Fezzani v. Bear, Stearns & Co., Inc.

14-3983,09-4414-cv Fezzani v. Bear, Stearns & Co., Inc. UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE SECOND CIRCUIT April Term, 2011 (Decided: January 30, 2015) Docket No. 14-3983, 09-4414 - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - ON PETITION FOR REHEARING - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 1 MOHAMMED FEZZANI, CIRENACA FOUNDATION, DR. VICTORIA BLANK, LESTER 2 BLANK, JAMES BAILEY, JANE BAILEY, BAYDEL LTD., MARGARET BURGESS, 3 PATRICK BURGESS, BOOTLESVILLE TRUST, AND ADAM CUNG, 4 5 Plaintiffs-Appellants, 6 7 v. 8 9 BEAR, STEARNS & CO. INC., BEAR STEARNS SECURITIES CORP., RICHARD 10 HARRITON, MORRIS WOLFSON, ARIELLE WOLFSON, ABRAHAM WOLFSON, TOVIE 11 WOLFSON, ANDERER ASSOCIATES, BOSTON PARTNERS, WOLFSON EQUITIES, 12 TURNER SCHARER, CHAN SASHA FOUNDATION, UNITED CONGREGATION 13 MESERAH, ISAAC DWECK, INDIVIDUALLY AND AS CUSTODIAN FOR NATHAN 14 DWECK, BARBARA DWECK, MORRIS I. DWECK, RALPH I. DWECK, JACK 15 DWECK, FAHNESTOCK & CO. INC., BARRY GESSER, MICHAEL REITER, AND 16 APOLLO EQUITIES, 17 18 Defendants-Appellees, 19 20 ARTHUR BRESSMAN, ANDREW BRESSMAN, RICHARD ACOSTA, GLENN O'HARE, 21 JOSEPH SCANNI, BRETT HIRSCH, GARVEY FOX, MATTHEW HIRSCH, RICHARD 22 SIMONE, CHARLES PLAIA, JOHN MCANDRIS, JACK WOLYNEZ, ROBERT 23 GILBERT, FIRST HANOVER SECURITIES, INC., BANQUE AUDI SUISSE 24 GENEVE, FOZIE FARKASH, RAWAI RAES, BASIL SHIBLAQ, IYAD SHIBLAQ, 25 KEN STOKES, MILLO DWECK, BEATRICE DWECK, RICHARD DWECK, ISAAC B. 26 DWECK, HANK DWECK, and DONALD & CO., 27 28 Defendants. 29 30 - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 31 1 B e f o r e: WINTER, CABRANES, and LOHIER, Circuit Judges. 2 3 Petition for panel rehearing or rehearing en banc of a 4 portion of this panel’s opinion and summary order dated May 7, 5 2013, which affirmed the district court’s dismissal of federal 6 securities law fraud claims against a clearing broker and 7 individual investors. 716 F.3d 18; 527 Fed. Appx. 89. The 8 petition for panel rehearing is denied. 9 Judge Lohier concurs in part and dissents in part in a 10 separate opinion. 11 12 Max Folkenflik, Folkenflik & McGerity, New 13 York, New York, for Plaintiffs-Appellants. 14 15 Kerry A. Dziubek and Michael D. Schissel, 16 Arnold & Porter LLP, New York, New York, for 17 Defendants-Appellees Bear, Stearns & Co. Inc. 18 and Bear, Stearns Securities Corp. (Now J.P. 19 Morgan Securities Inc. and J.P. Morgan 20 Clearing Corp.). 21 22 Howard Wilson and Scott A. Eggers, Proskauer 23 Rose LLP, New York, New York, for 24 Defendant-Appellee Richard Harriton. 25 26 Anne K. Small, Michael A. Coley, Jacob H. 27 Stillman, John W. Avery, and Jeffrey A. 28 Berger, for amicus curiae The Securities and 29 Exchange Commission, Washington, DC. 30 31 WINTER, Circuit Judge: 32 33 This opinion addresses petitions for rehearing by appellants 34 from the court’s summary order and from the opinion filed the 35 same day. It also addresses an amicus brief filed by the 36 Securities and Exchange Commission in support of the Petition for 2 1 Rehearing from the panel opinion. Familiarity with the summary 2 order, the panel opinion, and the dissent from the panel opinion 3 is assumed. We deny appellants’ petitions. 4 I. 5 The petition for rehearing relating to the summary order 6 argues that this court’s decision in Levitt v. J.P. Morgan, 710 7 F.3d 454 (2d Cir. 2013), filed just before the summary order, is 8 inconsistent with that summary order with respect to the 9 complaint’s allegations of Bear Stearns’ liability as the 10 clearing broker for Baron’s fraud. We disagree. 11 We begin by noting that the issue in Levitt was whether the 12 common issues with regard to the liability of clearing brokers 13 for the fraud or manipulation of introducing brokers so 14 predominated over individual issues as to justify certification 15 of a class. See Fed. R. Civ. P. 23(b)(3). That issue 16 necessarily caused a discussion of the caselaw governing such 17 liability. That discussion stated in part: 18 III. Duty of a Clearing Broker (Generally) 19 We have previously said that “a clearing 20 ‘agent [ ]’ is generally under no fiduciary 21 duty to the owners of the securities that 22 pass through its hands” . . . . 23 24 [D]istrict courts in this Circuit have 25 distinguished two categories of cases. 26 First, in cases where a clearing broker was 27 simply providing normal clearing services, 28 district courts have declined to “impose [ ] 29 liability on the clearing broker for the 30 transgressions of the introducing broker.” 31 Fezzani v. Bear, Stearns & Co., 592 F.Supp.2d 3 1 410, 425-26 (S.D.N.Y. 2008). The district 2 courts have so held even if the clearing 3 broker was alleged to have known that the 4 introducing broker was committing fraud, 5 Fezzani, 592 F.Supp.2d at 425; even if the 6 clearing broker was alleged to have been 7 clearing sham trades for the introducing 8 broker . . . and even if the clearing broker 9 was alleged to have failed to enforce margin 10 requirements against the introducing broker 11 -- thereby allowing the introducing broker’s 12 fraud to continue -- in violation of Federal 13 Reserve and NYSE rules. 