United States Court of Appeals
For the First Circuit
No. 05-1221
In re XCELERA.COM SECURITIES LITIGATION
ALEX STUEBLER; JIM HICKS; JACK LADUE; GLOVER POWELL; DOUG HORAN,
Plaintiffs-Appellees,
v.
XCELERA.COM; ALEXANDER M. VIK; GUSTAV M. VIK,
Defendants-Appellants.
APPEAL FROM THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
FOR THE DISTRICT OF MASSACHUSETTS
[Hon. Rya W. Zobel, U.S. District Judge]
Before
Torruella, Cyr, and Lipez, Circuit Judges.
Louis R. Cohen, with whom Todd C. Zubler, Jonathan Cedarbaum,
Peter J. Macdonald, Robin L. Alperstein, and Wilmer Cutler
Pickering Hale and Dorr LLP were on brief, for appellants.
Peter A. Pease, with whom Patrick T. Egan, Colleen M. Conners,
Berman Devalerio Pease Tabacco Burt & Pucillo, Elaine Kusel,
Jeffrey Spinazzola, and Milberg Weiss Bershad & Schulman LLP were
on brief, for appellees.
December 13, 2005
LIPEZ, Circuit Judge. We treat this interlocutory appeal
from an order certifying a class in a securities fraud case as a
companion case to In re PolyMedica Corp. Sec. Litig., No. 05-1220,
slip op. (1st Cir. Dec. _, 2005), also decided this day. Our
determination in PolyMedica of the standard of efficiency to be
used in the application of the fraud-on-the-market theory informs
the analysis in this case. Defendants-Appellants Xcelera Inc.1, an
Internet holding company, and its directors, Alexander and Gustav
Vik (collectively, "Defendants"), argue that the district court
erred in determining that the market for Xcelera stock was
efficient during the relevant time period, and certifying the class
on that basis. For the reasons set forth below, we affirm.
I.
Alex Stuebler, Jim Hicks, Jack Ladue, Glover Powell, and
Doug Horan ("Plaintiffs") are purchasers of Xcelera stock, who seek
to represent a class of all purchasers of Xcelera stock from April
1, 1999, through August 8, 2000 (the "Class Period").2 According
1
While Plaintiffs (and the case caption) refer to the company
involved in this case as "Xcelera.com, Inc.," we refer to the
company by the name used by Defendants, "Xcelera Inc."
2
Plaintiffs also seek to represent a subclass of all purchasers of
Xcelera stock who purchased stock on the same day or within three
trading days after each of Alexander and Gustav Vik's allegedly
insider sales, which are said to have taken place on and between
February 22, 2000, and June 22, 2000. Certification of the
subclass necessarily hinges upon certification of the class. Since
we affirm the district court's order certifying the class, and
since Defendants do not object to that portion of the district
court's order certifying the subclass, we do not address the
-2-
to Plaintiffs, Defendants issued a press release on April 1, 1999,
stating that Xcelera had acquired a majority interest in Mirror
Image Internet, Inc. ("Mirror Image"), an Internet holding company.
More press releases and television appearances followed throughout
the Class Period, touting Xcelera's ownership of Mirror Image.
Defendants allegedly did not disclose, however, that this
acquisition was part of a joint venture with two other companies,
Kahnberget Holding, Ltd., and JAM Investments, Ltd. (collectively,
"JAM"), both of which had contributed a substantial portion of the
funds used to acquire the majority interest, $3.24 million, and
which were therefore entitled to a significant portion of the
Mirror Image stock pursuant to their joint-venture agreement.
Defendants also allegedly did not disclose the risk of dilution3 to
Xcelera shareholders should Defendants decide to issue Xcelera
stock in satisfaction of its obligation to JAM.
Plaintiffs contend that it was not until August 4, 2000
– when Xcelera issued its Annual Report for that year – that
Xcelera shareholders first learned that Xcelera might be required
to issue new shares of its stock to "certain third parties" in
order to pay for its investment in Mirror Image, and that this may,
in turn, result in a material dilution of Xcelera stock. That same
district court's decision to certify the subclass.
3
"Dilution" means "[t]he reduction in the monetary value or voting
power of stock by increasing the total number of outstanding
shares." Black's Law Dictionary (8th ed. 2004).
-3-
day, the price of Xcelera's stock fell by 2.5%, from $12.31 to $12
per share. Several days later, after a brief rise in stock price
on August 7, the price of Xcelera stock fell again, this time by
approximately 16%, from $14 on August 8, 2000, to $11.75 on August
9, 2000.
On April 2, 2001, Plaintiffs filed a consolidated amended
complaint, alleging that Defendants artificially inflated the price
of Xcelera stock during the Class Period by failing to disclose the
ownership dispute surrounding the Mirror Image stock and the risk
of dilution of Xcelera stock. The complaint further alleged that
Alexander and Gustav Vik made insider sales of over 3.2 million
shares of Xcelera stock to the unknowing public during the Class
Period, reaping proceeds of over $250 million. Plaintiffs seek
damages against Defendants under § 10(b) of the Securities and
Exchange Act of 1934, 15 U.S.C. § 78j(b) (the "Exchange Act") and
Rule 10b-5 promulgated thereunder, 17 C.F.R. § 240.10b-5, and
against Alexander and Gustav Vik under § 20(a) and § 20A of the
Exchange Act, 15 U.S.C. § 78t(a), § 78t-1.
