United States Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit
2009-1021
HUVIS CORPORATION,
Plaintiff-Appellant,
v.
UNITED STATES,
Defendant-Appellee,
and
DAK FIBERS, INC. and WELLMAN, INC.,
Defendants.
Michael P. House, McDermott Will & Emery LLP, of Washington, DC, argued for
plaintiff-appellant. With him on the brief was Raymond Paretzky.
Stephen C. Tosini, Attorney, Commercial Litigation Branch, Civil Division, United
States Department of Justice, of Washington, DC, argued for defendant-appellee. With
him on the brief were Michael F. Hertz, Acting Assistant Attorney General, Jeanne E.
Davidson, Director, and Patricia M. McCarthy, Assistant Director.
Appealed from: United States Court of International Trade
Judge Gregory W. Carman
United States Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit
2009-1021
HUVIS CORPORATION,
Plaintiff-Appellant,
v.
UNITED STATES,
Defendant-Appellee,
and
DAK FIBERS, INC. and WELLMAN, INC.,
Defendants.
Appeal from the United States Court of International Trade in Case No.
06-00380, Judge Gregory W. Carman.
____________________________
DECIDED: June 25, 2009
____________________________
Before LOURIE, DYK, and PROST, Circuit Judges.
LOURIE, Circuit Judge.
Huvis Corporation (“Huvis”) appeals from the judgment of the United States
Court of International Trade affirming the United States Department of Commerce’s
(“Commerce’s”) valuation of Huvis’s imports. See Huvis Corp. v. United States, 525 F.
Supp. 2d 1370 (Ct. Int’l Trade 2007) (“Huvis I”); Huvis Corp. v. United States, No. 06-
00380, 2008 Ct. Intl. Trade Lexis 82 (Aug. 5, 2008) (“Huvis II”). Because Commerce’s
decision to use a constructed market price in valuing Huvis’s imports was supported by
substantial evidence and not contrary to law, we affirm.
BACKGROUND
Huvis is a Korean producer and exporter of polyester staple fiber, a synthetic
fiber that is used for stuffing products such as clothing and pillows. It is subject to an
antidumping duty order, under which a dumping margin is applied to all of Huvis’s
imports. Polyester staple fiber is made from terephthalic acid. Huvis uses three grades
of terephthalic acid in manufacturing its fiber: qualified-grade, middle-grade, and
purified. Huvis’s importation of polyester staple fiber into the United States had been
reviewed by Commerce four times in periodic administrative reviews, prior to the
administrative review it now appeals. During the fifth period of review, which is the
subject of the present appeal, Huvis purchased all of the terephthalic acid it used from
affiliated companies.
Commerce assigns a “value” to an import to determine the dumping margin
applied to it. When an importer purchases a “major input” from an affiliated party,
instead of assuming the input was purchased at arm’s length, Commerce applies the
“major input rule” to determine the value of the input. 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(f)(2), (3). The
parties agree that terephthalic acid constitutes a major input to polyester staple fiber.
Commerce’s interpretation of the major input rule requires Commerce normally to
“determine the value of a major input purchased from an affiliated person based on the
higher of: (1) [t]he price paid by the exporter or producer to the affiliated person for the
major input; (2) [t]he amount usually reflected in sales of the major input in the market
under consideration; or (3) [t]he cost to the affiliated person of producing the major
input.” 19 C.F.R. 351.407(b). Thus, for the fifth period of review, as with each of the
previous review periods, Commerce requested that Huvis submit three measures for its
2009-1021 2
purchases of each grade of terephthalic acid made during the period of review: (1) the
price Huvis paid to its affiliated suppliers (the “transfer price”); (2) the price at which the
affiliated producer made sales of the input to unaffiliated parties (the “market price”);
and (3) the affiliated producer’s cost of production for the input (the “cost of production”).
For middle-grade terephthalic acid, Huvis submitted all three measures. For qualified-
grade and purified terephthalic acids, Huvis submitted only the transfer price and cost of
production measures because it did not have access to market price data, as its
supplier for those two products, Samnam Petrochemical Company, Ltd. (“Samnam”),
considered that data proprietary.