14 15 In the second, much more limited 16 category of cases, district courts have found 17 plaintiffs’ allegations to be adequate -- and 18 so have permitted claims to proceed -- where 19 a clearing broker is alleged effectively to 20 have shed its role as clearing broker and 21 assumed direct control of the introducing 22 firm’s operations and its manipulative 23 scheme. Thus, in Berwecky v. Bear, Stearns & 24 Co., 197 F.R.D. 65 (S.D.N.Y. 2000), the 25 district court granted class certification in 26 a suit brought by investors against clearing 27 broker Bear, Stearns for its role in the 28 introducing firm A.R. Baron & Company’s 29 (“Baron”) scheme to defraud investors. The 30 Berwecky plaintiffs allege that Bear Stearns 31 “asserted control over Baron’s trading 32 operations by, inter alia, placing Bear, 33 Stearns’ employees at Baron’s offices to 34 observe Baron’s trading activities, approving 35 or declining to execute certain trades, 36 imposing restrictions on Baron’s inventory, 37 and loaning funds to Baron.” Id. at 67. The 38 plaintiffs alleged that Bear Stearns asserted 39 control over Baron’s activities “in order to 40 keep A.R. Baron a viable concern while Bear, 41 Stearns . . . continued to reap the large 42 profits they received from their activities 43 with A.R. Baron.” Id. The district court 44 found the allegations that Bear Stearns 45 “control[led]” the implementation of the 46 scheme to manipulate the price of securities 47 sold by Baron sufficient to satisfy Rule 48 23(b)(3)’s predominance requirement. Id. at 4 1 68-69. 2 3 Levitt, 710 F.3d at 465-67 (some internal citations omitted). 4 The petition argues that Levitt held that the allegations in 5 Berwecky were sufficient to state a claim for relief under Rule 6 12(b)(6) against a clearing broker. The petition further notes, 7 correctly, that the allegations in Berwecky that “[Bear Stearns] 8 asserted control over Baron’s trading operations by, inter alia, 9 placing Bear, Stearns’ employees at Baron’s offices to observe 10 Baron’s trading activities, approving or declining to execute 11 certain trades, imposing restrictions on Baron’s inventory and 12 loaning funds to Baron,” Berwecky, 197 F.R.D. at 67, are 13 substantially identical to those in the present case. The 14 complaint here alleges that “Bear Stearns assumed control over 15 and sent Bear employees to Baron to ‘enforce that control’” and 16 required that every trade ticket be checked and “reviewed every 17 order at this discretion [to] determine whether to execute the 18 trade.” Thus, because the pertinent factual allegations in the 19 present case and Berwecky are substantially identical, the 20 petition concludes that our affirmance by summary order resolved 21 the merits of the claim incorrectly. 22 However, Levitt also cited the district court opinion in 23 Fezzani twice favorably, the very decision that our summary order 24 affirmed, and any seeming inconsistency evaporates once it is 25 recognized that Levitt’s discussion quoted above was entirely in 5 1 the context of determining only whether a class was properly 2 certified under Fed. R. Civ. P. 23(b)(3) and not whether the 3 factual allegations were sufficient under Rule 12(b)(6). Levitt, 4 710 F.3d at 465. Indeed, Berwecky was itself a district court 5 decision under Rule 23(b), and the issues regarding the legal 6 sufficiency of the allegations were never finally determined. 7 Berwecky, 197 F.R.D. at 68-69. 8 The issues regarding the sufficiency of the pleadings under 9 Rule 12(b)(6) are quite different from those regarding 10 certification of a class pursuant to Rule 23(b)(3). Whereas the 11 Rule 12(b)(6) inquiry goes to the merits, the Rule 23(b)(3) issue 12 is whether “law or fact questions common to the class predominate 13 over questions affecting individual members.” In re Initial Pub. 14 Offerings Sec. Litig., 471 F.3d 24, 32 (2d Cir. 2006). As the 15 Supreme Court noted in Amgen Inc. v. Connecticut Ret. Plans & 16 Trust Funds, although 17 a court’s class-certification analysis must 18 be “rigorous” and may “entail some overlap 19 with the merits of the plaintiff’s underlying 20 claim,” Wal-Mart Stores, Inc. v. Dukes, 564 21 U.S. 131 S. Ct. 2541, 2551 (2011), Rule 23 22 grants courts no license to engage in free- 23 ranging merits inquiries at the certification 24 stage. Merits questions may be considered to 25 the extent -- but only to the extent -- that 26 they are relevant to determining whether the 27 Rule 23 prerequisites for class certification 28 are satisfied. 29 30 133 S. Ct. 1184, 1194-95 (2013). 31 Therefore, Levitt’s comment on Berwecky at most held that 6 1 Bear Stearns’ alleged “control” of Baron was “sufficient to 2 satisfy Rule 23(b)(3)’s predominance requirement.” Levitt, 710 3 F.3d at 467 (citing Berwecky, 197 F.R.D. at 68-69). 