On November 12, 2002, Plaintiffs filed a motion for
certification of the class and the insider trading subclass
-4-
pursuant to Fed. R. Civ. P. 23(a)4 and (b)(3).5 In order to satisfy
Rule 23(b)(3)'s requirement that common questions of law and fact
predominate over individual questions, Plaintiffs relied upon the
"fraud-on-the-market" presumption of reliance. Defendants opposed
the motion, arguing that Plaintiffs were not entitled to a
presumption of reliance because the market was not "efficient" – a
prerequisite for presuming reliance. In support of this position,
Defendants submitted the affidavit of Dr. Matthew P. Richardson, a
professor of finance at New York University and a Research
Associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research. He
concluded that the market for Xcelera stock was not efficient
during the Class Period. Plaintiffs responded by submitting the
affidavit of Dr. Scott A. Hakala, director of CBIZ Valuation Group,
Inc., a national business and valuation firm, who came to the
opposite conclusion.
4
Defendants do not dispute that the requirements of Rule 23(a) –
numerosity, typicality, commonality, and adequacy – have been met;
thus, we do not address them.
5
Rule 23(b)(3) provides, in relevant part, that "[a]n action may
be maintained as a class action if the court finds that the
questions of law or fact common to the members of the class
predominate over any questions affecting only individual members."
As we noted in PolyMedica, "[t]his requirement, although
reminiscent of the commonality requirement of Rule 23(a), is far
more demanding because it tests whether proposed classes are
sufficiently cohesive to warrant adjudication by representation."
No. 05-1220, slip op. (internal quotation marks and citation
omitted).
-5-
At Defendants' request, the district court conducted a
two-day evidentiary hearing on November 20 and 21, 2003. Both
parties presented oral argument, and each expert gave testimony
concerning the meaning of market efficiency and whether the market
for Xcelera stock was efficient. Defendants argued that the market
for a particular stock is efficient if it rapidly and accurately
reflects all material, publicly available information, and that
Xcelera's market did not meet these standards. Plaintiffs, on the
other hand, argued that while efficiency requires that market price
reflect all material, publicly available information "relatively
rapidly or within a reasonable period of time," the market price
need not reflect such information accurately. According to
Plaintiffs, the standard of market efficiency that they advocate is
satisfied by application of the factors set forth in Cammer v.
Bloom, 711 F. Supp. 1264 (D.N.J. 1989), which weigh in favor of a
finding of efficiency in the Xcelera market.
On September 30, 2004, the district court issued its
decision certifying both the class and the insider trading
subclass.6 The court credited Plaintiffs' expert analysis which
largely tracked the Cammer factors, and rejected Defendants' expert
analysis as focusing too much on whether market price "perfectly
6
In its decision, the district court also granted Plaintiffs'
motion to certify additional class representatives. Defendants do
not object to the grant of this motion, and we therefore do not
address it.
-6-
and correctly incorporate[d]" – as opposed to merely reflected –
publicly available information.
On February 15, 2005, we granted Defendants' petition for
permission to appeal the district court's order pursuant to Rule
23(f) of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure.7 Defendants argue
that the district court erred in adopting a definition of "market
efficiency" which did not require that market price rapidly and
accurately reflect all publicly available information. Defendants
further argue that the district court erred in applying only the
Cammer factors to determine market efficiency.
II.
As we stated in PolyMedica,
[t]he formulation of the proper standard for efficiency
is a purely legal question reviewed de novo. Reviewing
the application of that standard to the facts of a case
involves the review of a mixed question of law and fact.
Given the various factors relevant to an efficiency
determination, and the abundant evidence that can be
developed with respect to each factor, the determination
of whether a market is efficient is a fact-dominated
inquiry. Therefore, deferential clear-error review
applies to that determination. The ultimate decision to
certify a class is, of course, a discretionary one.
No. 05-1220, slip op. (internal citation omitted).
In a securities fraud action under § 10(b) of the
Exchange Act, and Rule 10b-5 promulgated thereunder, plaintiffs are
7
Rule 23(f) provides, in relevant part, that "a court of appeals
may in its discretion permit an appeal from an order of a district
court granting or denying class action certification under this
rule if application is made to it within ten days after entry of
the order." Fed. R. Civ. P. 23(f).
-7-
typically required to prove that they individually relied on a
defendant's misrepresentation. Id. Requiring proof of
individualized reliance, of course, would effectively preclude
securities fraud class actions under Rule 23(b)(3). Individual
issues of reliance would necessarily overwhelm the common ones.
The fraud-on-the-market theory eliminates the need to prove
individualized reliance by allowing a rebuttable presumption that
the plaintiff relied on the "integrity of the market price" which
reflected the misrepresentation. "Before an investor can be
presumed to have relied upon the integrity of the market price,
however, the market must be 'efficient.'" Id. In an efficient
market, the defendant's misrepresentations are absorbed into, and
reflected by, the market price. Investors who rely on the market
price, therefore, indirectly rely on those misrepresentations,
thereby justifying a presumption of reliance under the fraud-on-
the-market theory. Conversely, when a market lacks efficiency,
there is no assurance that market price reflects the defendant's
misrepresentations and that investors therefore indirectly relied
on those misrepresentations.
