool; and that they collectively stood to gain or lose
(depending on whether they received the guaranteed return on
their shares). In and of themselves, these averred facts boost
the SEC across the legal threshold for horizontal commonality.
-27-
rather, to acquire an entertainment commodity for personal
consumption. Relying heavily on Forman, the district court
accepted SG's thesis. SEC v. SG Ltd., 142 F. Supp. 2d at 130-
31. We do not agree.
In Forman, apartment dwellers who desired to reside in
a New York City cooperative were required to buy shares of stock
in the nonprofit cooperative housing corporation that owned and
operated the complex. Based on its determination that
"investors were attracted solely by the prospect of acquiring a
place to live, and not by financial returns on their
investments," the Forman Court held that the cooperative housing
arrangement did not qualify as a security under either the
"stock" or "investment contract" rubrics. Id. at 853. The
Court's conclusion rested in large part upon an Information
Bulletin distributed to prospective residents which stressed the
nonprofit nature of the cooperative housing endeavor. Id. at
854 (emphasizing that "[n]owhere does the Bulletin seek to
attract investors by the prospect of profits resulting from the
efforts of the promoters or third parties").7
7
The Court reiterated this conclusion in dismissing the
possibility that the co-op would lease commercial facilities,
professional offices, parking spaces, and communal washing
machines. Noting that the Information Bulletin made no
reference to the prospect of any such income as a means of
offsetting rental costs, the Court concluded "that investors
were not attracted to Co-op City by the offer of these potential
-28-
We think it noteworthy that the Forman Court contrasted
the case before it with Joiner. In that case, economic
inducements made by promoters in conjunction with the assignment
of oil well leases transformed the financial instrument under
consideration from a naked leasehold right to an investment
contract. 320 U.S. at 348. The Joiner Court found dispositive
advertising literature circulated by the promoters which
emphasized the benefits to be reaped from the exploratory
drilling of a test well. Id. ("Had the offer mailed by
defendants omitted the economic inducements of the proposed and
promised exploration well, it would have been a quite different
proposition.").
The way in which these cases fit together is
instructive. In Forman, the apartment was the principal
attraction for prospective buyers, the purchase of shares was
merely incidental, and the combination of the two did not add up
to an investment contract. 421 U.S. at 853. In Joiner, the
prospect of exploratory drilling gave the investments "most of
their value and all of their lure," the leasehold interests
themselves were no more than an incidental consideration in the
transaction, and the combination of the two added up to an
investment contract. 320 U.S. at 349. This distinction is
rental reductions." Forman, 421 U.S. at 856.
-29-
crucial, see Forman, 421 U.S. at 853 n.18, and it furnishes the
beacon by which we must steer.
Seen in this light, SG's persistent representations of
substantial pecuniary gains for privileged company shareholders
distinguish its StockGeneration website from the Information
Bulletin circulated to prospective purchasers in Forman. While
SG's use of gaming language is roughly analogous to the
cooperative's emphasis on the nonprofit nature of the housing
endeavor, SG made additional representations on its website that
played upon greed and fueled expectations of profit. For
example, SG flatly guaranteed that investments in the shares of
the privileged company would be profitable, yielding monthly
returns of 10% and annual returns of 215%. In our view, these
profit-related guarantees constitute a not-very-subtle form of
economic inducement, closely analogous to the advertising
representations in Joiner. In the same way that the prospect of
profitable discoveries induced investors to buy oil well leases,
the prospect of a sure-fire return lured participants to buy
shares in the privileged company (or so it can be argued).
This is not to say that SG's gaming language and
repeated disclaimers are irrelevant. SG has a plausible
argument, forcefully advanced by able counsel, that no
participant in his or her right mind should have expected
-30-
guaranteed profits from purchases of privileged company shares.
But this argument, though plausible, is not inevitable. In the
end, it merely gives rise to an issue of fact (or, perhaps,
multiple issues of fact) regarding whether SG's representations
satisfy Howey's expectation-of-profit requirement.