4 Because Levitt is not in conflict with our summary order in 5 Fezzani, the present panel did not overlook or misapprehend the 6 law as is required for rehearing by F.R.A.P. 40(a)(2). We, 7 therefore, reaffirm our holding that Bear Stearns’ conduct as 8 alleged in the Amended Complaint is not sufficient to state a 9 claim for relief under Section 10(b) and Rule 10(b)(5). While 10 the Amended Complaint alleges in conclusory fashion that Bear 11 Stearns asserted “control” over Baron’s trading activity, it 12 fails to allege facts showing how this “control” related to 13 fabricating “market” prices of particular securities and 14 communicating them to customers or to manipulating prices with 15 regard to any particular securities. Appellants allege that Bear 16 Stearns was aware of the manipulations, knew that these 17 manipulations were leading to a crisis, but continued to clear 18 trades that did not involve unnecessary exposure to itself. 19 Knowledge alone, however, is not enough to attach liability to a 20 clearing broker under Section 10(b). ATSI Commc’ns, Inc. v. 21 Shaar Fund, Ltd., 493 F.3d 87, 102 (2d Cir. 2007). Moreover, 22 there are legitimate reasons for clearing brokers to monitor the 23 trading activities of some introducing brokers. A clearing 24 broker guarantees the performance of buyers and sellers of the 7 1 securities being traded and often extends credit to clearing 2 brokers. Indeed, the complaint states that Baron was in deep 3 debt to Bear Stearns, reason enough to monitor Baron’s 4 activities. 5 The facts alleged in the Amended Complaint, if proven, would 6 not show that Bear Stearns directed the fraud or instructed Baron 7 or Dweck1 to set up sham transactions. There is a real danger of 8 harm to the financial industry in allowing such allegations to 9 suffice to subject clearing brokers to the cost of discovery and 10 perhaps a trial even though there is no evidence of participation 11 by the brokers in the fraud or manipulation. The potential of 12 such litigation would deter clearing brokers from engaging in 13 normal business activities -- guaranteeing performance, extending 14 credit, and therefore often monitoring the financial condition of 15 introducing brokers -- and drive up costs of trading generally. 16 See Stoneridge Inv. Partners, LLC v. Scientific-Atlanta, 552 U.S. 17 148, 163-64 (2008) (“extensive discovery and the potential for 18 uncertainty and disruption in a lawsuit allow plaintiffs with 19 weak claims to extort settlements from innocent companies,” and 20 because “contracting parties might find it necessary to protect 21 against these threats, [this may] rais[e] the costs of doing 1 Isaac R. Dweck is sued individually and as a custodian for Nathan Dweck, Barbara Dweck, Morris I. Dweck, Ralph I. Dweck, and Jack Dweck. Although appellants refer broadly to “the Dwecks,” their allegations regarding the Dwecks seem to involve only Isaac R. Dweck. 8 1 business” and “[o]verseas firms . . . could be deterred from 2 doing business” in United States security markets.). The 3 complaint similarly alleges that Bear Stearns lent Baron money 4 and propped it up, but this activity is integral to the ordinary 5 clearing function of a clearing broker.2 Finally, appellants 6 fail to claim that Bear Stearns’ alleged “control” was sufficient 7 to render it a Section 20(a) control person with respect to 8 Baron. The petition for panel rehearing with respect to Bear 9 Stearns is, therefore, denied. 10 II. 11 We also address arguments, echoed in appellants’ petition 12 for rehearing, made in an amicus brief filed by the SEC. The SEC 2 Appellants additionally argue that (1) they relied on Bear Stearns’s confirmation statements in future purchases of stock; (2) the confirmations and monthly statements were themselves manipulative acts directed at plaintiffs; and (3) the panel overlooked binding state court precedent as to aiding and abetting liability. None of these arguments warrant rehearing. Arguments (1) and (2) may be rejected because appellants have still failed to sufficiently allege conduct not involving the ordinary functions of a clearing broker, as discussed above. Argument (3) -- regarding plaintiffs’ state law claim of aiding and abetting fraud -- may also be easily dismissed. The District Court here dismissed that claim on the basis that “[a]s a matter of law, clearing brokers are not responsible or liable for the fraudulent sales practices of the introducing broker.” Fezzani v. Bear, Stearns & Co., 592 F. Supp. 2d 410, 426 (S.D.N.Y. 2008) (citing Greenberg v. Bear, Stearns & Co., 220 F.3d 22, 29 (2d Cir. 2000)). Although Judge Crotty relied on federal rather than state precedent, the Greenberg case’s holding on this point is expressly as to New York state aiding and abetting liability. New York state law is not to the contrary, and we have recently reaffirmed exactly this principle. See In re Amaranth Natural Gas Commodities Litig., 730 F.3d 170, 185 (2d Cir. 2013) (“[T]he mere performance of routine clearing services cannot constitute the aiding and abetting of fraud under New York law.” (emphasis added)); Levitt, 710 F.3d at 466 (“Not does the ‘simple providing of normal clearing services to a primary broker who is acting in violation of the law . . . make out a case of aiding and abetting against the clearing broker.’” (quoting Greenberg, 220 F.3d at 29)). 