A. Standard of "Market Efficiency"
1. "Market Efficiency" Under PolyMedica
In PolyMedica, we held that "an efficient market is one
in which the market price of the stock fully reflects all publicly
available information." Id. This definition focuses on whether a
-8-
market is efficient in the informational sense, that is, whether
market prices respond rapidly to new information, such that prices
impound all publicly available information (and misinformation),
thereby justifying a presumption of reliance under the fraud-on-
the-market theory.
2. The District Court's Standard of Efficiency
According to the district court, an efficient market is
one in which "market price reflect[s] publicly available
information." In re: Xcelera.Com Sec. Litig., No. 00-11649-RWZ, at
6 (D. Mass. Sept. 30, 2004) (unpublished opinion). This definition
of market efficiency does not provide explicitly that market price
must "fully" reflect "all" available information, the standard set
forth in PolyMedica. However, the district court's reliance upon
Cammer to determine whether the Xcelera market was efficient means
that it necessarily applied the standard of efficiency used in
Cammer, which tracks the definition we adopted in PolyMedica. See
Cammer, 711 F. Supp. at 1281 (stating that an efficient market is
one in which "current price reflects all available information,"
and citing economic commentator Eugene Fama's definition of market
efficiency as "[a] market in which prices always 'fully reflect'
available information").
Still, Defendants argue that the district court's
definition of an efficient market is incomplete. Missing from the
court's definition, Defendants assert, is a requirement that in an
-9-
efficient market, "stock prices rapidly and accurately reflect all
publicly available information." (Emphasis added.) Because of
these omissions, Defendants argue, the district court wrongfully
concluded that Xcelera's market was efficient.
a. Rapidly
While we agree with Defendants that an efficient market
must "rapidly" reflect all publicly available information, and so
stated in PolyMedica, that characteristic is implicit in the
requirement that a market "fully reflect" all publicly available
information. See PolyMedica, No. 05-1220, slip op. (stating that
"market price 'fully reflects' all publicly available information
when prices respond so quickly to new information that it is
impossible for traders to make trading profits on the basis of that
information") (internal quotation marks and citation omitted).
Therefore, where, as here, the district court correctly determined
that market price must fully reflect all publicly available
information for purposes of defining market efficiency, the
district court understood that market price must "rapidly" reflect
such information in an efficient market. Moreover, the district
court's reliance upon Cammer, which emphasized the importance of an
efficient market "rapidly reflect[ing] new information in price,"
711 F. Supp. at 1276 n.17, again indicates that the district court
understood that an efficient market rapidly absorbs and reflects
new information.
-10-
b. Accurately
Defendants argue that an efficient market must also
respond to information accurately. According to their expert
witness, Richardson, an efficient market "accurately" reflects all
publicly available information when "investors [are] rational and
fac[e] no trading frictions such that stock prices equal their
'fundamental value.'" Accuracy, Richardson argues, thus hinges
upon a stock price's consistency with its fundamental value, which,
in turn, hinges upon the market behaving rationally.
Elaborating further, Richardson explains that
"fundamental value is the discounted sum of expected future cash
profits of the stock." In an efficient market, Richardson states,
information should "tell you something about . . . the expected
cash flow of the asset or the risk of that asset[,] and that
information should get incorporated into that price." Richardson
argues that "fundamental, or true, value" does not, however, mean
"ultimate future value," such that "investors [must] be fortune
tellers." Rather, it means a "fair price" that "incorporates all
the information currently available to investors," such that price
adjustments are "accurate on average: the prices should neither
underreact nor overreact to particular news announcements."
But investors are not always rational, Richardson
contends; the presence of irrational investors in the market causes
prices "to diverg[e] from fundamentals." The decisions of these
-11-
irrational investors, Richardson argues, "begin to move prices away
from their fundamental value" – away from expected risks and
returns – "meaning they're not reflecting the information in a
rational way." Richardson acknowledges, however, that the presence
of these irrational investors "is not enough per se to refute the
hypothesis that the market is efficient." On the contrary, "prices
will eventually adjust until the mispricings disappear," so long as
there are a sufficient number of rational investors active in the
market, and provided that these rational investors are not limited
in their ability "to take advantage of, or 'arbitrage,' these
mispricings" by "purchas[ing] the underpriced securities (i.e.,
relative to fundamental value) and sell[ing] the overpriced ones to
the irrational investors." Thus, in order "for prices to not
accurately reflect fundamental information," Richardson contends,
"there must be a reason why asset prices diverged from
fundamentals, e.g., the presence of irrational investors . . . and
[] there must be some limits to arbitrage that prevent rational
capital from forcing prices and fundamental value to converge."
Not surprisingly, Plaintiffs insist that "accuracy"
should be excluded from the definition of efficiency. According to
Hakala, their expert, a market is efficient when "all relevant and
publicly available information is impounded in share price." By
requiring that market price "accurately" reflect public
information, Hakala argues that Defendants are advocating "a higher
-12-
standard" of market efficiency imposed by academics, which demands
that markets must behave rationally so that stock prices will
"always conform to some idealized fundamental value that is
demonstrated in retrospect." Hakala contends that market
efficiency demands only that market price "reflects all public
information" so that "an average investor wo[n't] ordinarily be
able to beat the market . . . . It doesn't say anything about
whether the market was right or wrong in retrospect. . . ."
According to Hakala, "[Richardson's] analysis confuses market
efficiency with a level of hyper-rationality or perfect foresight
on the part of market participants that is unrealistic and not
required for a presumption of fraud-on-the-market." This analysis,
Hakala contends, "amounts to second-guessing the market, concluding
that the market, in retrospect . . . [was] over-valued."
