United States Court of Appeals
For the First Circuit
No. 09-1169
FAMILY WINEMAKERS OF CALIFORNIA, STEPHEN J. POOR, III, M.D.,
GERALD C. LEADER,
Plaintiffs, Appellees,
v.
EDDIE J. JENKINS, in his official capacity as Chairman of the
Massachusetts Alcoholic Beverages Control Commission; ROBERT H.
CRONIN and SUSAN CORCORAN, in their official capacities as
Associate Commissioners of the Massachusetts Alcoholic Beverages
Control Commission,
Defendants, Appellants.
ON APPEAL FROM THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
FOR THE DISTRICT OF MASSACHUSETTS
[Hon. Rya W. Zobel, U.S. District Judge]
Before
Lynch, Chief Judge,
Stahl, Circuit Judge, and DiClerico,* District Judge.
David Hadas, Assistant Attorney General, with whom Martha
Coakley, Attorney General of the State of Massachusetts, and Thomas
A. Barnico, Assistant Attorney General, were on brief for the
appellants.
Michael D. Madigan, with whom Stephen M. Diamond and Madigan,
Dahl & Harlan, P.A., were on brief for the National Beer
Wholesalers Association, amicus curiae.
Lisa Hibner Tavani, Deputy Attorney General, with whom Anne
Milgram, Attorney General of the State of New Jersey, and Lorinda
*
Of the District of New Hampshire, sitting by designation.
Lasus, Deputy Attorney General were on brief for the states of New
Jersey, Ohio, Rhode Island, Utah, and Wyoming, amici curiae.
Evan T. Lawson, with whom Michael Williams, Lawson & Weitzen,
LLP, and Louis A. Cassis were on brief for Wine & Spirits
Wholesalers of Massachusetts, Inc., Wine & Spirits Wholesalers of
America, Inc., American Beverage Licensees, and Sazerac Company,
amici curiae.
Tracy K. Genesen, with whom Kenneth W. Starr, Micah C.E.
Osgood, Gerald J. Caruso, Susan E. Engel, and Elizabeth M. Locke
were on brief for the appellees.
Bruce L. Hay for Wine Institute, WineAmerica, Oregon
Winegrowers Association, Virginia Wineries Association, Washington
Wine Institute, Madera Vintners Association, Monterey County
Vintners and Growers Association, and Napa Valley Vintners, amici
curiae.
January 14, 2010
LYNCH, Chief Judge. Massachusetts officials appeal from
an injunction against a 2006 Massachusetts statute establishing
differential methods by which wineries distribute wines in
Massachusetts, Mass. Gen. Laws ch. 138, § 19F. The district court
enjoined enforcement of § 19F on the ground that the law
discriminates against interstate commerce in violation of the
Commerce Clause of the United States Constitution. See Family
Winemakers of Cal. v. Jenkins, No. 1:06-cv-11682-RWZ at 17-28 (D.
Mass. Nov. 19, 2008) (order granting summary judgment).
We briefly summarize the basis for the lawsuit, the
issues presented, and our resolution of them before turning to the
supporting analysis. Section 19F only allows "small" wineries,
defined by Massachusetts as those producing 30,000 gallons or less
of grape wine a year, to obtain a "small winery shipping license."
This license allows them to sell their wines in Massachusetts in
three ways: by shipping directly to consumers, through wholesaler
distribution, and through retail distribution. All of
Massachusetts's wineries are "small" wineries. Some out-of-state
wineries also meet this definition.
Wines from "small" Massachusetts wineries compete with
wines from "large" wineries, which Massachusetts has defined as
those producing more than 30,000 gallons of grape wine annually.
These "large" wineries must choose between relying upon wholesalers
to distribute their wines in-state or applying for a "large winery
shipping license" to sell directly to Massachusetts consumers.
-3-
They cannot, by law, use both methods to sell their wines in
Massachusetts, and they cannot sell wines directly to retailers
under either option. No "large" wineries are located inside
Massachusetts.
Plaintiffs, a group of California winemakers and
Massachusetts residents, assert § 19F was designed with the
purpose, and has the effect, of advantaging Massachusetts wineries
to the detriment of those wineries that produce 98 percent of the
country's wine, in violation of the Commerce Clause. Massachusetts
defends § 19F on the basis that its law has neither a
discriminatory purpose nor a discriminatory effect. Massachusetts
has not argued in its briefs that there are no legitimate
alternative methods of regulation to serve § 19F's asserted
purposes. Massachusetts also argues that under the Twenty-first
Amendment, state laws are immunized from Commerce Clause scrutiny
unless the laws discriminate on their face.
The primary question before us is whether § 19F
unconstitutionally discriminates against interstate commerce in
-4-
light of both the Commerce Clause,1 art. I, § 8, cl. 3, and § 2 of
the Twenty-first Amendment.2
It is clear that § 2 of the Twenty-first Amendment does
not protect state alcohol laws that explicitly favor in-state over
out-of-state interests from invalidation under the Commerce Clause.
Granholm v. Heald, 544 U.S. 460, 489 (2005). But § 19F is neutral
on its face; it does not, by its terms, allow only Massachusetts
wineries to distribute their wines through a combination of direct
shipping, wholesaler distribution, and retail sales. Section 19F
instead uses a very particular gallonage cap to confer this benefit
upon "small" as opposed to "large" wineries.
We hold that § 19F violates the Commerce Clause because
the effect of its particular gallonage cap is to change the
competitive balance between in-state and out-of-state wineries in
1
The Commerce Clause vests Congress with the authority to
"regulate Commerce . . . among the several States." U.S. Const.
art. I, § 8, cl. 3. This grant of exclusive federal power carries
an implicit consequence for states' powers. When states regulate
commerce within their own borders, they cannot enact laws that
discriminate against out-of-state economic interests in favor of
in-state competitors absent congressional authorization or some
other source of constitutional authority. Or. Waste Sys., Inc. v.
Dep't of Envtl. Quality, 511 U.S. 93, 98 (1994). This aspect of
the Commerce Clause is commonly referred to as the "dormant
commerce clause" because its limitations upon states are not stated
in the text.
2
Section 2 of the Twenty-first Amendment states that
"[t]he transportation or importation into any State, Territory, or
possession of the United States for delivery or use therein of
intoxicating liquors, in violation of the laws thereof, is hereby
prohibited." It thereby gives states certain limited authority to
regulate the transportation, importation, and use of alcohol within
their borders notwithstanding the effects on interstate commerce.
-5-
a way that benefits Massachusetts's wineries and significantly
burdens out-of-state competitors. Massachusetts has used its
30,000 gallon grape wine cap to expand the distribution options
available to "small" wineries, including all Massachusetts
wineries, but not to similarly situated "large" wineries, all of
which are outside Massachusetts. The advantages afforded to
"small" wineries by these expanded distribution options bear little
relation to the market challenges caused by the relative sizes of
the wineries. Section 19F's statutory context, legislative
history, and other factors also yield the unavoidable conclusion
that this discrimination was purposeful. Nor does § 19F serve any
legitimate local purpose that cannot be furthered by a non-
discriminatory alternative.
We further hold that the Twenty-first Amendment cannot
save § 19F from invalidation under the Commerce Clause. Section 2
of the Twenty-first Amendment does not exempt or otherwise immunize
facially neutral but discriminatory state alcohol laws like § 19F
from scrutiny under the Commerce Clause. We affirm the grant of
injunctive relief.