9 1 incorrectly reads our opinion as holding that, in any and all 2 manipulation cases, liability attaches only to persons who 3 communicate a misrepresentation to a victim. The SEC argues that 4 “[t]he essence of manipulation is not a misrepresentation, but 5 market activity -- the buying and selling of shares -- that 6 itself creates a ‘false pricing signal.’ A manipulative 7 transaction, such as parking, is an ‘intentional interference 8 with the free forces of supply and demand’” (quoting ATSI, 493 9 F.3d at 100; In re Pagel, Inc., 33 S.E.C. 1003, 1985 WL 548387, 10 *3 (1985), aff’d, 803 F.2d 942 (8th Cir. 1986)). Arguing that 11 our opinion conflated manipulative conduct with 12 misrepresentations, the brief further states: 13 This Court has similarly recognized that 14 engaging in manipulative acts -- practices 15 ‘that are intended to mislead investors by 16 artificially affecting market activity’ -- 17 are violations distinct from making 18 ‘misrepresentations.’ Ganino v. Citizens 19 Utils. Co., 228 F.3d 154, 161 (2d Cir. 2000). 20 Emphasizing that distinction is this Court’s 21 ruling that a manipulation claim requires 22 ‘market activity aimed at deceiving investors 23 as to how other market participants have 24 valued a security.’ ATSI, 493 F.3d at 99- 25 100, 105 (emphasis added). 26 27 [Pet. Panel Rehear. 4] 28 We write only to state the obvious: our opinion did not 29 require that reliance by a victim on direct oral or written 30 communications by a defendant must be shown in every manipulation 31 case. Indeed, we agree with the propositions of law asserted by 10 1 the SEC that, in a manipulation claim, a showing of reliance may 2 be based on “market activity” intended to mislead investors by 3 sending “a false pricing signal to the market,” upon which 4 victims of the manipulation rely. ATSI, 493 F.3d at 100. 5 However, the discussion in ATSI of “false pricing signal[s] 6 to the market” is derived from the Supreme Court’s use of the 7 efficient market hypothesis to establish a rebuttable presumption 8 of reliance based on the effect of misrepresentations on the 9 market price of securities. Basic Inc. v. Levinson, 485 U.S. 10 224, 241-45 (1988). ATSI extended a variation of that theory to 11 market prices affected by manipulation. In the present case, 12 however, there is no claim that there existed a market in any 13 sense of the word for the shares Baron sold to appellants. The 14 shares in question are not alleged to have been traded in any 15 structure reasonably viewed as an independent market with 16 publicly reported prices purportedly representing arms-length 17 transactions based on supply and demand. See ATSI, 493 F.3d at 18 100-01 & n.4. Therefore, there is not a claim that the inflated 19 prices paid by appellants were based on “false pricing signal[s] 20 to the market.” The allegations in the present complaint state 21 only that Baron sold shares to appellants at prices that were 22 manufactured by Baron salespeople but were represented as set by 23 trading in a market that was falsely represented to exist. 24 The appellants’ and the SEC’s concerns that our opinion 11 1 disregarded ATSI are, therefore, wholly unfounded. Not only did 2 our opinion cite ATSI repeatedly and quote extensively from it, 3 but it read ATSI in a way favorable to manipulation claims. Our 4 opinion stated the “market” “signaled” by manipulative conduct 5 need not be fully efficient -- a highly efficient market is an 6 unlikely site for manipulation, see Fezzani v. Bear, Stearns & 7 Co. Inc., 716 F.3d 18, 21 n.2 (2d Cir. 2013) -- and suggested 8 that a future court might create a rebuttable presumption of 9 reliance in a less-than-efficient market context. See id. What 10 we did not, and could not, say was that ATSI’s holding and 11 rationale applies where no actual ongoing market for the 12 securities in question exists. 13 Our point is illustrated by the claims against Dweck. There 14 is no allegation that Dweck’s parking transactions, and their 15 purported prices, were ever reported in a market. Indeed, there 16 is no allegation that the “prices” used in the parking 17 transactions -- or in sham transactions by others coordinated 18 with the parking -- were ever made known to the buyers of the 19 securities in question or that the securities were sold to 20 appellants at prices “signaled” by the prices used in the parking 21 or coordinated transactions. There are, in short, no factual 22 allegations that Dweck’s parking transactions sent “a signal” to 23 any identified market or that any buyer or seller relied upon the 24 parking prices. In the entire 116-page complaint, appellants 12 1 have not specifically pleaded a causal link between any single 2 stock purchase or sale and a corresponding parking by Dweck or 3 coordinated transactions by others. See ATSI, 493 F.3d at 106- 4 07. 