In each of its three previous reviews, Huvis had similarly submitted information
that was missing certain market price data. Commerce had, in all cases but one,
applied the major input rule for those products by comparing only the two measures
Huvis had provided, transfer price and the cost of production, 1 but in the fifth
administrative review, Commerce chose to include in the comparison a market price
that was constructed from “facts available.”
“If . . . necessary information is not available on the record,” Commerce is
required to “use the facts otherwise available in reaching the applicable determination
under this title.” 19 U.S.C. § 1677e(a). However, under 19 U.S.C. § 1677e(c),
Commerce must corroborate such secondary information “from independent sources
that are reasonably at [its] disposal.” Commerce must also
1
In the one counterexample, Commerce explained that the evidence
suggested that the qualified-grade and middle-grade terephthalic acids were
interchangeable, so it filled in the missing qualified-grade terephthalic acid market price
with Huvis’s submitted middle-grade terephthalic acid market price.
2009-1021 3
consider information that is submitted by an interested party and is
necessary to the determination but does not meet all the applicable
requirements . . . if
(1) the information is submitted by the deadline established for its
submission,
(2) the information can be verified,
(3) the information is not so incomplete that it cannot serve as a reliable
basis for reaching the applicable determination,
(4) the interested party has demonstrated that it acted to the best of its
ability in providing the information and meeting the requirements
established by the administering authority or the Commission with respect
to the information, and
(5) the information can be used without undue difficulties.
19 U.S.C. § 1677m(e). Commerce finally may not draw “adverse inferences” against an
importer unless the importer fails to cooperate in the investigation. 19 U.S.C.
§ 1677e(b). The parties agree that Huvis cooperated with Commerce in the fifth review.
Commerce applied the major input rule by first constructing the missing market
prices for Huvis’s qualified-grade and purified terephthalic acids using facts available. It
constructed the market prices by first calculating an average profit rate taken from the
supplier’s submitted financial statements. It then increased the costs of production by
that profit rate to form constructed market prices for each of the qualified-grade and
purified terephthalic acids. Applying the major input rule, Commerce found that the
constructed market prices were the highest of the three measures for both the qualified-
grade and purified terephthalic acids, so it determined that the value of each of those
products was its market price, as constructed. For middle-grade terephthalic acid, the
highest of the three measures was the transfer price, so Commerce determined that the
value of the middle-grade terephthalic acid was its transfer price. The following chart
2009-1021 4
demonstrates the relative values for each product. In the chart, “r” represents the profit
rate that Commerce applied.
Qualified-Grade Middle-Grade Purified
Terephthalic Acid Terephthalic Terephthalic Acid
Acid
Highest Measure (QTA transfer (MTA transfer (PTA transfer price)
Provided by Huvis price) price)
Value (Highest Measure (QTA constructed (MTA transfer (PTA constructed
After Constructing market price) = price) market price) =
Missing Measures, the (QTA cost of (PTA cost of
Result of Applying production) x (1+r) production) x (1+r)
Major Input Rule)
Huvis challenged Commerce’s application of the major input rule in the Court of
International Trade, arguing that substantial evidence did not support the constructed
market prices that Commerce had calculated to fill in the missing market prices for
qualified-grade and purified terephthalic acids. The court held that the prices
Commerce had constructed were consistent with the statutory requirements and
supported by substantial evidence, as Commerce had used Huvis’s own data in
calculating the market prices and had not applied adverse inferences against Huvis.
But the court held that Commerce’s construction of the market prices was not consistent
with Commerce’s established practice, which had previously been, according to the
court, to use the highest available measure rather than constructing a measure, i.e.,
market price, that was otherwise unavailable. Thus, the court remanded for Commerce
either to use only the available measures provided by Huvis, i.e., transfer price and cost
of production, in applying the major input rule, or to adequately explain its reason for
treating Huvis differently in this administrative review than it had in prior administrative
reviews.