I. Facts
We engage in de novo review both because the district
court entered summary judgment and because the issues presented are
ones of law. There is no disagreement on the material facts. See
Fed. R. Civ. P. 56(c); see also Sullivan v. City of Springfield,
561 F.3d 7, 14 (1st Cir. 2009).
-6-
The ratification of the Twenty-first Amendment ended
Prohibition and gave states substantial control over the regulation
of alcoholic beverages. Most states, including Massachusetts, then
imposed a three-tier system to control the sale of alcoholic
beverages within their territories. The hallmark of the three-tier
system is a rigid, tightly regulated separation between producers,
wholesalers, and retailers of alcoholic beverages. Producers can
ordinarily sell alcoholic beverages only to licensed in-state
wholesalers. Mass. Gen. Laws ch. 138, §§ 2 and 19. Wholesalers
then must obtain licenses to sell to retailers. Id. § 18.
Retailers, which include stores, taverns, restaurants, and bars,
must in turn obtain licenses to sell to consumers or to serve
alcohol on their premises. Id. §§ 12, 15. Recently, as to wine,
Massachusetts has adjusted the separation between these three
tiers, as we describe below.
The structure of the usual three-tier system is commonly
described as an hourglass, with wholesalers at the constriction
point. There are thousands of producers nationwide, a handful of
licensed Massachusetts wholesalers, and approximately ten thousand
licensed retailers in Massachusetts. See Commonwealth of
Massachusetts Alcoholic Beverages Control Commission, Licensing,
http://www.mass.gov/abcc/ licensing/licensing.htm.
The three-tier system has had a particularly pronounced
effect on wineries' access to the Massachusetts market. The
economic incentives created by the three-tier system, in
-7-
conjunction with the structure of the wine industry, severely
limited certain wineries' ability to sell their wines in
Massachusetts.
In 2006, the year § 19F was enacted, 5,350 registered
wineries in the United States produced a total of 646,395,818
gallons of wine, which includes both grape wine and fruit wine
production. Almost all of the country's wine production and sales
come from a small number of wineries. In 2006, the five largest
wineries in the U.S. produced approximately 70 percent of the
country's wine. The country's thirty largest wineries comprised
approximately 92 percent of the market, and each produced between
680,000 and 150 million gallons per year. The rest of the
commercial market--the 3,540 wineries which produce between one and
680,000 gallons per year--competed for 8 percent of the market
share. Finally, 1,780 wineries produced less than one gallon of
wine per year and had virtually zero percent of the market share.3
The concentration of wine production among the largest
producers is driven by another feature of the wine industry: there
are, broadly speaking, two categories of wine, high-volume,
3
These figures were derived from industry statistics
tracked by Wine Business Monthly and from data provided by the
federal Alcohol and Tobacco Tax and Trade Bureau (TTB) for 2006,
both of which are publicly available and were introduced either in
the record or by various amici. See The Top 30 Wine Companies of
2006, available at http://www.winebusiness.com/wbm/?gogetArticle
&dataID=46697; see also Gina Riekhof and Michael Sykuta, Politics,
Economics, and the Regulation of Direct Interstate Shipping in the
Wine Industry, April 2004, Working Paper No. 2003-04 at 7,
available at http://cori.missouri.edu/wps.
-8-
lower-cost wines and low-volume, higher-quality, higher-priced
boutique wines. The largest wineries produce millions of gallons
of wine per year because they have generally specialized in the
former, but not to the exclusion of the latter. Wineries smaller
than the largest producers have tended to specialize in low-volume
boutique wines, which can be produced with a relatively small
quantity of grapes and a much lower initial outlay of resources.
At least until the current recession, consumer demand for boutique
wines had grown exponentially, fueling a rise in the number of
smaller U.S. wineries (which include many wineries producing more
than 30,000 gallons annually). Fed. Trade Comm'n, Possible
Anticompetitive Barriers to E-Commerce: Wine 6 (2003), available at
http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/07/winereport2.pdf (hereinafter FTC
Report).
Under Massachusetts's former three-tier system, all
wineries could only distribute their wines through licensed
Massachusetts wholesalers, and 75 percent of the wine sold in
Massachusetts went through five wholesalers. This gave
wholesalers, not wineries, the balance of the bargaining power.
Wholesalers do not necessarily distribute a winery's entire range
of wines; they often distribute the wines most likely to be
profitable to them, which are lower-priced, high-volume wines.
Wholesalers make profits by selling wines to retailers at a markup.
The more a wine sells out at retail, generating more requests for
restocking, the more money a wholesaler makes. Wholesalers also
-9-
face fixed costs that do not depend on the price they pay to the
winery for the wine: they bear the costs of transportation,
storage, and handling. For these reasons, wineries producing
higher-priced, low-volume wines, whatever the gallonage output of
the winery, are less profitable and less likely to attract
wholesaler distribution.
The largest wineries, as the major producers of
lower-priced, high-volume wines, have been best able to attract
wholesalers. Only the country's fifty to one hundred largest
wineries have consistently secured wholesaler representation. For
most smaller wineries of whatever gallonage, which produce mostly
boutique wines, obtaining wholesaler representation has been
difficult, if not impossible. And even if a smaller winery
obtained wholesaler representation, wholesalers were likely to
distribute only one or two of its wines, limiting Massachusetts
consumers' access to particular wines.
Wineries have heralded direct shipping as a supplemental
avenue of distribution because of its economic advantages,
especially for wineries that do not rank among the fifty to one
hundred largest producers. Direct shipping lets consumers directly
order wines from the winery, with access to their full range of
wines, not just those a wholesaler is willing to distribute.
Direct shipping also avoids added steps in the distribution chain,
eliminating wholesaler and retailer price markups. See FTC Report
at 22-23.
-10-
Before 2005, § 19B, Massachusetts's farmer-winery
licensing law, on its face allowed only in-state wineries to obtain
licenses to combine distribution methods through wholesalers,
retailers, and direct shipping to consumers. Mass. Gen. Laws ch.
138, § 19B (2002). Five months after Granholm invalidated similar
facially discriminatory state laws, § 19B was held to be invalid
under the Commerce Clause. Stonington Vineyards v. Jenkins, No.
05-10982-JLT, slip op. at 1-2 (D. Mass. Oct. 5, 2005).
In 2006, the Massachusetts legislature enacted § 19F over
then-Governor Romney's veto. Section 19F does not distinguish on
its face between in-state and out-of-state wineries' eligibility
for direct shipping licenses, but instead distinguishes between
"small" or "large" wineries through the 30,000 gallon cap.
During floor debates, § 19F's sponsor summed up § 19F as
follows: "[W]ith the limitations that we are suggesting in the
legislation, we are really still giving an inherent advantage
indirectly to the local wineries." Likewise, the state senator
whose district included Massachusetts's then-largest winery
explained his qualified support for § 19F by stating that "the
agricultural industry here in Massachusetts is really strong and
should be preserved. And we do this . . . because we produce these
specialty goods, pick-your-own orchards and wineries." The senator
had another concern--that the winery in question, which primarily
produced fruit wine, "comes close to the 30,000 [gallon] production
limit" for "small" wineries and would likely soon exceed it because
-11-
"it's a winery that is growing . . . and certainly uses wholesalers
in other states." The senator urged modifications to § 19F because
"we should be promoting this kind of industry and not adopting
regulations, however inadvertently, that might take away the
advantage that the winery would have." The draft of § 19F was
amended shortly thereafter to exempt non-grape fruit wine
production from the 30,000 gallon cap, and that version was
enacted.4
To repeat, all wineries producing over 30,000 gallons of
wine--all of which are located outside Massachusetts--can apply for
a "large winery shipment license," which allows them to directly
sell and ship wine to consumers, but only if "the winery has not
contracted with or has not been represented by a wholesaler
licensed under section 18 for the preceding 6 months." Mass. Gen.
Laws ch. 138, § 19F(a). To the extent a choice is available at
all, under § 19F(a), "large" wineries can either choose to remain
4
Massachusetts tries to dismiss these statements as the
isolated and unrepresentative comments of a few legislators. But
such statements are precisely the kind of evidence the Supreme
Court has looked to in previous Commerce Clause cases challenging
a statute as discriminatory in purpose. See Minnesota v. Clover
Leaf Creamery Co., 449 U.S. 456, 465-68 (1981) (looking to a
senator's and representatives' statements during floor debates as
probative evidence of purpose); Hunt v. Wash. State Apple Adver.