5 Even though each of the individual plaintiffs must show 6 reliance on a misrepresentation for which the particular 7 defendant is responsible, there is no factual allegation by any 8 of the eleven individual plaintiffs as to how the various 9 “signals,” “appearances,” or “illusions” emphasized in the 10 dissent as created by Dweck’s parking moved the price they paid 11 for particular shares. Much of the dissent turns on an attempt 12 to confine the purposes of “parking” to avoiding downward 13 pressure on a security’s market price. But parking, a tactic 14 that we agree can be a serious violation, can have many purposes. 15 To establish this, we need look no further than the SEC’s own 16 description of Baron’s frauds. Having found the lack of an 17 independent market for the securities fraudulently sold by Baron, 18 the SEC stated that “[w]hile persons may park stock for a variety 19 of reasons[,] Baron parked stock to maintain the appearance of 20 compliance with the commission’s net capital rules.” In re Bear, 21 Sterns Secs. Corp., 705 S.E.C. 537, 1999 WL 569554, *3 n.6 22 (1999). 23 We do not reject the “signals” theory. Far from it. We 24 simply recognize that it is a red herring given the nature of 13 1 appellants’ claims. The pleading gaps described above are hardly 2 unintentional. The complaint seeks damages from all defendants 3 for all losses of all plaintiffs whether or not a particular 4 defendant is alleged to have engaged in a sham transaction in a 5 security purchased by a particular plaintiff. For example, 6 appellants’ claims against Dweck lump together sales of 7 securities that Dweck did not park with those of securities he 8 did park. Appellants claim that Dweck is liable for all of the 9 losses of all of the plaintiffs whether or not the securities 10 they bought were the subject of Dweck’s parking transactions.3 11 Clearly, ATSI’s reference to false pricing signals to a market 12 necessarily has to involve -- in private actions for damages -- 13 allegations of: (i) particular securities (ii) manipulated by 14 particular defendants (iii) causing the losses to the particular 15 buyers. See ATSI, 493 F.3d at 101-02. Appellant claims fail to 16 meet that requirement. 17 To sum up, the facts alleged in this complaint do not 18 involve any ongoing market affected by false pricing signals by 19 Dweck. What they involve are misrepresentations to the victims 20 by Baron salespeople as to how the price they were charging for 21 particular securities was arrived at. Dweck’s role in parking 3 The complaint alleges on page 107 that Dweck is liable for losses in the “Manipulated Securities.” Page 3 of the complaint defines “Manipulated Securities” to include several companies whose stock Dweck is not alleged to have parked or manipulated. 14 1 certain securities was unknown to, and not relied upon by, those 2 who purchased identical securities, much less by those who 3 purchased securities not parked by Dweck. Although the complaint 4 occasionally references an “inflated” market or “price 5 movements,” there is no allegation that customers relied on 6 publicly reported prices4 or anything other than the fraudulent 7 representations of Baron salespeople. For all that appears in the 8 complaint, the stock parking may have been intended to deceive 9 regulators, as actually found by the SEC, 70 S.E.C. 537, 1999 WL 10 569554, *3-4, and perhaps Bear Stearns, but is not alleged to 11 have caused particular transactions. Our dissenting colleagues’ 12 discussion of market manipulation, while indisputable in the 13 abstract, is used to create a theory of manipulation in the 4 The SEC’s amicus brief states, in a footnote, that “the Commission previously found, and as judicially noticeable material confirms (i.e., news items, trading records, and public filings) the relevant securities traded ‘in over-the-counter markets’ (i.e., NASDAQ) and on AMEX. In re Bear, Stearns Secs. Corp., 54 S.E.C. 224, 228 (1999).” The citation has not led us to any SEC decision, much less one “finding” public trading of the securities in question. What the footnote may be referencing is a 1999 SEC decision, see In re Bear, Stearns Secs. Corp., 70 S.E.C. 537, 1999 WL 569554, *2 (1999), that includes a cursory description of Baron’s intended activities when it was founded in 1992: “Bressman and others established Baron in 1992 to underwrite the issuance of securities of small issuers trading in the over-the-counter markets, and to carry on market-making and retail sales of such securities.” This description hardly suffices to remedy the lack of any allegations in the complaint that transactions in the relevant securities and their pricing were publicly available or that the prices communicated by Baron salespeople were in any way related to publicly reported prices. Finally, and dispositively, even if publicly reported transactions with a connection to sales by Baron were alleged, they would not support the claims asserted in the complaint, which seeks to hold all defendants liable for all of the plaintiffs’ losses. The suggestion that we take judicial notice of various unidentified documents that may or may not show public trades seems rather anomalous in light of the failure of the 116-page complaint to mention them and of the amicus brief’s failure to provide detail. In any event, even if we discovered some public trading, that would not remedy the other problems described above. 