2009-1021 5
On remand, Commerce explained its change in treatment, stating that it had
recognized for the first time that it had evidence on the record that could be used to
construct a market price, providing “a more complete analysis under the major input
rule, and result[ing] in a more accurate calculation of Huvis’s dumping margin.” Huvis II,
2008 Ct. Intl. Trade Lexis 82, at *5. When Huvis returned to the Court of International
Trade, the court found that the explanation was reasoned, explaining that Commerce is
free to change its methodology to improve accuracy and that Huvis did not detrimentally
rely on the prior practice. Thus, the court affirmed Commerce’s application of the major
input rule.
Huvis timely appealed the Court of International Trade’s decision. We have
jurisdiction pursuant to 28 U.S.C. § 1295(a)(5).
DISCUSSION
“We review the Court of International Trade’s judgment, affirming or reversing the
final results of an administrative review, de novo.” Fag Kugelfischer Georg Schafer AG
v. United States, 332 F.3d 1370, 1372 (Fed. Cir. 2003). In so doing, “[w]e apply anew
the same standard used by the court, and will uphold Commerce’s determination unless
it is unsupported by substantial evidence on the record, or otherwise not in accordance
with law.” Yancheng Baolong Biochem. Prods. Co. v. United States, 337 F.3d 1332,
1333 (Fed. Cir. 2003) (citation and internal quotation marks omitted). However, “we
give great weight to the informed opinion of the Court of International Trade . . . , [and] it
is nearly always the starting point of our analysis.” Nippon Steel Corp. v. United States,
458 F.3d 1345, 1351 (Fed. Cir. 2006) (quotation marks and citation omitted).
Substantial evidence means “more than a mere scintilla” and “such relevant evidence
2009-1021 6
as a reasonable mind might accept as adequate to support a conclusion.” Suramerica
de Aleaciones Laminadas, C.A. v. United States, 44 F.3d 978, 985 (Fed. Cir. 1994)
(quoting Consol. Edison Co. v. NLRB, 305 U.S. 197, 229 (1938)). “[T]he substantiality
of evidence must take into account whatever in the record fairly detracts from its
weight,” including “contradictory evidence or evidence from which conflicting inferences
could be drawn.” Suramerica, 44 F.3d at 985 (quotation marks omitted).
Huvis argues that Commerce’s decision to use a constructed market price in
applying the major input rule was both unsupported by substantial evidence and
contrary to law. Huvis asserts that Commerce’s standard practice was to use only the
available measures, cost of production and transfer price, in applying the major input
rule when market price data was unavailable. Thus, according to Huvis, this practice
became “law of the proceeding,” and Huvis reasonably expected Commerce to adhere
to it. Huvis argues that such law of the proceeding does not require a showing of
detrimental reliance on the standard practice, and, even if Huvis did have to show
reliance, it never had a chance to present such evidence to the Court of International
Trade. Huvis also argues that, in general, Commerce may not depart from a consistent
past practice without explanation, and it did not explain what was different in this review
from the four preceding reviews. Huvis argues that Commerce claims only to have
recognized for the first time in this review that it could construct a market price based on
existing evidence, so, according to Huvis, Commerce did not actually find any new
evidence that would justify a departure from past practice.
Huvis also argues that Commerce’s method of constructing a market price
unlawfully violated Huvis’s statutory rights. Huvis contends that Commerce unlawfully
2009-1021 7
penalized Huvis for failing to provide information that it was unable to provide.
According to Huvis, Commerce disregarded the cost of production, which was available
information that Huvis provided and was necessary to its determination, violating
19 U.S.C. § 1677m(e). Huvis further asserts that Commerce’s methodology for
constructing a market price was both adverse to Huvis and demonstrably inaccurate, in
violation of 19 U.S.C. § 1677e(b) and (c). According to Huvis, even though the record
establishes that qualified-grade terephthalic acid is, on average, of lower quality and
less expensive than middle-grade terephthalic acid, the relative values were switched
after Commerce constructed the market price for qualified-grade terephthalic acid and
applied the major input rule, resulting in a higher value for qualified-grade acid than
middle-grade acid. Moreover, since Commerce constructed the market price by
marking up the cost of production by an average profit margin, Huvis asserts that the
resulting market price will always be higher than the cost of production. Thus,
according to Huvis, Commerce’s method effectively eliminates the cost of production
from the comparison and will always be adverse to importers, contravening the statutory
scheme.