In response to arguments raised by the parties in
PolyMedica, we have already resolved this debate in favor of
Plaintiffs. As we explained in PolyMedica, the fraud-on-the-market
presumption of reliance does not depend on the accuracy of the
market price, and whether it "mirror[s] the best possible
estimates, in light of all available information, of the actual
economic values of securities in terms of their expected risks and
returns." No. 05-1220, slip op. (internal quotation marks and
citation omitted). Rather, this presumption depends on whether the
market price of the stock reflects all available information, such
-13-
that an investor can be deemed to have indirectly relied on the
misrepresentation. Whether the stock was "worth" more or less in
some fundamental value sense, while arguably relevant to the
efficiency inquiry, is not essential to it.
As we stated in PolyMedica, "[w]hile fundamental value
efficiency may be the more comprehensive of the two concepts,
encompassing both speed and accuracy, [e]fficiency is not an all-
or-nothing phenomenon." Id. (emphasis in original) (internal
quotation marks and citation omitted). We explained that "for
purposes of establishing the presumption of reliance, therefore,
investors need only show that the market was informationally
efficient," not fundamental value efficient. Id.; see also id.
(stating that "the fraud-on-the-market theory does not require
'proof that the market correctly reflects some 'fundamental value'
of the security. To apply the fraud-on-the-market theory, it is
sufficient that the market for a security be 'efficient' only in
the sense that market prices reflect the available information
about the security'") (quoting In re Verifone Sec. Litig., 784 F.
Supp. at 1479 n.7).
Defendants do not, and cannot, cite to any language in
Basic requiring that the market price of a stock must accurately
reflect its fundamental value for purposes of demonstrating market
efficiency. In fact, as we noted in PolyMedica, the Supreme Court
in Basic declined to explicitly address the meaning of market
-14-
efficiency – much less a fundamental value theory of market
efficiency – stating that, "[w]e do not intend conclusively to
adopt any particular theory of how quickly and completely publicly
available information is reflected in market price." Id. (quoting
Basic, 485 U.S. at 249 n.28).8
Defendants contend that the district court, abetted by
Plaintiffs' expert, misconstrued "accuracy" to mean that the
Xcelera market must "correctly predict" what the fundamental value
of the security (i.e., "the discounted sum of expected future cash
profits of the stock") will be in the future. On the contrary,
Defendants argue, "accuracy" means only that a stock's price will
reflect its fundamental value "at any given moment." This is a
disingenuous argument. Like any lawsuit, the securities fraud
action involves the recreation of past events through proof. Proof
of fundamental value "at any given moment" would necessarily be a
retrospective analysis which, in the words of Hakala, "amounts to
second-guessing the market, concluding that the market, in
8
We are unpersuaded by the cases cited by Defendants which
generally allude to stock price's consistency with "accuracy" and
"value." None of these cases specifically hold that a market is
inefficient where the stock's price fails to "accurately" reflect
all publicly available information, see, e.g., Ross v. Bank South,
N.A., 885 F.2d 723 (11th Cir. 1989); Hurley v. FDIC, 719 F. Supp.
27 (D. Mass. 1989), nor do any of these cases analyze whether a
market was inefficient based on the failure of stock price to
mirror fundamental value, i.e., "the discounted sum of expected
future cash profits of the stock," see, e.g., Gariety v. Grant
Thornton, LLP, 368 F.3d 356 (4th Cir. 2004); Freeman v. Laventhol
& Horwath, 915 F.2d 193 (6th Cir. 1990).
-15-
retrospect . . . [was] over-valued." If this retrospective
judgment was that the stock price at a given moment was over-
valued, that judgment would be tantamount to the conclusion that
the stock price was a poor predictor of what subsequent analysis
would reveal about fundamental value at that given moment.
We find no error in the district court's determination
that, pursuant to Defendants' definition of market efficiency, "a
robust stock market would always present a defense at the class
certification stage and on the merits that depends on highly
subjective, retrospective analysis of what people trading in a
stock should have been thinking." The court's reference to
"retrospective analysis" is not incorrect. The present-day
analysis of the fundamental value of Xcelera's assets by
Defendants' expert during the Class Period is necessarily
"retrospective." In addition, we find no error in the court's
rejection of Defendants' expert's "suggest[ion] that market
efficiency is a rare phenomenon." Defendants' expert conceded that
"[t]he Internet sector as a whole, at least the 400 sample firms,"
was inefficient "in aggregate," and relied on an economic treatise
whose author concluded that "financial markets in most scenarios
are not expected to be efficient. Market efficiency only emerges
as an extreme special case, unlikely to hold under plausible
circumstances." (Citing Andrei Shleifer, Inefficient Markets: An
Introduction to Behavioral Finance 24 (2000).) This emphasis on
-16-
the rarity of efficient markets, grounded in the concept of
fundamental value efficiency, would have the likely effect of
making it unduly difficult to establish the fraud-on-the-market
presumption of reliance.
The district court was right to worry about these
implications of Defendants' efficiency arguments; it did not err by
rejecting Defendants' proposed definition of market efficiency
requiring consistency with fundamental value. By drawing on the
standard of efficiency in Cammer and holding that "a share's market
price [must] reflect publicly available information, not . . .
perfectly and correctly incorporate it," the district court adopted
the correct standard of efficiency. We must now decide whether the
court correctly applied this standard in determining that the
Xcelera market was efficient.