Comm'n, 432 U.S. 333, 352 (1977) (pointing to a statement by a
single state commissioner as strong evidence of discriminatory
purpose).
Clearly the remarks of a single legislator are not controlling
and do not compel any conclusion that the remarks reflect
legislative intent. See Consumer Prod. Safety Comm'n v. GTE
Sylvania, Inc., 447 U.S. 102, 118 (1980). But they are evidence.
-12-
completely within the three-tier system and distribute their wines
solely through wholesalers, or they can completely opt out of the
three-tier system and sell their wines in Massachusetts exclusively
through direct shipping. They cannot do both. Wholesaler
distribution is also the only way "large" wineries can distribute
wines to retailers, including all Massachusetts restaurants and
bars. To put it differently, "large" wineries cannot distribute
directly to consumers except at the cost of giving up distribution
to retailers. By contrast, "small" wineries can simultaneously use
the traditional wholesaler distribution method, direct distribution
to retailers, and direct shipping to reach consumers.
The practical effects of the distinctions Massachusetts
has drawn are significant. In 2006, 637 U.S. wineries were "large"
under § 19F(a)'s definition. They produced between 30,001 and over
100 million gallons per year and accounted for 98 percent of all
wine produced in the United States. The thirty largest "large"
wineries represented 92 percent of the national market, while the
other 607 "large" wineries produced between 30,001 and 680,000
gallons per year, averaged slightly less than 60,000 gallons per
year, and made up approximately 6 percent of the U.S. wine
production market in 2006.
There were 4,713 "small" wineries in the United States in
2006, as the term "small" is defined by § 19F(b). Of these
wineries, 1,780--more than a third--produced less than one gallon
per year and had virtually no market share. The remaining 2,933
-13-
"small" wineries accounted for 2 percent of the total annual wine
production in the United States in 2006.5
In 2007, there were thirty-one wineries in Massachusetts,
all met § 19F(b)'s definition of "small," and approximately half of
these wineries produced fruit wine in addition to or in lieu of
traditional grape-based wines. Each produced between 200 and
24,000 gallons per year.6
II. Whether § 19F Discriminates against Interstate Commerce
The Commerce Clause prevents states from creating
protectionist barriers to interstate trade. See, e.g., Lewis v. BT
Inv. Managers, Inc., 447 U.S. 27, 35 (1980). Discrimination under
the Commerce Clause "means differential treatment of in-state and
out-of-state economic interests that benefits the former and
burdens the latter," as opposed to state laws that "regulate[]
5
We accept these facts as true, as both parties have
agreed upon them, although important gaps appear in these
statistics. TTB counted the number of wineries in the U.S. and
their total gallonage based on the records it keeps for the purpose
of levying a federal excise tax on "wine premises." See 27 C.F.R.
§ 24.100 (2009). These statistics do not precisely line up to the
"large" and "small" categories in § 19F, because TTB's statistics
do not distinguish between wines produced from grapes versus from
other fruits. Id. at § 24.10 (defining "wine premises" as places
where wine operations occur and "wine" to include both grape wine
and other fruit wines).
6
They collectively produced 235,690 gallons of wine in
2007, though Massachusetts's statistics do not say whether this is
all wine or just grape wine. While this was well under one tenth
of one percent of U.S. annual wine production, Massachusetts's wine
industry is in its early stages and is growing rapidly. See An
Economic Snapshot of the Mass. Winery Industry, Mass. Dep't of
Agriculture, Sept. 2008, available at http://www.mass.gov/agr/
facts/wine.htm.
-14-
evenhandedly with only incidental effects on interstate commerce,"
Or. Waste Sys., 511 U.S. at 99 (internal quotation marks omitted).
Plaintiffs bear the initial burden of showing discrimination.7 See
Cherry Hill Vineyard LLC v. Baldacci, 505 F.3d 28, 33 (1st Cir.
2007) (citing Hughes v. Oklahoma, 441 U.S. 322, 336 (1979)).
If plaintiffs meet their burden, then "a discriminatory
law is virtually per se invalid . . . and will survive only if it
advances a legitimate local purpose that cannot be adequately
served by reasonable non-discriminatory alternatives."8 Dep't of
Revenue v. Davis, 128 S. Ct. 1801, 1808 (2008) (citations omitted)
(internal quotation marks omitted). The state bears the burden of
showing legitimate local purposes and the lack of non-
discriminatory alternatives, and discriminatory state laws rarely
7
While the Supreme Court has said "[a] finding that state
legislation constitutes economic protectionism may be made on the
basis of either discriminatory purpose or discriminatory effect,"
Chem. Waste Mgmt., Inc. v. Hunt, 504 U.S. 334, 344 n.6 (1992)
(quoting Bacchus Imps., Ltd. v. Dias, 468 U.S. 263, 270 (1984))
(alteration in original) (citation omitted) (internal quotation
marks omitted), plaintiffs argue both are present, and we agree.
8
Though this standard is stringent, it is also quite
different from a standard requiring the state to demonstrate a
"compelling state interest" that cannot be served through a non-
discriminatory alternative. We reject plaintiffs' contention that
the "compelling interest" standard applies here and is required by
Maine v. Taylor, 477 U.S. 131 (1986). Maine v. Taylor, like
subsequent Supreme Court precedents, required states to demonstrate
only that the statute "serves a legitimate local purpose" that
"could not be served as well by available non-discriminatory
means." Id. at 138.
-15-
satisfy this exacting standard.9 See Camps Newfound/Owatonna, Inc.
v. Town of Harrison, 520 U.S. 564, 581-82 (1997).
We explain in more detail the arguments being made.
Plaintiffs argue that Massachusetts's choice of 30,000 gallons as
the demarcation point between "small" and "large" wineries, along
with the production exception for fruit wine, has both a
discriminatory effect and purpose. The discriminatory effect is
because § 19F's definition of "large" wineries encompasses the
wineries which produce 98 percent of all wine in the United States,
all of which are located out-of-state and all of which are deprived
of the benefits of combining distribution methods. All wines
produced in Massachusetts, on the other hand, are from "small"
wineries that can use multiple distribution methods. Plaintiffs
also say that Section 19F is discriminatory in purpose because the
gallonage cap's particular features, along with legislators'
statements and § 19F's process of enactment, show that § 19F's true
purpose was to ensure that Massachusetts's wineries obtained
advantages over their out-of-state counterparts. Plaintiffs also
argue that Massachusetts cannot meet its burden of justifying § 19F
because the law neither advances the three-tier system nor
9
Of course, even if the challenged law regulates in-state
and out-of-state interests even-handedly, it may still violate the
Commerce Clause if "the burden imposed on [interstate] commerce is
clearly excessive in relation to the putative local benefits" under
the test first set forth in Pike. Dep't of Revenue, 128 S. Ct. at
1808 (quoting Pike v. Bruce Church Inc., 397 U.S. 137, 142 (1970))
(alteration in original) (internal quotation marks omitted).
-16-
effectively assists small wineries in ways that available non-
discriminatory alternatives could not. Finally, in the
alternative, plaintiffs contend that § 19F impermissibly burdens
interstate commerce under Pike even if it is not discriminatory.
Massachusetts counters that § 19F is not discriminatory
in effect because most "small" wineries are located out-of-state.