The government responds that Commerce’s decision to construct a market price
was both supported by substantial evidence and not contrary to law. According to the
government, Commerce had no consistent prior practice that it was required to continue
to follow, and Huvis never submitted or identified evidence of detrimental reliance on
any prior methodology. The government adds that Commerce had previously advised
Huvis that it would use facts available to fill in missing measures, as long as there were
reasonable, non-adverse data on the record to do so. Indeed, according to the
2009-1021 8
government, Commerce had done the same thing in reviews of other imports. The
government also argues that Commerce may deviate from its past practice when it
reasonably explains its reasons for departure, and, according to the government,
Commerce did so here. The government asserts that Commerce adequately explained
why it treated Huvis differently in the fifth review than it did in earlier reviews, as it only
then realized that record evidence would support a constructed market price and
improve its accuracy.
The government also responds that its method for constructing market prices
was consistent with Congress’s statutory scheme. According to the government,
market price data was necessary to apply the major input rule, as the rule requires a
comparison of three measures, one of which is market price. Because market price
data were not available, the government argues that Commerce permissibly relied upon
the facts available to determine market prices for the major inputs. According to the
government, Commerce did not ignore the submitted costs of production in violation of
19 U.S.C. § 1677m(e); indeed, it used cost of production as an element to construct a
market price and it used cost of production for the ultimate comparison required by the
major input rule. Thus, according to the government, Commerce complied with the
statute. The government also asserts that the data upon which Commerce relied were
reasonable, not adverse, and supported by substantial evidence, in compliance with
19 U.S.C. § 1677e(b) and (c). The government argues that, to construct market prices,
Commerce used verified information submitted by Huvis, including its supplier’s audited
financial statements. Even though qualified-grade terephthalic acid is normally less
expensive than middle-grade terephthalic acid, according to the government, Huvis
2009-1021 9
acknowledges that sometimes the relationship between prices actually is reversed, with
qualified-grade being more expensive than middle-grade. The government therefore
asserts that Commerce was justified in producing an outcome wherein the qualified-
grade value determined by applying the major input rule was greater than the middle-
grade value determined by the rule. Thus, according to the government, Commerce
applied a reasonable, statutorily based methodology.
We conclude that the Court of International Trade correctly found Commerce’s
methodology for applying the major input rule to be supported by substantial evidence
and adequately explained, in accordance with the law. In general, an agency may
deviate from a past practice when “the new policy is permissible under the statute, . . .
there are good reasons for it, and . . . the agency believes it to be better, which the
conscious change of course adequately indicates.” FCC v. Fox Television Stations,
Inc., 129 S. Ct. 1800, 1811 (2009). Thus, Commerce need only show that its
methodology is permissible under the statute and that it had good reasons for the new
methodology.
A. Commerce’s Methodology Was Permissible Under the Statute
We agree with the government that Commerce’s decision to construct a market
price was in accordance with the governing statutes. We have found permissible
Commerce’s interpretation of the major input rule, which uses as the value the highest
of the three measures, viz. transfer price, cost of production, and market price. See
NTN Bearing Corp. of Am. v. United States, 368 F.3d 1369, 1374–76 (Fed. Cir. 2004).
Huvis argues that the constructed market price always consists of adding an amount to
the cost of production, meaning the constructed market price will always be higher than
2009-1021 10
the cost of production, and cost of production is therefore effectively ignored. That
system, according to Huvis, violates 19 U.S.C. § 1677m(e) by ignoring available
information that Huvis provided and was necessary to Commerce’s determination.
However, Commerce’s decision to construct a market price did not ignore the cost of
production data. In fact, cost of production was taken into account twice in Commerce’s
application of the major input rule. First, Commerce used the cost of production to
construct the market price. Second, Commerce included the cost of production in the
comparison of the three measures to calculate a value. Further, we agree with the
government that the constructed market price will not always be higher than the cost of
production, so even the comparison of the three measures does not ignore cost of
production. If, for example, Huvis were to take a loss on a certain product, the profit
rate would be negative, and the resulting market price would be lower than the cost of
production; therefore, the value determined by applying the major input rule would be
the cost of production. Thus, Commerce’s methodology did not violate 19 U.S.C.