III.
A. Level of Inquiry
In evaluating whether the Xcelera market was efficient,
the district court considered the "persuasive and widely followed"
factors enumerated in Cammer. Xcelera, No. 00-11649-RWZ, at 5.
These factors are: (1) the stock's average trading volume; (2) the
number of securities analysts that followed and reported on the
stock; (3) the presence of market makers and arbitrageurs; (4) the
-17-
company's eligibility to file a Form S-3 Registration Statement9;
and (5) a cause-and-effect relationship, over time, between
unexpected corporate events or financial releases and an immediate
response in stock price. Cammer, 711 F. Supp. at 1286-87. These
factors provide useful evidence from which market efficiency may be
inferred, and are therefore relevant to a district court's
determination of whether a market is efficient. As we noted in
PolyMedica, however, these factors are not exhaustive. No. 05-
1220, slip op. (citing Unger, 401 F.3d at 323, 325 (noting that
Cammer factors are not exhaustive, and are "an analytical tool,"
not "a checklist")).
Crediting Plaintiffs' expert analysis, the district court
concluded, without further discussion of the factors, "that the
stock's trading volume was high; Xcelera received the attention of
the press and analysts as well as the participation of
sophisticated investors; there were no undue limits to arbitrage,
and that the stock price did respond to information." Xcelera, No.
00-11649-RWZ, at 5. Plaintiffs argue that the district court
correctly determined that these factors were satisfied and that the
Xcelera market was therefore efficient. Defendants contend that
9
Companies permitted by the SEC to file an S-3 Registration
Statement, an abbreviated prospectus requiring fewer disclosures
than Forms S-1 or S-2, are those which meet the $75 million market
capitalization requirement and have filed reports with the SEC for
twelve consecutive months. 17 C.F.R. § 239.13 (2003).
-18-
the district court's concise analysis of market efficiency is
inconsistent with the searching inquiry demanded by Rule 23.
We disagree. As Plaintiffs point out, the district court
received and reviewed hundreds of pages of briefing and exhibits
focused on the issue of market efficiency, received multiple
affidavits from experts on both sides and heard two days of
testimony from those experts and arguments from counsel regarding
market efficiency. In holding that Xcelera's market was efficient,
the court specifically credited the testimony of Plaintiffs' expert
over that of Defendants' expert, noting Xcelera's satisfaction of
the Cammer factors and rejecting Defendants' evidence that market
price did not "perfectly and correctly" incorporate publicly
available information. This is not a case where the district court
"simply presumed the facts in favor of an efficient market" based
on "bare allegations" raised in the plaintiff's complaint. Unger,
401 F.3d at 323, 325.
Here, the district court properly "engaged in a case-
specific analysis that went well beyond the pleadings," weighing
the competing evidence concerning market efficiency and offering a
succinct explanation of its determination that the fraud-on-the-
market presumption should apply to this class action. PolyMedica,
05-1220, slip op. (quoting Waste Mgmt. Holdings, Inc. v. Mowbray,
208 F.3d 288, 297 (1st Cir. 2000)). The district court was not
required to explain itself in greater detail. The more important
-19-
issue is whether the evidence supports its determination to apply
the presumption.
B. The Cammer Factors
1. Cause-and-Effect Relationship
Starting with the fifth, and in many ways, the most
important, Cammer factor, Plaintiffs contend that the district
court correctly found a historical cause-and-effect relationship
between company disclosures and an immediate response in stock
price. This relationship is, of course, "the essence of an
efficient market and the foundation for the fraud on the market
theory." Cammer, 711 F. Supp. at 1287. In the absence of such a
relationship, there is little assurance that information is being
absorbed into the market and reflected in its price. To
demonstrate the existence of a cause-and-effect relationship
between corporate information and stock price, Plaintiffs' expert
presented the results of a sophisticated event study analyzing how
Xcelera stock price reacted to company-specific events.10
Plaintiffs' study lists more than forty separate instances, thirty-
10
In addition to company-specific events, the study also analyzed
how Xcelera's stock price reacted to information in the industry
and in the general stock market (the NASDAQ, which is "the largest
electronic, screen-based market in the world"). PolyMedica, No.
05-1220, slip op. (internal quotation marks and citation omitted).
Plaintiffs' expert found that the movements of Xcelera's stock
price correlated with the movements of a sampling of other Internet
companies and with the NASDAQ as well, thereby further indicating
that "Xcelera's common stock price is efficiently reacting to
public information."
-20-
six of which occurred during the Class Period, in which Xcelera
stock price rose or fell (in several cases, by more than 50%, and
in one case, rose by more than 100%) within one day11 of the release
of company-specific information.