It says this proves that § 19F disproportionately benefits out-of-
state, not in-state, wineries, especially since there are far more
"small" § 19F(b) wineries in the country than "large" § 19F(a)
ones. Massachusetts argues that § 19F is not discriminatory in
purpose because its aim is to level the economic playing field for
all "small" wineries irrespective of where they are located, and
the district court erroneously looked to comments by individual
legislators, lobbyists, and intermediate steps in § 19F's process
of enactment to find discriminatory purpose.10 Finally,
Massachusetts says that § 19F poses no undue burden on interstate
commerce under Pike and any such burden is surpassed by the local
benefits of greater competition and consumer choice.
We explain below our reasons for rejecting
Massachusetts's arguments. Because we hold that § 19F
discriminates against interstate commerce, it is unnecessary for us
to decide whether § 19F would also violate the Commerce Clause
10
Massachusetts further asserted, but only at oral
argument, that there are no other feasible means of giving small
wineries a limited exemption from the three-tier system than
through § 19F.
-17-
under Pike. See C & A Carbone, Inc. v. Town of Clarkstown, 511
U.S. 383, 390 (1994).
A. Section 19F is Discriminatory in Effect
A state law is discriminatory in effect when, in
practice, it affects similarly situated entities in a market by
imposing disproportionate burdens on out-of-state interests and
conferring advantages upon in-state interests. Or. Waste Sys., 511
U.S. at 99 (defining discrimination); see also Gen. Motors Corp. v.
Tracy, 519 U.S. 278, 298 (1997) ("[A]ny notion of discrimination
assumes a comparison of substantially similar entities.") (footnote
omitted).
One such form of discrimination is plainly when "the
effect of a state regulation is to cause local goods to constitute
a larger share, and goods with an out-of-state source to constitute
a smaller share, of the total sales in the market." Exxon Corp. v.
Governor of Maryland, 437 U.S. 117, 126 n.16 (1978). State laws
that alter conditions of competition to favor in-state interests
over out-of-state competitors in a market have long been subject to
invalidation. See, e.g., Hunt, 432 U.S. at 350-51; Polar Ice Cream
& Creamery Co. v. Andrews, 375 U.S. 361, 376-77 (1964); Baldwin v.
G.A.F. Seelig, Inc., 294 U.S. 511, 519 (1935); see also Baldacci,
505 F.3d at 36 (explaining the doctrine); Houlton Citizens'
Coalition v. Town of Houlton, 175 F.3d 178, 188-89 (1st Cir. 1999)
(same).
-18-
Plaintiffs must present evidence as to why the law
discriminates in practice. See Baldacci, 505 F.3d at 36-37.11
Here, the totality of the evidence introduced by plaintiffs
demonstrates that § 19F's preferential treatment of "small"
wineries that produce 30,000 gallons or less of grape wine is
discriminatory. Its effect is to significantly alter the terms of
competition between in-state and out-of-state wineries to the
detriment of the out-of-state wineries that produce 98 percent of
the country's wine.
Section 19F confers a clear competitive advantage to
"small" wineries, which include all Massachusetts's wineries, and
creates a comparative disadvantage for "large" wineries, none of
which are in Massachusetts. "Small" wineries that obtain a
§ 19F(b) license can use direct shipping to consumers, retailer
distribution, and wholesaler distribution simultaneously.
Combining these distribution methods allows "small" wineries to
sell their full range of wines at maximum efficiency because they
serve complementary markets. "Small" wineries that produce
higher-volume wines can continue distributing those wines through
wholesaler relationships. They can obtain new markets for all
11
Baldacci only addressed the kind of showing required when
a statute is challenged as discriminatory in effect but is
concededly non-discriminatory in purpose. 505 F.3d at 36. We did
not address whether a lesser showing might suffice when a law is
allegedly discriminatory in both effect and purpose. We do not
reach this question because even under the standard in Baldacci,
plaintiffs have shown § 19F is discriminatory in effect.
-19-
their wines by distributing their wines directly to retailers,
including individual bars, restaurants, and stores. They can also
use direct shipping to offer their full range of wines directly to
Massachusetts consumers, resulting in greater overall sales.
Combining these methods also lowers "small" wineries'
distribution costs because they can choose which method or
combination of methods will be most cost-effective for a particular
wine. As the parties' briefs highlight, this produces important
synergies. "Small" wineries' use of retail distribution increases
brand recognition and makes wholesaler distribution more likely.
Direct shipping can similarly increase consumer demand for a
particular wine, increasing the prospects for further retail sales
and wholesaler distribution.
Not surprisingly, Massachusetts's wineries have taken
advantage of these benefits. Twenty-seven of Massachusetts's
thirty-one wineries have obtained "small" winery licenses; in
contrast, only twenty-six of the 2,933 out-of-state "small"
wineries producing more than a gallon per year have done so.12
Massachusetts's wineries have also benefitted from their access to
multiple distribution channels in practice. In 2007, the first
12
It is true, as Massachusetts argues, that in 2006, 4,713
wineries qualified as "small" under § 19F(b). But more than a
third of these wineries produced less than a gallon of wine a year
and cannot really be considered part of the interstate wine market.
Moreover, many "small" out-of-state wineries likely distribute
virtually all of their wine through in-person sales or to their
home-state markets.
-20-
year § 19F was in effect, Massachusetts's wineries distributed 29
percent of their annual production through wholesalers and 71
percent through retail outlets, including direct shipping. See An
Economic Snapshot of the Massachusetts Winery Industry.
The 637 out-of-state wineries that qualified as "large"
under § 19F(a) in 2006 do not get these advantages and must instead
choose between direct shipping and wholesaler distribution. Under
§ 19F(a), whether a "large" winery chooses wholesaler distribution
or direct shipping, its choice carries a significant loss of
potential profits, since using a single method results in a
comparative loss of consumer sales. "Large" wineries also face
comparatively greater distribution costs because they cannot always
distribute a given wine through the most cost-effective method.
And they cannot take advantage of the synergies that increase the
net amount of demand for wines when multiple distribution methods
are used together. These amount to considerable competitive
disadvantages in an industry that Massachusetts's own evidence
characterizes as one with indisputably slim profit margins and a
highly competitive market.
Moreover, contrary to Massachusetts's assertions, § 19F
does not level the playing field for all wineries unable to obtain
consistent wholesaler distribution under the three-tier system.
Section 19F's demarcation line between "small" and "large" wineries
instead creates an especially acute competitive disadvantage for
the wineries that are defined as "large" under § 19F(a) but which
-21-
in practice face the same difficulties in distributing most of
their wines as the "small" § 19F(b) wineries. Massachusetts's own
evidence shows that only the largest 50 to 100 wineries can
distribute most of their wines through wholesalers under the three-
tier system. The remaining 537 or so "large" wineries each produce
between 30,001 and 680,000 gallons per year of a mix of mass-market
and boutique wines. In 2006, their percentage of the market share
for wine production far exceeded that of § 19F(b) "small" wineries.
These smaller "large" wineries lose the most under the
§ 19F regime. Unlike the largest of the "large" wineries, which
can distribute the vast majority of their wines through existing
wholesale distribution, these smaller "large" wineries can only
distribute a handful of their higher-volume wines through
wholesalers. If they choose direct shipping, however, they are
forced to terminate their existing wholesaler relationships, which
also means that they lose all access to retailers in Massachusetts.
Since this is a crucial way for a winery to build consumer
awareness for the brand in Massachusetts, its unavailability means
that these wineries are not able to compete on the same footing as
§ 19F(b) "small" wineries. Importantly, these are also the
wineries that would otherwise be most competitive in the market for
boutique wines: their size affords them otherwise considerable
advantages in terms of marketing, volume, transportation, and brand
recognition.