15 1 absence of a market. 2 Given these facts, Stoneridge clearly applies to the claims 3 against Dweck. There is no presumption of reliance based on any 4 identifiable market, and -- given the lack of an allegation that 5 any plaintiff knew of the stock parking or prices used therein -- 6 no allegation of reliance upon the parking transactions. See 7 Stoneridge, 552 U.S. at 159-60. 8 Finally, as we noted in our opinion, although claiming that 9 defendants are liable for all losses of all investors caused by 10 Baron, whether or not the losses involved sham transactions by a 11 particular defendant, appellants have never offered either a 12 theory of vicarious liability under state law or of controlling- 13 person liability under federal law. The SEC’s amicus brief fails 14 even to purport to fill this gap. 15 16 1 LOHIER, Circuit Judge, concurring in part and dissenting in part: 2 The majority opinion today denies a petition for rehearing that I would 3 have granted in part.  I nevertheless commend my panel colleagues for clarifying 4 that the initial majority opinion in this case did not hold that the Supreme Court’s 5 decisions in Stoneridge and Janus1 require a plaintiff claiming market 6 manipulation to allege that a defendant directly communicated false information 7 to a victim.  Majority Op. at 10–11.  Because that opinion initially appeared to 8 foreclose the plaintiffs’ market manipulation claim against Israel Dweck, even 9 though plaintiffs alleged that he had engaged directly in a manipulation of 10 securities, I dissented on the ground that the opinion conflated the elements of a 11 misrepresentation claim and those of a manipulation claim.  In particular, it 12 appeared to ignore the well‐established theory of reliance based on the 13 fraud‐on‐the‐market doctrine.  See Fezzani v. Bear, Stearns & Co. Inc., 716 F.3d 14 18, 29 (2d Cir. 2013) (Lohier, J., dissenting).  As the Supreme Court recently 15 reaffirmed, that doctrine remains alive and well.  See Halliburton Co. v. Erica P. 16 John Fund, Inc., 134 S. Ct. 2398, 2409, 2413–15 (2014).  1  Stoneridge Inv. Partners, LLC v. Scientific‐Atlanta, Inc., 552 U.S. 148 (2008); Janus Capital Grp., Inc. v. First Derivative Traders, 131 S. Ct. 2296 (2011). 1 1 Prompted in part by the compelling arguments advanced by the Securities 2 and Exchange Commission as amicus curiae in support of the appellants’ petition 3 for rehearing, the majority’s denial of the petition helpfully corrects the 4 misimpressions left by the original majority opinion.  For example, it recognizes 5 that we have never required “that reliance by a victim on direct oral or written 6 communications by a defendant must be shown in every manipulation case.”2  7 Majority Op. at 10–11.  It also clarifies that “in a manipulation claim, a showing of 8 reliance may be based on ‘market activity’ intended to mislead investors by 9 sending ‘a false pricing signal to the market,’ upon which victims of the 10 manipulation rely.”  Id. at 11.  Of course, I agree; as I explained in my prior 11 dissent, to read our jurisprudence otherwise would be a mistake.  See Fezzani, 12 716 F.3d at 28–29 (Lohier, J., dissenting).  13 Nevertheless, I continue to dissent from the majority’s ongoing refusal to 14 let the plaintiffs’ claims against Dweck proceed.  We should grant the petition for 15 rehearing and vacate the District Court’s dismissal of those claims.  The majority 16 opinion’s denial of the petition is wrong because, in the process of correcting one 2  Here, I would replace the phrase “every manipulation case” with “any manipulation case.”  2 1 apparent error in the original opinion, it falls prey to two others.   2 The opinion’s first error is to suggest that the claims against Dweck 3 founder because they “lump together sales of [manipulated] securities that 4 Dweck did not park with those of securities he did park,” even though the 5 plaintiffs also allege that Dweck is responsible for losses in both categories of 6 securities.  Majority Op. at 13.  This is not a reason to dismiss these claims.  As an 7 initial matter, the plaintiffs’ treatment of the parked and unparked securities 8 together does not justify dismissing the complaint as to those securities that 9 Dweck is alleged to have parked.  More importantly, the opinion ignores the fact 10 that the alleged manipulative scheme here, like most “pump and dump” stock 11 manipulation schemes, involves a cluster of interdependent securities that the 12 defendants—Dweck included—manipulated in tandem by parking certain shares 13 of those securities with knowing nominees while selling other shares to 14 unwitting victims.  