For instance, on April 1, 1999, Xcelera's stock price
increased 194% following an announcement that Xcelera had purchased
a majority interest in Mirror Image that day; on December 21, 1999,
following the announcement of Hewlett-Packard's $32 million
investment in Xcelera that day, Xcelera's stock increased 20%; a
glowing report in the Gilder Technology Report on February 12, 2000
caused Xcelera stock price to increase 42% on that day; and on July
11
In addition to a one-day window, Plaintiffs' event study lists,
as a control, the effect of company-specific information over
longer windows of two, three, and five days, respectively. For
example, following the announcement on March 22, 2000 that Exodus
would invest $637.5 million in Mirror Image, Xcelera's stock price
increased by 24% on that day. According to the event study, this
information accounted for a 23% increase in price two days after
the announcement, a 25% increase after three days, and a 23%
increase after five days. Defendants argue that the two- and five-
day (and presumably, the three-day) windows are inconsistent with
the requirement that an efficient market must rapidly reflect all
publicly available information. However, because Plaintiffs' event
study captures the same-day reaction of Xcelera's stock price to
company-specific events, Defendants' arguments concerning the
multi-day windows are unavailing. See Jonathan R. Macey et al.,
Lessons from Financial Economics: Materiality, Reliance, and
Extending the Reach of Basic v. Levinson, 77 Va. L. Rev. 1017, 1031
(1991) (stating that "financial economists often define the event
period as the two-day period consisting of the announcement day and
the following day"); see also Lehocky v. Tidel Techs., Inc., 220
F.R.D. 491, 506-07 (S.D. Tex. 2004) (concluding that plaintiff's
expert's event study using two-day window was "sufficient to
demonstrate, for class certification purposes, that a cause and
effect relationship between company-specific announcements and
stock price may exist").
-21-
13, 2000, the day Lazard Freres released a negative analyst report
on Xcelera, the stock price dropped 19%. Conversely, Plaintiffs'
expert also found that re-releases of old information, such as
secondary announcements about acquisitions or new investments,
resulted in only a modest stock price reaction or no reaction at
all. Based on these findings, Plaintiffs' expert concluded that
the Xcelera market reacted strongly – both positively and
negatively – to new information concerning the company (including,
but not limited to, disclosures at issue in this case).
Defendants argue that Plaintiffs' reliance upon various
news events to demonstrate this cause-and-effect relationship was
an exercise in post-hoc logic. In support of this argument,
Defendants cite to the Fifth Circuit’s decision in Unger, in which
the court concluded that such post-hoc reasoning, without
supporting expert statistical analysis, failed to take into account
the many other factors that could affect stock price. 401 F.3d at
324. In that case, however, the plaintiffs offered only "sketchy"
evidence of a cause-and-effect relationship, including "one-sided
affidavits, and unexplained Internet printouts," and provided no
expert statistical evidence whatsoever. Id. at 320, 325.
Plaintiffs argue that in this case, by contrast,
Plaintiffs' expert submitted an event study which "sought to
identify all or nearly all of the news and information" pertaining
to Xcelera – whether "statistically significant" or not – "in the
-22-
form of published articles, press releases, reports, news bulletins
and financial filings of Xcelera," for the proposed Class Period.
As noted above, in addition to this company-specific information,
Plaintiffs' event study included a determination of how Xcelera
stock price reacted to general-market and industry-specific
information, the kind of information the court found lacking in
Unger. Id. at 325 (stating that statistical evidence touching on
"the daily market average; national, local and industry-specific
economic news; [and] competitors' activities" may be helpful to
determination of efficiency). Plaintiffs' expert also supported
his event study with two affidavits, and provided testimony at a
two-day hearing devoted, in part, to the findings of the event
study.
2. The Stock's Average Trading Volume
Plaintiffs presented evidence that the average weekly
trading volume for Xcelera stock, that is, the number of
outstanding shares being traded on a weekly basis, was high. A
high average weekly trading volume suggests market efficiency since
it implies "significant investor interest in the company" and "a
likelihood that many investors are executing trades on the basis of
newly available or disseminated corporate information." Cammer,
711 F. Supp. at 1286. Plaintiffs demonstrated that the average
daily trading volume for Xcelera stock exceeded 1,000,000 shares
per day throughout the Class Period. Put another way, the average
-23-
daily trading volume represented more than 4% of approximately 27.5
million total outstanding shares – well above the 1% or 2% figures
suggested by several courts as the benchmark for supporting a
presumption of efficiency. See, e.g., O'Neil v. Apel, 165 F.R.D.
479, 508 (W.D. Mich. 1996); Cammer, 711 F. Supp. at 1293.
Defendants argue that Plaintiffs overstate the trading
volume of Xcelera shares by using split-adjusted shares12 as opposed
to the smaller number of actual (unadjusted) shares. For instance,
Defendants object to Plaintiffs' calculation of the daily trading
volume for August 10, 1999 using the 9,600 split-adjusted shares
traded that day, instead of the only 400 unadjusted shares traded
that day. Yet Defendants do not cite any authority for the
proposition that Plaintiffs may not adjust for stock splits in
order to derive a uniform trading volume for the Class Period.
3. Number of Securities Analysts
Both parties agree that the greater the number of
securities analysts following and reporting on a company's stock,
12
Xcelera's stock underwent several stock splits throughout the
Class Period. A stock split refers to "[t]he issuance of two or
more new shares in exchange for each old share without changing the
proportional ownership interests of each shareholder," thereby
"lower[ing] the price per share and thus mak[ing] the stock more
attractive to potential investors." Black's Law Dictionary (8th
ed. 2004). For example, Xcelera's 2-for-1 stock split on September
30, 1999 would have given an owner of 100 shares of Xcelera stock
a total of 200 shares, or two shares for each share previously
owned. In order to establish a uniform trading volume for the
Class Period, which contained multiple stock splits, Plaintiffs
adjusted their calculation of trading volume by taking into account
all splits that had occurred over the Class Period.