-22-
The ultimate effect of § 19F is to artificially limit the
playing field in this market in a way that enables Massachusetts's
wineries to gain market share against their out-of-state
competitors. Section 19F(b)'s choice of a 30,000 gallon grape wine
production cap helps Massachusetts wineries to improve their
position in the market. At the same time, § 19F(a) burdens all the
larger out-of-state competitors and impedes their ability to
effectively use their natural advantages.13
Massachusetts argues that there can be no discrimination
because the favored "small" winery group created by § 19F(b) is
almost entirely comprised of out-of-state wineries. Massachusetts
claims this means that whatever the burden on out-of-state wineries
under § 19F(a), § 19F(b) does not create an in-state benefit, since
Massachusetts's "small" wineries are made no better off than their
out-of-state counterparts. Without evidence of in-state benefits,
Massachusetts concludes, the Supreme Court's decision in Exxon
dictates that we find no discriminatory effect.
Massachusetts's argument ignores the effect of its
statute. Section 19F(b)'s benefit to eligible "small" out-of-state
wineries cannot be viewed separately from the much greater
disadvantages that § 19F(a) imposes on out-of-state wineries.
13
Our decision in Baldacci is consistent with this
conclusion. That case involved a challenge to a Maine law that
allowed wineries to sell to consumers only in face-to-face
transactions. 505 F.3d at 30-31. That challenge failed because
plaintiffs did not introduce any evidence that the law benefitted
Maine vineyards or harmed out-of-state wineries. Id. at 38.
-23-
Massachusetts's wineries uniquely receive a net competitive gain
under § 19F, while the law impairs out-of-state wineries'
competitive position. It deprives "large" wineries--and especially
those "large" wineries that have trouble obtaining wholesale
distribution--of the competitive advantages of specialization and
higher-volume production. These disadvantages exceed the benefits
that out-of-state "small" wineries receive.
Exxon does not support Massachusetts's argument. Exxon
held that a law that restricts a market consisting entirely of out-
of-state interests is not discriminatory because there is no local
market to benefit. 437 U.S. at 125-26. Exxon is not apposite
where, as here, there is an in-state market and the law operates to
its competitive benefit. Massachusetts cannot apply Exxon only to
"large" wineries as distinct from "small" wineries; the wine market
is a single although differentiated market, and § 19F's two
provisions operate on that market together.
Likewise, the fact that § 19F(b) benefits both in-state
and some out-of-state "small" wineries does not prove that § 19F is
non-discriminatory. We have previously rejected the notion that "a
favored group must be entirely in-state for a law to have a
discriminatory effect on commerce," reasoning that when a law
burdened a group whose members were entirely out-of-state and
benefitted a class whose members were largely but not wholly
located in-state, it was still impermissibly discriminatory in
-24-
effect.14 See Walgreen Co. v. Rullan, 405 F.3d 50, 59 (1st Cir.
2005).
B. Section 19F is Discriminatory in Purpose
We further hold that § 19F conferred a competitive
advantage upon Massachusetts wineries by design.
In Alliance of Auto. Mfrs. v. Gwadosky, 430 F.3d 30 (1st
Cir. 2005), we discussed the methodology for determining
legislative purpose when a state statute is allegedly motivated by
an intent to discriminate against interstate commerce. Under that
methodology, we look to "the statute as a whole," id. at 37,
including statutory text, context, and legislative history, but we
also consider whether the statute was "closely tailored to achieve
the legislative purpose" the state asserted.15 Id. at 38.
14
Nor do we find the reasoning of the two district court
cases that have upheld other states' gallonage caps to be
persuasive. See Black Star Farms, LLC v. Oliver, 544 F. Supp. 2d
913 (D. Ariz. 2008); Cherry Hill Vineyards, LLC v. Hudgins, 488 F.
Supp. 2d 601 (W.D. Ky. 2006).
15
Other courts have invalidated state statutes as motivated
by a discriminatory intent after examining an even wider range of
sources. Some have done so based on the test for discriminatory
purpose used in the Equal Protection context, which looks for a
history or pattern of discrimination. See, e.g., S.D. Farm Bureau,
Inc. v. Hazeltine, 340 F.3d 583, 593-96 (8th Cir. 2003); Waste
Mgmt. Holdings, Inc. v. Gilmore, 252 F.3d 316, 336 (4th Cir. 2001);
see also McNeilus Truck and Mfg., Inc. v. Ohio ex rel. Montgomery,
226 F.3d 429, 443 (6th Cir. 2000) (invalidating a statute as
discriminatory in both purpose and effect). We need not adopt a
broader view of the sources probative of legislative intent to find
that § 19F is discriminatory in purpose. Nor need we consider
whether an Equal Protection analysis is apposite in the Commerce
Clause context. Even under our narrower methodology in Alliance of
Auto. Mfrs., § 19F is discriminatory in purpose.
-25-
That § 19F discriminates against out-of-state wineries in
its effects strengthens the inference that the statute was
discriminatory by design. "'[L]ess deference to . . . legislative
judgment is due . . . where the local regulation bears
disproportionately on out-of-state residents and businesses.'" Id.
at 39 (second and third alterations in original) (quoting Kassel v.
Consol. Freightways Corp., 450 U.S. 662, 675-76 (1981) (plurality
opinion)); see also D. H. Regan, The Supreme Court and State
Protectionism: Making Sense of the Dormant Commerce Clause, 84
Mich. L. Rev. 1091, 1144-47, 1206-45 (1986) (suggesting that the
Commerce Clause is particularly concerned with deliberate
discrimination, and that previous Supreme Court cases invalidating
state statutes involved discriminatory effects in combination with,
and as evidence of, discriminatory purpose); K.M. Sullivan & G.
Gunther, Constitutional Law 206 (16th ed. 2007).
As to statutory context, § 19F is a new addition to a
provision that covers an array of alcohol licensing rules.16 While
§ 19 generally includes licensing rules for producers that are
typical of the three-tier system, § 19F is one of a number of
16
Section 19F is unlike the law at issue in Alliance of
Auto. Mfrs., which we described as a fully integrated part of an
"intricately constructed law" that had been on the books for three
decades. 430 F.3d at 37-38.
Moreover, when, as here, a state statute is both
discriminatory in effect and in purpose, it is clearly
discriminatory within the meaning of the Commerce Clause, and we
need not address whether evidence of a legislative intent to
discriminate would suffice on its own. Cf. Alliance of Auto.
Mfrs., 430 F.3d at 36 n.3.
-26-
recently appended subsections that sets out special exceptions to
that system for particular entities. See, e.g., Mass. Gen. Laws.
ch. 138, § 19C (farmer-brewery licenses); id. § 19D (pub-brewery
licenses); § 19E (farmer-distillery licenses). Many of these
subsections were enacted for the express purpose of assisting
Massachusetts's domestic industries, including but not limited to
§ 19B, § 19F's facially discriminatory and unconstitutional
predecessor.17 Though § 19F contains no stated statutory purpose,
its placement in a licensing law that grants exceptions to the
three-tier system for the predominant purpose of benefitting local
industry is pertinent evidence of discriminatory intent. Based on
statements made by various Massachusetts legislators, it is also
clear that Massachusetts intended to benefit its local wine
industry, and that it did so in particular ways whose effects on
out-of-state wineries could easily be foreseen.
The gap between Massachusetts's professed neutrality and
§ 19F's practical effects also underscores the conclusion of
discriminatory purpose. See Hunt, 432 U.S. at 352 (observing that
the disparity between a law's asserted ends and its means was
"somewhat suspect" and evidenced a likely discriminatory purpose).
Massachusetts has asserted various purposes behind § 19F:
17
See id. § 19B(a) (farmer-winery licenses were created
"[f]or the purpose of encouraging the development of domestic
vineyards"); id. § 19C(a) (farmer-brewery licenses exist "[f]or the
purpose of encouraging the development of domestic farms"); id.
§ 19E(a) (farmer-distillery licenses are issued "[f]or the purpose
of encouraging the development of domestic farms").