As the complaint describes it, “[i]f one security propped up 15 by the misconduct of defendants failed, all would fail.”  J.A., Vol. II, at 255.  In 16 other words, Dweck’s parking of certain securities helped to sustain the 17 defendants’ manipulation of all of the securities, and the allegations in the 18 complaint as to Dweck’s role in the manipulation support a claim for losses 3 1 associated with the overall market manipulation scheme. 2 The opinion makes a second, more serious set of errors.  It misunderstands 3 the relationship between parking transactions and the fraud‐on‐the‐market 4 doctrine, and it confuses the “signals” theory relating to parking transactions—a 5 theory the opinion purports to embrace, see Majority Op. at 13—with the direct 6 misrepresentation theory.  In unraveling these errors, I think it useful to define 7 “parking,” which, in the context of market manipulation, is no mere infraction; 8 people go to prison for it.  See, e.g., United States v. Russo, 74 F.3d 1383, 1386, 9 1393 (2d Cir. 1996); United States v. Regan, 937 F.2d 823, 829–30 (2d Cir.), 10 amended by 946 F.2d 188 (2d Cir. 1991).  We have described “parking” as 11 follows:  “[A]n artificial device to avoid depressing the market price [that] . . . 12 occurs when a broker, unable to keep securities in his trading account, ostensibly 13 sells the same to another broker, with the understanding that the same securities 14 will be purchased back by the ostensible seller before the settlement date.  In this 15 manner the shares are not sold into the [open] market.”  United States v. Corr, 16 543 F.2d 1042, 1045 n.5 (2d Cir. 1976); see also United States v. Bilzerian, 926 F.2d 17 1285, 1290 (2d Cir. 1991) (“‘Parking’ refers to a transaction in which a 18 broker‐dealer buys stock from a customer with the understanding that the 4 1 customer will buy the stock back at a later date for the purchase price plus 2 interest and commissions . . . [with] no market risk to the broker‐dealer who is 3 the owner of the shares in name only.”).  An illegal parking transaction keeps a 4 significant number of shares in the hands of a “friendly” nominee who agrees not 5 to sell the security and thereby avoids placing downward pressure on the share 6 price, as might occur if the security were sold legitimately on the open market.  In 7 turn, keeping the parked shares out of the market supply enables the defendant 8 to maintain better control over the tradeable shares and to manipulate the share 9 price more easily.   10 So defined, parking indisputably reflects an illegal sham transaction, an 11 artificial device designed to avoid depressing the market price of a security.  We 12 previously have recognized the tie between parking transactions and a fraud on 13 the market.  See Russo, 74 F.3d at 1393 (endorsing a theory pursuant to which a 14 broker‐dealer for whom defendants worked engaged in stock parking and 15 thereby “perpetrated a fraud on the market by divorcing the financial risk of 16 owning [the parked stock] from legal ownership of the stock”).  Commentators 17 have confirmed the connection.  See, e.g., Lewis D. Lowenfels & Alan R. 18 Bromberg, Securities Market Manipulations: An Examination and Analysis of 5 1 Domination and Control, Frontrunning, and Parking, 55 Alb. L. Rev. 293, 339–41 2 (1991).  3 The majority opinion does not quibble with the fact that the complaint 4 alleges a parking transaction more or less as defined above.  Instead, it derides 5 the complaint for not alleging that the specific prices used in Dweck’s parking 6 transactions “were ever reported in a market” or that the “‘prices’ used in the 7 parking transactions . . . were ever made known to the buyers of the securities in 8 question or that the securities were sold to appellants at prices ‘signaled’ by the 9 prices used in the parking . . . transactions.”  Majority Op. at 12.  But this 10 misunderstands one of the primary functions of parking schemes such as the one 11 alleged here:  to conceal rather than transmit real price information.  Here, the 12 relevant “signals” are not false pricing signals about the specific “prices used in 13 the parking transactions,” but rather include:  (1) creating the false appearance of 14 trading volume or activity in the parked security, (2) making it appear that 15 Dweck (and others) rather than the broker‐dealer was the beneficial owner of the 16 security who bore the financial risk of ownership, when, in fact, Dweck’s 17 financial risk as a nominal holder of the securities was divorced from his legal 18 ownership, (3) masking the number of shares of the manipulated securities that 6 1 the broker‐dealer actually controlled, and (4) creating the illusion that the parked 2 securities were trading on the open, liquid market, when in fact they were not.  In 3 my view, several paragraphs in the complaint plausibly allege that these signals, 4 among others, were transmitted to the market.  For example: 5   10.  