§ 1677m(e).
Huvis also asserts that Commerce’s methodology for constructing a market price
was adverse to Huvis and demonstrably inaccurate, in violation of 19 U.S.C. § 1677e(b)
and (c). The parties agree that Huvis did not fail to cooperate in the investigation, so
Commerce was not entitled to use adverse inferences against Huvis under § 1677e(b).
Even when Commerce uses adverse inferences, it must use a “reasonably accurate
estimate of the respondent’s actual rate” when using “facts available.” F.Lii de Cecco di
Filippo Fara S. Martino S.p.A. v. United States, 216 F.3d 1027, 1032 (Fed. Cir. 2000).
2009-1021 11
We disagree with Huvis’s argument that the constructed market price is
demonstrably inaccurate or constitutes an adverse inference against Huvis. As
evidence, Huvis points to the relative market prices of qualified-grade and middle-grade
terephthalic acids. Qualified-grade has more impurities, making it presumably of lower
quality, than middle-grade acid. However, the constructed market price of qualified-
grade acid is higher than the verified market price of middle-grade acid. Thus, Huvis
argues that Commerce’s method of constructing market prices is clearly inaccurate. We
disagree. As the government points out and the Court of International Trade found, the
higher level of impurities in qualified-grade acid does not necessarily mean that it should
have a lower market price. See Huvis II, 2008 Ct. Intl. Trade Lexis 82, at *7–9 n.2, *11–
12. Other factors affect market price. Indeed, the month-by-month transfer prices
reveal that Huvis paid more for qualified-grade acid than it did for middle-grade acid in
certain months, even though the average transfer price of qualified-grade acid was
lower.
Further, Commerce reasonably chose to construct the market price by adding the
cost of production to the profit margin, since there is no suggestion here that product
sales were unprofitable or that the profit margins were unusually low. 2 At oral
argument, Huvis pointed out that the profit margin that Commerce used was the
average profit margin for all of Samnam’s products, rather than a more precise profit
margin for the particular input, e.g., qualified-grade terephthalic acid. Oral Arg. 11:17–
11:44, May 4, 2009, available at http://oralarguments.cafc.uscourts.gov/mp3/2009-
1021.mp3. However, Huvis never argued, and presented no evidence, that the overall
2
Indeed, the constructed market price could be too low under the
Commerce methodology if it failed to take account of other costs.
2009-1021 12
average profit margin did not accurately reflect the profit margin for the particular input.
Huvis instead argued that “the profit margin used, it’s undisputed, was the profit margin
for the supplier company as a whole. That may or may not be accurate in terms of
reflecting correctly the profit on this particular input.” Id. (emphasis added). Thus,
rather than prove the inaccuracy of the profit margin directly, Huvis argued that it had
proven the inaccuracy of the profit margin as reflected in the relative market prices of
qualified-grade and middle-grade terephthalic acids. Id. at 9:20–9:39 (“The basis for our
position that it was unreasonable to use it for this input is the verified information that
the particular input here, this QTA, qualified terephthalic acid, is the least valuable, . . .
the lowest quality of the three different terephthalic acids.”). As we demonstrated
above, the mere fact that the relative market prices of qualified-grade and middle-grade
terephthalic acids were different than might have been expected, based on their
average transfer prices, does not prove that Commerce’s construction of market prices
was either inaccurate or adverse to Huvis. We therefore agree with the government
that Commerce’s constructed market price is not demonstrably inaccurate and does not
constitute an adverse inference against Huvis.
B. Commerce Had Good Reason for Its Change of Policy
We also agree with Commerce that it had good reason for changing its
methodology. When it changes a past practice, an agency must also show that there
are good reasons for its new policy. See Fox Television, 129 S. Ct. at 1811; Nippon
Steel Corp. v. U.S. Int’l Trade Comm’n, 494 F.3d 1371, 1378 n.5 (Fed. Cir. 2007) (“[T]he
Supreme Court requires us to give deference to agency decisions that embody policy
changes. When an agency decides to change course, however, it must adequately
2009-1021 13
explain the reason for a reversal of policy.” (internal citations omitted)). Sometimes an
agency must provide a more detailed justification than what would suffice for a new
policy created on a blank slate, such as when “its new policy rests upon factual findings
that contradict those which underlay its prior policy; or when its prior policy has
engendered serious reliance interests that must be taken into account.” Fox Television,
129 S. Ct. at 1811.
Here, Commerce stated that it changed its methodology to improve accuracy.