-27-
to facilitate direct shipment, to further the three-tier system, to
make all small wineries, irrespective of their location, better
able to compete, and to thereby provide Massachusetts consumers
with greater choice. The 30,000 gallon cap and the fruit wine
exception, Massachusetts claimed at oral argument, reflected the
legislature's rational assessment of the kind of wineries that
needed special assistance because they were suffering from the
limitations of the three-tier system. But these general aims stand
in stark contrast to § 19F's specific and highly irregular
features.
The wine industry and federal law have developed
definitions of "small," "medium," and "large" wineries in order to
describe the way the industry produces and distributes wines and,
in the case of federal law, to offer "small" wineries regulatory
benefits. These definitions do not, of course, bind states to
particular regulatory choices. But their lack of correlation to
§ 19F belies Massachusetts's claim that § 19F's features reflected
an objective choice to remedy the purported competitive
disadvantage faced uniquely by wineries producing 30,000 gallons or
less of grape wine. That is particularly true given that this
gallonage cap counts wineries as "small" even if they produce more
than 30,000 gallons of wine when fruit wine production is counted.
See Kassel, 450 U.S. at 675-78 (questioning the legitimacy of the
Iowa legislature's motives in enacting a statute that banned
vehicles longer than 55 feet from using Iowa roads, when all other
-28-
states in the West and Midwest had a 65-foot limit and the Iowa
statute had a number of significant and irregular exceptions);
Hunt, 432 U.S. at 350-52 (finding a North Carolina apple-labeling
law discriminatory in effect and, impliedly, in purpose when its
requirements prevented Washington from using its apple-grading and
labeling system, which had become the industry standard).
According to uncontested evidence in the record, the wine
industry considers wineries that produce 120,000 gallons per year
or less "small." "Medium" wineries produce between 120,000 and
600,000 gallons annually, and "large" wineries produce more than
600,000 gallons per year. The industry apparently does not
differentiate between wineries that produce fruit as opposed to
grape wine; relative size is the critical factor. The Federal
Trade Commission largely adopted these definitions when it surveyed
conditions of competition in the wine industry. See FTC Report at
6.
Nor, according to testimony from industry figures, does
Massachusetts's 30,000 gallon demarcation point between "small" and
"large" wineries correspond to the ability of the winery to obtain
wholesaler representation. To the contrary, this choice prevents
out-of-state, smaller "large" wineries from competing on equal
terms with Massachusetts's "small" wineries even though these
wineries faced similar difficulties in obtaining wholesaler
distribution under the three-tier system.
-29-
Massachusetts's claim at oral argument that its
definition of "small" wineries targets those wineries in need of
competitive assistance also diverges considerably from the
definitions the federal government and other states have developed
for this same broad purpose. As we have said, there is no
relationship to those wineries who are able or unable to obtain
wholesalers. Beyond that, as a matter of federal tax policy,
wineries producing 250,000 gallons or less of any type of wine, and
not merely wineries that produce less than 30,000 gallons of grape
wine per year, are deemed "small wineries" in need of competitive
assistance in the form of a substantial tax break. See Alcohol &
Tobacco Tax & Trade Bureau, Dep't of the Treasury, TTB Compliance
Seminar for Bonded Wine Premises 73-74 (2008), available at
http://www.ttb.gov/pdf/compliance-seminar.pdf (hereinafter TTB
Compliance Seminar).18 No other state has defined a "small" wine
producer and attached the same consequences to this definition as
Massachusetts has.19 And no other state counts gallonage by
18
The tax code provision defines "small" wineries as those
under 250,000 gallons annually and provides the greatest incentives
for wineries that produce under 150,000 gallons annually. See 26
U.S.C. § 5041(c)(1)-(2); 27 C.F.R. § 24.278(a) (2008); TTB
Compliance Seminar at 70-71. The federal tax code also measures
"wine" production by counting wines produced from various fruits,
not just grape wine. See 27 C.F.R. § 24.10.
19
Arizona, Kentucky, Ohio, and Indiana have limited access
to direct shipping to "small" or "farm" wineries. See Ariz. Rev.
Stat. Ann. § 4-205.04(C); Ky. Rev. Stat. Ann. § 243.155,
invalidated in part by Cherry Hill Vineyards, LLC v. Lilly, 553
F.3d 423 (6th Cir. 2008); Ohio Rev. Code Ann. § 4303.232(A)(1);
Ind. Code 7.1-3-12-4, 7.1-3-12-5(a). Other states provide other
-30-
excluding all fruit wine production; "wine" in these other states
means wines made from any fruit or other agricultural product. See
Ariz. Rev. Stat. Ann. § 4-101(36); Ark. Code Ann. § 3-5-202(4);
Fla. Stat. § 564.01; Ky. Rev. Stat. Ann. § 241.010(55); Ind. Code
7.1-1-3-49; Ohio Rev. Code Ann. § 4301.01(3). Section 19F's
definition of a "small" winery does not even correspond to the way
Massachusetts previously classified wineries by size for the
purpose of calculating a licensing fee.20
Section 19F's unusual regulatory features do track one
thing precisely: the unique attributes of Massachusetts's own wine
industry.21 All of Massachusetts's thirty-one wineries are eligible
regulatory benefits to such wineries. See, e.g., Ark. Code Ann.
§ 3-5-1602(c)(1)(E); Fla. Stat. § 599.004. Though most of these
states define "small" wineries with reference to the number of
gallons they produce annually, no other state considers 30,000
gallons a significant figure. See Ariz. Rev. Stat. Ann. § 4-
205.04(C); Ark. Code Ann. §§ 3-5-1601, 3-5-1602(c)(1)(E); Fla.
Stat. § 599.004; Ky. Rev. Stat. Ann. § 241.010(46); Ohio Rev. Code
Ann. § 4303.232(A)(1).
20
Section 19B, § 19F's unconstitutional predecessor,
included a subsection that calculated license fees based on a
winery's annual gallonage. Wineries in lower-gallonage categories
paid lower fees. Mass. Gen. Laws ch. 138, § 19B(l). Wineries were
divided into categories of 5,000 gallons or less per year; 5,000 to
20,000 gallons; 20,000 to 100,000 gallons; 100,000 to 200,000
gallons; 200,000 to 1,000,000 gallons; and more than 1,000,000
gallons per year. Id. These categories were based on total annual
gallonage and did not consider whether the wine came from grapes or
other fruits. Id.; id. § 19B(m).
21
To be clear, we do not hold that when an industry and the
federal government have developed a standard definition in the
field of alcohol regulation, a state must follow that definition
or have its law deemed suspect. Cf. North Dakota v. United States,
495 U.S. 423, 430-33 (1990). It is the totality of the evidence of
discriminatory purpose and discriminatory effect that leads us to
-31-
for "small" winery licenses. All fall neatly within the 30,000
gallon cap, producing between 200 gallons and 24,000 gallons
annually. And the record demonstrates--and Massachusetts does not
contest--that legislators were well aware of these figures.
The fact that this gallonage cap excludes wines made from
fruits other than grapes, no matter how many gallons a winery
produces per year, is particularly probative. In past years,
Massachusetts's largest winery produced more than 30,000 gallons of
wine annually because between half and three-quarters of its
production came from apple wines. The main effect of the fruit
wine exception was to guarantee that this winery, like all other
Massachusetts wineries, could take advantage of § 19F(b)'s
beneficial distribution rules for "small" wineries. Massachusetts
has offered no other explanation for the fruit wine exception, and
there is no obvious reason why it would serve § 19F's ostensible
purposes. This exception, like similar, facially neutral statutory
exemptions apparently motivated by a desire to shield in-state
interests, "weaken[s] the presumption in favor of the validity of
the [general provision], because [it] undermine[s] the assumption
that the State's own political processes will act as a check on
local regulations that unduly burden interstate commerce." Raymond
Motor Transp., Inc. v. Rice, 434 U.S. 429, 447 (1978).
conclude that § 19F discriminates against interstate commerce.