Defendant[] Isaac R. Dweck . . . also engaged in 6 parking transactions with the purpose and effect of 7 creating a false appearance of an active trading market 8 with the intent of inflating the trading price of the 9 Manipulated Securities and causing investors, such as 10 plaintiffs to purchase the Manipulated Securities.  11 131.  Parking misl[ed] regulators and customers about 12 the amount of Baron Stocks in Baron’s own inventory, 13 and fictitiously improved Baronʹs net capital . . . .  The 14 placement of such stock also artificially maintained the 15 price of the Manipulated Stocks.  The “parking” was 16 done with the purpose and had the effect of creating a 17 false impression in the minds of Baron customers of the 18 value and liquidity of the “parked” securities and 19 induced Baron customers, including plaintiffs, to make 20 investments based on Baron’s illusion of trading 21 activity.  22 221.  . . . [Plaintiffs] were unaware that the market for 23 Baron stocks was entirely a fictional mirage.  Month 24 after month, they had received confirmations and 25 monthly statements from Bear Stearns which indicated 26 that the Baron stocks were trading in a bona fide 27 market.  Publicly available information on these stocks 28 further confirmed an active market where large 29 numbers of shares traded freely. . . .  [None of the] 7 1 plaintiffs[] knew that Bear Stearns, the Dweck 2 Defendants, . . . and all other defendants knew that 3 Baron simply cr[e]ated the illusion of an active market 4 through parking, wash sales, unauthorized purchases 5 and fraud. 6 319.  . . . Defendants’ fraudulent and manipulative 7 activities as described herein created the appearance 8 that the price at which the Manipulated Securities 9 traded reflected bona fide supply and demand in a 10 freely functioning market.  The increasing prices of the 11 Manipulated Securities appeared to indicate increasing 12 value, placed by the market, on the businesses 13 underlying the securities.  Thus, . . . the appearance of 14 an active, rising market induced plaintiffs to purchase 15 those securities in reliance upon the “wisdom of the 16 marketplace.”  Instead, the values placed by the market 17 on the Manipulated Securities were fictitious and solely 18 a result of defendants’ manipulative practices.  19 J.A., Vol. II, at 243, 281, 310, 340. 20 21 The majority opinion summarizes its reasons for denying the petition by 22 suggesting that the plaintiffs did not rely on the signals conveyed by Dweck’s 23 parking transactions, but relied instead on “misrepresentations by Baron sales 24 people as to how the price they were charging for particular securities was 25 arrived at.”  Majority Op. at 14.  The opinion concludes that “Dweck’s role in 26 parking certain securities was unknown to and not relied upon by those who 27 purchased” the securities.  Id.  On the one hand, to the extent that the majority 8 1 opinion can be understood to conclude that the plaintiffs failed to allege reliance 2 on Dweck’s role, it misses the point of the manipulative scheme, which was to 3 conceal rather than disclose Dweck’s role as a confederate who parked securities.  4 On the other hand, to the extent that the opinion suggests that the plaintiffs 5 inadequately alleged reliance on the effect of Dweck’s parking, as well as other 6 components of the manipulative scheme, that suggestion is contradicted by the 7 allegations quoted above.   8 I can’t help but to end by noting that the majority opinion trots out 9 Stoneridge yet again to reject the claims against Dweck, this time on the ground 10 that the plaintiffs did not allege “reliance upon the parking transactions.”  11 Majority Op. at 15.  I have previously explained and will not repeat why 12 Stoneridge does not apply to claims of market manipulation such as the one 13 alleged here, or why plaintiffs were not obliged to allege reliance on the parking 14 transactions themselves.     9 1 I respectfully dissent from the denial of the petition for rehearing as to the 2 claims against Dweck.3 3  The appellants’ arguments in their petition for rehearing relating to Bear Stearns and the summary order in this case are not without force.  Nevertheless, I agree with my panel colleagues that the appellants’ nearly exclusive reliance on Levitt v. J.P. Morgan Securities, Inc., 710 F.3d 454 (2d Cir. 2013), is misplaced.  Levitt is not necessarily inconsistent with the summary order and, as a technical matter, fails to provide a basis for rehearing under Rule 40(a) of the Federal Rules of Appellate Procedure.  I therefore concur in the result as to Bear Stearns.  I do not necessarily join the majority’s other reasons for rejecting the petition for rehearing as to Bear Stearns.  See, e.g., Majority Op. at 8 (“There is a real danger of harm to the financial industry in allowing such allegations to suffice to subject clearing brokers to the cost of discovery and perhaps a trial even though there is no evidence of participation by the brokers in the fraud or manipulation.”). 10