-24-
the greater the likelihood that information released by a company
is being relied upon by investors. As the court in Cammer noted,
the existence of a significant number of analysts implies that
company reports are "closely reviewed by investment professionals,
who would in turn make buy/sell recommendations to client
investors." 711 F. Supp. at 1286. The parties also agree that
only one analyst followed Xcelera's stock and issued only one
report during the Class Period – far fewer than the fifteen
research reports on the company at issue in Cammer, whose market
was found to be efficient, id. at 183.
Defendants argue that one analyst is not enough, see
O'Neil, 165 F.R.D. at 501 (stating that "[m]ajor corporations are
closely followed by hundreds of securities analysts throughout the
country"), and that the news coverage relied upon by Plaintiffs was
more "journalistic commentary" than the kind of "analysis that
would help investors understand the published information about the
company and invest on that basis." In addition, Defendants argue
that the Xcelera market lacked the presence of sophisticated
institutional investors who "search out, distill, trade on, and
disseminate information affecting an issuer" and who are thus vital
to an efficient market. See Lehocky, 220 F.R.D. at 508 (crediting
plaintiff's expert's assertion that "there is a general
understanding that a high level of institutional interest in a
security serves to increase the efficiency of the market").
-25-
Notwithstanding the presence of only one securities
analyst, Plaintiffs contend that information about Xcelera was
widely distributed through "news articles, press releases,
television interviews and the Company's SEC filings," and indirect
coverage from numerous influential brokerage firms reporting on
other Internet and technology stocks. This media attention,
Plaintiffs argue, more than made up for the lack of securities
analysts. See Cheney v. Cyberguard Corp., 213 F.R.D. 484, 499
(S.D. Fla. 2003) (stating that significant number of news items
featuring defendant company "indicat[ed] that information regarding
[the company] may have been widely distributed, which would support
a finding of efficiency"). In addition, in response to Defendants'
charge that the Xcelera market lacked institutional investors,
Plaintiffs point to the fact that two major institutions – Hewlett
Packard and Exodus Communications – made significant investments in
Xcelera, and that for the last six months of the Class Period, at
least thirty other institutional investors also invested in
Xcelera.
4. Number of Market-Makers and Arbitrageurs
A market-maker is "[o]ne who helps establish a market for
securities by reporting bid-and-asked quotations" (the price a
buyer will pay for a security and the price a seller will sell a
security), Black's Law Dictionary (8th ed. 2004), and who "stand[s]
ready to buy or sell at these publicly quoted prices," Lehocky, 220
-26-
F.R.D. at 508 n.24. According to Plaintiffs' expert, a market-
maker, more particularly, "is a brokerage firm or special
securities firm that actively buys and sells stocks on its own
account with the intention of holding them for a relatively short
period of time so as to make a market."
While the court in Cammer found that market-makers (and
arbitrageurs13) contribute to market efficiency by "react[ing]
swiftly to company news and reported financial results by buying or
selling stock and driving it to a changed price level," 711 F.
Supp. at 1287, Defendants argue that the mere existence of market-
makers, without more, is not meaningful. See O'Neil, 165 F.R.D. at
502 (stating that "it is impossible to accord much significance to
the number of market makers, until one knows the volume of shares
that they committed to trade, the volume of shares they actually
traded, and the prices at which they did so"); see also id. (noting
that "the economic literature has criticized reliance upon the
number of marker makers as an indicator of efficiency," and citing
study which found "no empirical correlation between the number of
market makers and the efficiency of the market"). Defendants
13
Neither Cammer nor other courts addressing this factor
distinguish between market-makers and arbitrageurs, but instead
refer to the two somewhat interchangeably. As we noted in
PolyMedica, "arbitrageurs" are professional investors who exploit
price differences in different markets by buying and selling
identical securities in those markets. Id. While arbitrageurs are
distinct from market-makers, who seek to facilitate trading in a
particular security, both play an important role in keeping markets
efficient.
-27-
contend that Plaintiffs' evidence establishes only the presence of
market-makers in the Xcelera market, not whether they in fact
contributed to market efficiency by "buying or selling Xcelera's
stock and driving it to a price reflective of all information
bearing on value."14
Plaintiffs contend that more than twenty market-makers
participated in the market for Xcelera stock, with seven market-
makers trading over one million shares each in the final quarter of
the Class Period. They say that this evidence demonstrates not
only that there was a sufficient number of market-makers present to
facilitate trading, see, e.g., Cheney, 213 F.R.D. 484, 500 (S.D.
Fla. 2003) (holding that presence of between fifteen and nineteen
market-makers weighed in favor of finding of market efficiency)
(citing Cammer, 711 F. Supp. at 1283 n.30 (finding that presence of
eleven market-makers weighed in favor of efficiency)), but also
14
In addition, Defendants argue that Plaintiffs offered no evidence
whatsoever for the presence of arbitrageurs in the Xcelera market.
Defendants contend that the absence of arbitrageurs demonstrates
that there were limits on the ability of rational investors to
engage in short sales, thereby "push[ing] prices to incorporate all
publicly available information." Plaintiffs argue that Defendants'
evidence of constraints on short sales relates to rationality, not
efficiency, and thus has no place in the Cammer analysis. (We
address below Defendants' evidence of irrationality in the Xcelera
market). In any event, Plaintiffs contend, "during the Class
Period investors were able to and did sell Xcelera's shares short,
and the number of people shorting Xcelera stock grew" during most
of the Class Period.
-28-
that these market-makers were in fact conducting trades in
significant volume.15
C. The District Court's Fraud-on-the-Market Determination
Although Defendants insist that the evidence we have
summarized here did not support the district court's finding of an
efficient market on the basis of the Cammer factors, we disagree.