-32-
We conclude that § 19F altered the competitive balance to
favor Massachusetts's wineries and disfavor out-of-state
competition by design.22
C. Lack of Legitimate Local Purpose and Availability
of Reasonable Non-Discriminatory Alternatives
Because plaintiffs have shown that § 19F discriminates
against interstate commerce, Massachusetts bears the heavy burden
of showing that the statute is nonetheless constitutional because
it serves a legitimate local purpose that cannot be attained
through reasonable non-discriminatory alternatives. Dep't of
Revenue, 128 S. Ct. at 1808. The state can only carry this burden
by presenting "concrete record evidence," and not "sweeping
assertion[s]" or "mere speculation," to substantiate its claims
that the discriminatory aspects of its challenged policy are
necessary to achieve its asserted objectives. Granholm, 544 U.S.
at 492-93; see also Chem. Waste Mgmt., 504 U.S. at 342.
Massachusetts has not even attempted to do so here.23 Because the
22
This conclusion is not dependent on the many statements
of discriminatory purpose by lobbyists and the intermediate steps
in the legislative process the district court relied upon in its
opinion.
23
The state did not brief this point. It was only in
response to questioning at oral argument that Massachusetts
characterized § 19F as the only feasible means the state has to
serve the local purposes of benefitting small wineries, supporting
the three-tier system, and increasing consumer choice. This
argument is untimely and likely waived. It is also not supported
by anything in the record. Several amici try to fill the gap, but
amici may not make up for waiver by a party. See United States v.
Sturm, Ruger & Co., Inc., 84 F.3d 1, 6 (1st Cir. 1996).
-33-
constitutionality of a state statute is involved, we nonetheless
consider the issue.
The record shows that at least one viable non-
discriminatory alternative existed when § 19F was under
consideration: the Model Direct Shipment Bill, which the National
Conference of State Legislatures adopted in 1997. The Model Bill
does not define "small" or "large" wineries or regulate access to
licenses depending on winery size. As an alternative to § 19F,
then-Governor Romney proposed a version of the Model Bill which
would have allowed all wineries to ship directly to consumers, sell
to retailers, and distribute through wholesalers. But the state
legislature rejected this proposal and overrode his veto.
Plaintiffs argue that this alternative would have helped
small wineries without undercutting the three-tier system because
it included limitations on the total volume wineries could ship to
consumers. Whatever the merits of this proposal, Massachusetts has
never claimed it would be unworkable. Under similar circumstances,
the Supreme Court has, as a rule, struck down the discriminatory
state law in question. See Granholm, 544 U.S. at 491-92; Camps
Newfound/Owatonna, 520 U.S. at 582 n.16.
III. Whether the Twenty-first Amendment Immunizes Facially
Neutral Alcohol Statutes from Commerce Clause Scrutiny
We now consider whether, as Massachusetts asserts, the
Twenty-first Amendment protects § 19F from invalidation,
-34-
notwithstanding the fact that it discriminates against interstate
commerce in purpose and effect.
Whether the Twenty-first Amendment granted states the
authority to enact even facially neutral but discriminatory alcohol
laws that would otherwise violate the Commerce Clause was not
decided by Granholm and the answer is not readily apparent from the
text of the Amendment. Granholm holds the interpretation of this
amendment instead turns on historical context. Section 2 of the
Twenty-first Amendment granted the states the authority to regulate
liquor only to the extent that they had done so before Prohibition
under two federal laws: the Wilson Act of 189024 and the Webb-Kenyon
Act of 1913.25 See Granholm, 544 U.S. at 484.
The Supreme Court held in Granholm that through these
Acts, Congress gave the states newfound powers to regulate alcohol
that came within their borders, even if it had traveled in
24
The Wilson Act stated "[t]hat all . . . intoxicating
liquors . . . transported into any State . . . for use,
consumption, sale or storage therein, shall upon arrival in such
State . . . be subject to the operation and effect of the laws of
such State . . . enacted in the exercise of its police powers, to
the same extent and in the same manner as though such liquids or
liquors had been produced in such State . . . and shall not be
exempt therefrom by reason of being introduced therein in original
packages or otherwise." 27 U.S.C. § 121.
25
The Webb-Kenyon Act provided that "[t]he shipment or
transportation . . . of any . . . intoxicating liquor of any kind
from one State . . . into any other State . . . which said . . .
intoxicating liquor is intended, by any person interested therein,
to be received, possessed, sold, or in any manner used, either in
the original package or otherwise, in violation of any law of such
State. . . is prohibited.” 27 U.S.C. § 122.
-35-
interstate commerce. The Wilson Act did this by allowing states to
restrict or prohibit the sale of out-of-state alcohol "to the same
extent and in the same manner" as alcohol that was produced in-
state. 544 U.S. at 478 (quoting 27 U.S.C. § 121) (internal
quotation marks omitted). The Webb-Kenyon Act expanded states'
regulatory authority by expressly authorizing states to regulate
alcohol that traveled in interstate commerce even if it was being
shipped solely for consumers' personal use. Id. at 481-84. These
Acts did not, however, exempt states from the Commerce Clause's
existing prohibitions on state laws that discriminated against out-
of-state goods and favored local interests. Id. at 484-85.
The precise question in Granholm was what effect, if any,
the Twenty-first Amendment has upon facially discriminatory state
alcohol laws that would otherwise be subject to invalidation under
the Commerce Clause. 544 U.S. at 471. The question of whether the
Twenty-first Amendment protects facially neutral laws like § 19F
was not before the Court.
Massachusetts now contends that the Twenty-first
Amendment protects facially neutral laws from invalidation under
the Commerce Clause, even if they discriminate in purpose or
effect, because it says such laws are distinguishable from facially
discriminatory laws for the purposes of the Twenty-first Amendment.
In the alternative, Massachusetts asserted at oral argument that
-36-
the Twenty-first Amendment should lessen Commerce Clause scrutiny
of such laws to mere rational basis review.26
We reject these arguments. Based on our analysis of
historical sources, we conclude that the Wilson and Webb-Kenyon
Acts did not protect facially neutral state liquor laws from
invalidation under the Commerce Clause if they were
discriminatory.27 To hold otherwise, we would have to find that
these Acts not only recognized the difference between facially
discriminatory and facially neutral but discriminatory state laws,
but also affirmatively intended to protect the latter and not the
former. All evidence points to the contrary.
By the time the Wilson Act became law in 1890, it was
well established that under the Commerce Clause, facially neutral
26
The states of New Jersey, Ohio, Rhode Island, and
Wyoming, as amici, do not join Massachusetts's argument that there
is no Commerce Clause scrutiny if the statute is facially neutral.
They do support the contention that § 19F is not discriminatory in
effect or purpose. They argue in general terms that it cannot be
irrational for a legislature to make distinctions based on winery
size. It does not, of course, follow that the precise distinction
drawn cannot have a discriminatory effect. These states also make
the parade of horribles-style argument that a state's loss of
control over the alcoholic beverage market "can lead to illegal
activity, including shipment to underage individuals, the sale of
adulterated products, and the possibility of organized crime
involvement in disguised internet schemes." Massachusetts has not
advanced any of these theories, and it is difficult to see the
claimed causal relationship.
27
Because we hold that § 19F discriminates in effect and in
purpose in violation of the Commerce Clause, see supra Part II, we
do not decide whether, as Massachusetts argues, the Twenty-first
Amendment nonetheless immunizes non-discriminatory laws that impose
an undue burden on interstate commerce under Pike.
-37-
state statutes that had a discriminatory effect on out-of-state
interests constituted impermissible discrimination, just as
facially discriminatory state laws did.
The Supreme Court had decided two major discriminatory
effects Commerce Clause cases just before the Wilson Act passed.