Improving accuracy is generally a good reason for a change in methodology. See SKF
USA, Inc. v. United States, 537 F.3d 1373, 1380 (Fed. Cir. 2008) (affirming a new
methodology that was changed to improve accuracy and stating that, “[w]ith respect to
Commerce’s decision to revise [its] methodology after 14 annual reviews utilizing [a
different] methodology, we have specifically affirmed changes to . . . methodologies by
Commerce where reasonable”); Fujian Mach. & Equip. Imp. & Exp. Corp. v. United
States, 178 F. Supp. 2d 1305, 1327 (Ct. Int’l Trade 2001) (“Commerce is free to discard
one methodology in favor of another, the better to calculate more accurate dumping
margins.”).
Although Commerce need not show that its “reasons for the new policy are better
than the reasons for the old one,” Fox Television, 129 S. Ct. at 1811, here, Commerce
stated its reasons for the new policy as improving accuracy. Thus, we address whether
substantial evidence supported Commerce’s belief that including a constructed market
price in the major input rule would improve the accuracy of the value. We agree with
the government that Commerce’s belief was reasonable. For the same reasons that we
discussed above with respect to 19 U.S.C. § 1277e(b) and (c), Commerce reasonably
2009-1021 14
believed that its constructed market price would improve the accuracy of the value. As
market price is reasonably defined in the circumstances of this case as the sum of the
cost of production and a profit margin, Commerce reasonably believed that it could
accurately estimate market price, given that Huvis provided both cost of production and
profit margin. Commerce also reasonably believed the supplier’s average profit margin
adequately represented the profit margin for each specific product, as Huvis offered no
evidence to the contrary. Commerce further reasonably believed that including a
market price measure in the comparison would improve the accuracy of the value, given
the statute’s requirement of a comparison of all three measures. Finally, Huvis’s
argument concerning the relative market prices of qualified-grade and middle-grade
acids is unavailing for the reasons discussed above, viz., that the market prices of the
two acids do not necessarily reflect their relative purities.
We also agree with the government that Huvis did not detrimentally rely on
Commerce’s old methodology used in multiple preceding reviews. See Fox Television,
129 S. Ct. at 1811; Fujian, 178 F. Supp. 2d at 1327 (“Commerce may not make minor
but disruptive changes in methodology where a respondent demonstrates its specific
reliance on the old methodology used in multiple preceding reviews.”); Shikoku Chems.
Corp. v. United States, 795 F. Supp. 417 (Ct. Int’l Trade 1992) (overturning Commerce’s
use of a slightly improved methodology when the respondent demonstrated that it had
set its prices in reliance on the old methodology). As the Court of International Trade
found, Huvis did not and could not show that it had detrimentally relied on any
consistent prior practice. Huvis did not report market price data to Commerce because
“Huvis was powerless to force its affiliated supplier to provide such data, or at least
2009-1021 15
Huvis represented as much to Commerce. Therefore, the absence of market price data
from the record was not the result of Huvis’s reliance on Commerce’s prior practice;
rather, it was due to its affiliated supplier’s intransigence.” Huvis II, 2008 Ct. Intl. Trade
Lexis 82, at *14. We therefore agree with the government that Commerce’s change in
methodology was reasonable and adequately explained and that no further explanation
was required, such that Commerce was free to change its methodology.
Commerce has therefore shown that its new methodology of constructing a
market price was permissible under the statute and that it had good reasons for the new
methodology. We have considered Huvis’s remaining arguments and find them
unpersuasive.
CONCLUSION
Accordingly, the judgment of the Court of International Trade affirming
Commerce’s valuation of Huvis’s imports is affirmed.
AFFIRMED
2009-1021 16