2. Solely from the Efforts of Others. We turn now to
the question of whether the expected profits can be said to
result solely from the efforts of others. The courts of appeals
have been unanimous in declining to give literal meaning to the
word "solely" in this context, instead holding the requirement
satisfied as long as "the efforts made by those other than the
investor are the undeniably significant ones, those essential
managerial efforts which affect the failure or success of the
enterprise." Turner Enters., 474 F.2d at 482; accord Rivanna
Trawlers Unlimited v. Thompson Trawlers, Inc., 840 F.2d 236, 240
n.4 (4th Cir. 1988) (adopting this holding and listing eight
other circuits which have held to like effect). This liberal
interpretation of the requirement seemingly comports with the
Supreme Court's restatement of the Howey test. See Forman, 421
U.S. at 852 (explaining that "the touchstone is the presence of
an investment in a common venture premised on a reasonable
-31-
expectation of profits to be derived from the entrepreneurial or
managerial efforts of others").8
We need not reach the issue of whether a lesser degree
of control by a promoter or third party suffices to give rise to
an investment contract because SG's alleged scheme meets the
literal definition of "solely." According to the SEC's
allegations, SG represented to its customers the lack of
investor effort required to make guaranteed profits on purchases
of the privileged company's shares, noting, for example, that
"playing with [the] privileged shares practically requires no
time at all." SG was responsible for all the important efforts
that undergirded the 10% guaranteed monthly return. As the sole
proprietor of the StockGeneration website, SG enjoyed direct
operational control over all aspects of the virtual stock
exchange. And SG's marketing efforts generated direct capital
investment and commissions on the transactions (which it pledged
to earmark to support the privileged company's shares).
SG's payment of referral bonuses to participants who
introduced new users to the website does not require a different
result. Even if a participant chose not to refer others to the
StockGeneration website, he or she still could expect, based on
8We caution, however, that the Forman Court explicitly
reserved judgment on adoption of the Turner Enterprises
formulation. See 421 U.S. at 852 n.16.
-32-
SG's profit-related guarantees, to reap monthly profits from
mere ownership of the privileged company's shares. Accordingly,
the SEC's complaint makes out a triable issue on whether
participants expected to receive profits derived solely from the
efforts of others.
IV. CONCLUSION
We need go no further. Giving due weight to the
economic realities of the situation, we hold that the SEC has
alleged a set of facts which, if proven, satisfy the three-part
Howey test and support its assertion that the opportunity to
invest in the shares of the privileged company, described on
SG's website, constituted an invitation to enter into an
investment contract within the jurisdictional reach of the
federal securities laws. Accordingly, we reverse the order of
dismissal and remand the case for further proceedings consistent
with this opinion. The preliminary injunction and asset freeze
shall remain in force pending conclusion of the proceedings
below.
Reversed and remanded.
-33-
APPENDIX A
Securities Act of 1933 § 2(a)(1), 15 U.S.C.
§ 77b(a)(1):
The term "security" means any
note, stock, treasury stock,
security future, bond,
debenture, evidence of
indebtedness, certificate of
interest or participation in
any profit-sharing agreement,
collateral-trust certificate,
preorganization certificate or
subscription, transferable
share, investment contract,
voting-trust certificate,
certificate of deposit for a
security, fractional undivided
interest in oil, gas, or other
mineral rights, any put, call,
straddle, option, or privilege
on any security, certificate
of deposit, or group or index
of securities (including any
interest therein or based on
the value thereof), or any
put, call, straddle, option,
or privilege entered into on a
national securities exchange
relating to foreign currency,
or, in general, any interest
or instrument commonly known
as a "security," or any
certificate of interest or
participation in, temporary or
interim certificate for,
receipt for, guarantee of, or
warrant or right to subscribe
to or purchase, any of the
foregoing.
Securities Exchange Act of 1934 § 3(a)(10),
15 U.S.C. § 78c(a)(10)
-34-
The term "security" means any
note, stock, treasury stock,
security future, bond,
debenture, certificate of
interest or participation in
any profit-sharing agreement
or in any oil, gas, or other
mineral royalty or lease, any
collateral-trust certificate,
preorganization certificate or
subscription, transferable
share, investment contract,
voting-trust certificate,
certificate of deposit for a
security, any put, call,
straddle, option, or privilege
on any security, certificate
of deposit, or group or index
of securities (including any
interest therein or based on
the value thereof), or any
put, call, straddle, option,
or privilege entered into on a
national securities exchange
relating to foreign currency,
or in general, any instrument
commonly known as a
"security"; or any certificate
of interest or participation
in, temporary or interim
certificate for, receipt for,
or warrant or right to
subscribe to or purchase, any
of the foregoing; but shall
not include currency or any
note, draft, bill of exchange,
or banker's acceptance, which
has a maturity at the time of
issuance of not exceeding nine
months, exclusive of days of
grace, or any renewal thereof
the maturity of which is
likewise limited.
-35-