As we have already noted, "the determination of whether a market is
efficient is a fact-dominated inquiry. Therefore, deferential
clear-error review applies to that determination." The district
court was entitled to resolve the evidentiary conflicts in favor of
Plaintiffs. There was no clear error in the district court's
evaluation of the evidence under Cammer.
Anticipating the obstacles posed by clear-error review,
Defendants attempt to inject into the clear-error analysis an
argument that is more akin to a claim of legal error. Defendants
argue that even if the Cammer factors were met, the district court
should have concluded that Xcelera's market was inefficient based
on other factors rejected by the court. According to Defendants,
the district court erroneously applied the Cammer factors in
15
While listing "eligibility to file an S-3 Registration Statement"
as one of the five factors "that could give rise to an inference of
an efficient market," the district court chose not to address this
Cammer factor. Although both parties invoke this factor in support
of their respective positions, the district court did not err in
foregoing analysis of this factor in favor of Cammer's other
factors, and, therefore, we need not reach the parties' arguments
regarding this factor.
-29-
isolation, rather than viewing them as part of a broader analysis
of the structure of the Xcelera market. "[T]he ultimate question
of market efficiency," Defendants argue, "is structural, and [the
Cammer factors] are only partial indicators of market structure."
In order to determine whether the Xcelera market was efficient,
Defendants argue that the district court should have analyzed
whether Xcelera's market behaved "rationally".
Defendants contend that Xcelera's market was dominated by
irrational investors "not basing their decisions on analysis . . .
of the fundamental value of the stock in light of all currently
available information." Defendants further contend that
constraints on short sales in the Xcelera market prevented
arbitrageurs from acting on analyses that "push[] prices into line
with all information bearing on the security's fundamental value."16
Lastly, Defendants argue that Xcelera's stock price behaved
irrationally – reaching levels "that were orders of magnitude too
16
Defendants offer several pieces of evidence in support of the
existence of limits on capacity for arbitrage, including: high
costs of borrowing Xcelera stock to sell short (i.e., low "rebate
rates"); violations of put-call parity in the options market,
which, according to Defendants, "necessarily imply a limit to
arbitrage and, in particular, a short sales constraint"; a "high
turnover" of individual investors, indicating that investors were
buying and selling Xcelera stock within a relatively brief time,
and thereby not loaning their shares to short-sellers; a high level
of existing short interest, which, Defendants argue, implies
constraints on other would-be short-sellers; a high bid-ask spread,
suggesting that stock is too expensive to trade; and high risks
faced by short-sellers in light of the rapid rise in Xcelera's
stock price during the Class Period.
-30-
high, based on any possible range of future earnings growth, to be
consistent with an efficient market"; reacting to "minor"
developments in ways greatly disproportionate to the economic
significance of such developments; and "fluctuat[ing] wildly"
throughout the Class Period.17
As we stated in PolyMedica,
[t]he question of how much evidence of efficiency is
necessary in order for a court to accept the fraud-on-
the-market presumption of reliance at the class-
certification stage is . . . one of degree. District
courts must draw these lines sensibly, mindful of the
fact that while evidence of fundamental value may be
relevant to the determination of informational
efficiency, other more accessible and manageable evidence
may be sufficient at the certification stage to establish
the basic facts that permit a court to apply the fraud-
on-the-market presumption.
No. 05-1220, slip op. Here, focusing on the Cammer factors, the
district court concluded that Plaintiffs demonstrated the basic
facts necessary to justify a presumption of reliance at the class-
certification stage. The court's determination that "Defendant's
[sic] expert focuses too much on the rationality of the market, as
opposed to its efficiency," was an appropriate exercise of its
discretion. Xcelera, No. 00-11649-RWZ, at 5. As discussed above,
17
In order to demonstrate that Xcelera's stock price behaved
irrationally, Defendants offered the following: a comparison of
the price movements of Xcelera stock and those of the Dow Jones and
other Internet stocks from the same period; an analysis of whether
Xcelera's stock "could reasonably be said to reflect the
fundamental value of [its] assets"; evidence of "extraordinarily
high" volatility in Xcelera's stock price; and an analysis of
company-specific events to which Xcelera's stock price failed to
respond rationally.
-31-
for purposes of establishing the fraud-on-the-market presumption of
reliance, market efficiency does not require that a market be
"rational, i.e., consistent with fundamental value." While
evidence of irrationality in the Xcelera market – i.e., the
presence of irrational investors and limits to arbitrage which
prevented market price from reflecting fundamental value – may have
been "relevant to the extent it raises questions about
informational efficiency," the district court did not err in
finding "other more accessible and manageable evidence" sufficient
to establish the presumption of reliance.
The district court's consideration of four of the Cammer
factors, and its rejection of the rationality factors advanced by
Defendants, was thus proper for purposes of determining market
efficiency. Because there is no "magic number" of factors for
determining efficiency, we leave it to the district court in the
first instance to decide which factors and how many factors it will
consider, emphasizing that the ultimate efficiency determination is
subject to clear error review. Obviously, if the district court
considers too few factors or too little evidence, the determination
will not survive clear error review. That did not happen here.
-32-
IV.
For the foregoing reasons, the district court's order
certifying the class and the insider trading subclass is affirmed.
Costs are taxed against Defendants.
So ordered.
-33-