In Robbins v. Taxing Dist. of Shelby County, 120 U.S. 489 (1887),
the Court had invalidated a facially neutral state tax on
"drummers," individuals who "drummed up" sales by displaying
samples, because, inter alia, the tax disproportionately
disadvantaged out-of-state merchants and manufacturers. Id. at
490-91, 497-98. And in Minnesota v. Barber, 136 U.S. 313 (1890),
the Supreme Court had invalidated a Minnesota statute that required
in-state inspection of all meat before it could be sold within the
state. Id. at 326. Its reasoning cut broadly: "Although this
statute is not avowedly or in its terms directed against the
bringing into Minnesota of the products of other states," this was
the statute's "necessary effect." Id.
In a separate line of cases, the Supreme Court had also
indicated that a state's asserted rationale for a statute would be
viewed with skepticism if other evidence, including the statute's
effects, pointed strongly to a discriminatory purpose. "[I]f the
State, under the guise of exerting its police powers, should make
such exclusion or prohibition applicable solely to articles, of
that kind, that may be produced or manufactured in other States,"
the Court stated as early as 1879, "the courts would find no
-38-
difficulty in holding such legislation to be in conflict with the
Constitution of the United States." Guy v. City of Baltimore, 100
U.S. 434, 443 (1879); see also Austin v. Tennessee, 179 U.S. 343,
349-50 (1900) (suggesting that ostensibly neutral laws that were
intentionally applied in a discriminatory manner were invalid in
the Commerce Clause context).
When drafting the Wilson and Webb-Kenyon Acts, Congress
was presumably aware that these types of facially neutral but
discriminatory state laws were subject to invalidation under the
Commerce Clause. See Edelman v. Lynchburg Coll., 535 U.S. 106, 117
n.13 (2002); see also N. Star Steel Co. v. Thomas, 515 U.S. 29, 34
(1995). Yet Congress made no reference to the notion that the
Wilson and Webb-Kenyon Acts would permit states to enact liquor
laws with a discriminatory effect or motive. Although "Congress
may authorize the States to engage in regulation that the Commerce
Clause would otherwise forbid," courts can "exempt[] state statutes
from the implied limitations of the Clause only when the
congressional direction to do so has been unmistakably clear."
Maine v. Taylor, 477 U.S. 131, 138-39 (1986) (internal quotation
marks omitted). The Wilson and Webb-Kenyon Acts do evince an
unmistakably clear intention to permit states to regulate alcohol
which traveled in interstate commerce the same way as they
-39-
regulated in-state alcohol.28 But the two Acts cannot be construed
to authorize anything more.
Supreme Court decisions and legal scholarship of the era
confirm this interpretation. Scott v. Donald, 165 U.S. 58 (1897),
involved a challenge to a state law that gave the state liquor
commissioner control over all state sales of alcohol and included
two other provisions that explicitly disfavored out-of-state
manufacturers. Id. at 92. The Court compared the facts to other
Commerce Clause cases, including various discriminatory effects
cases involving goods other than alcohol, implying that alcohol
regulation was not a unique category for the purposes of the non-
discrimination rule. Id. at 93-99. The Court's ultimate holding
was that "[the Wilson Act] was not intended to confer upon any
state the power to discriminate injuriously against the products of
other states." While states, under the Wilson Act, could enact
laws to "forbid entirely the manufacture and sale of intoxicating
liquors," they "cannot . . . establish a system which, in effect,
28
It is clear that the Wilson and Webb-Kenyon Acts were
designed to advance the temperance movement's objectives by letting
states restrict or even prohibit the sale of alcohol within their
borders. See A. A. Bruce, The Wilson Act and the Constitution, 21
Green Bag 211, 215-16 (1909); L. Rogers, Interstate Commerce in
Intoxicating Liquors Before the Webb-Kenyon Act, 4 Va. L. Rev. 288,
293-300 (1917). The rule that state laws had to regulate in-state
and out-of-state interests even-handedly was no impediment to the
kind of laws the temperance movement pushed states to enact. See
R. F. Hamm, Shaping the Eighteenth Amendment: Temperance Reform,
Legal Culture, & the Polity, 1880-1920 188-89, 197-202 (1995).
-40-
discriminates between interstate and domestic commerce." Id. at
100.
Contemporaneous treatises on liquor law likewise
concluded that the Wilson Act did not immunize any kind of
discriminatory state law from scrutiny under the non-discrimination
rule.29
Against this background, we hold that the Twenty-first
Amendment does not exempt facially neutral state alcohol laws with
discriminatory effects from the non-discrimination rule of the
Commerce Clause. Nor, of course, are such laws exempt when they
also discriminate by design.
We also reject Massachusetts's alternate contention that
the Twenty-first Amendment lessens the degree of Commerce Clause
scrutiny for facially neutral but discriminatory state alcohol laws
to mere rational basis review. The Supreme Court implicitly
rejected this argument in Granholm when it applied the usual,
searching degree of scrutiny to invalidate the facially
discriminatory laws at issue. 544 U.S. at 489-90. And there is
29
See H. C. Black, A Treatise on the Laws Regulating the
Manufacture and Sale of Intoxicating Liquors § 44, at 55-56 (1892)
(noting the invalidity of state laws that involve "a tax imposed
upon an occupation, which necessarily discriminates against the
introduction and sale of products from another state" in its
effect); H. Joyce, The Law Relating to Intoxicating Liquors § 54,
at 67-69 (1910) (suggesting that the "special rule" embodied in the
Wilson Act was only to enable states to regulate alcohol in
interstate commerce). The Webb-Kenyon Act did not alter this
outcome, nor was it meant to do so. All it did was to enable
states to regulate alcohol shipped into a state for consumers'
personal use. See Granholm, 544 U.S. at 482-83.
-41-
nothing in the text, legislative history, or contemporaneous
understandings of the Wilson or Webb-Kenyon Acts that supports
Massachusetts's argument, let alone yields an unambiguous
indication of congressional intent to reduce Commerce Clause
scrutiny. In the absence of such evidence, Massachusetts's
interpretation of the Twenty-first Amendment fails.
Finally, we need not address whether § 19F could escape
invalidation on the ground that, despite its discriminatory effect
and design, the "core purposes" of the Twenty-first Amendment "are
sufficiently implicated . . . to outweigh the Commerce Clause
principles that would otherwise be offended." Bacchus, 468 U.S. at
275. Those purposes include "promoting temperance, ensuring
orderly market conditions, and raising revenue." North Dakota, 495
U.S. at 432. Massachusetts does not present any argument as to why
§ 19F serves any of these purposes.30 In any event, it is unclear
that this balancing test survives Granholm.31
30
In its argument that § 19F would pass muster under Pike,
Massachusetts identifies two interests § 19F serves: "the promotion
of competition and consumer choice." The state also mentions its
three-tier system as a local benefit, without analyzing whether
§ 19F, which relaxes the system, can be justified on this ground.
Massachusetts does not make the argument, made by the amici
Wine and Spirits Wholesalers, that the state's three-tier system
"prevent[s] a deluge of alcoholic beverages [from] descending
chaotically on consumers from many different sources" and that the
scheme is necessary to prevent the evils of the tied house. Amici
admit that the limits embodied in § 19F have the effect of
protecting in-state wholesalers from competition.
31
See Brooks v. Vassar, 462 F.3d 341, 351 (4th Cir. 2006)
(suggesting, over a dissent, that Granholm narrowed this inquiry
but did not eliminate it); see also M. K. Ohlhausen and G. L. Luib,
-42-
IV.
We affirm the judgment of the district court.
So ordered.
Moving Sideways: Post-Granholm Developments in Wine Direct Shipping
and Their Implications for Competition, 75 Antitrust L.J. 505,
528-29 (2008) (noting that Granholm left it "unclear whether there
are any circumstances under which the Twenty-first Amendment can
'save' such regulation from judicial condemnation" under the
Commerce Clause).
-43-