Steven A. Mueller, Bradley J. Brown, Mark A. Kruse, Kevin D. Miller, and Larry E. Phipps, on Behalf of Themselves and Those Like Situated v. Wellmark, Inc. D/B/A Wellmark Blue Cross and Blue Shield of Iowa, an Iowa Corporation, and Wellmark Health Plan of Iowa, Inc., an Iowa Corporation
IN THE SUPREME COURT OF IOWA
No. 13–1872
Filed February 27, 2015
STEVEN A. MUELLER, BRADLEY J. BROWN, MARK A. KRUSE,
KEVIN D. MILLER, and LARRY E. PHIPPS, on Behalf of Themselves
and Those Like Situated,
Appellants,
vs.
WELLMARK, INC. d/b/a WELLMARK BLUE CROSS AND BLUE
SHIELD OF IOWA, an Iowa Corporation, and WELLMARK HEALTH
PLAN OF IOWA, INC., an Iowa Corporation,
Appellees.
Appeal from the Iowa District Court for Polk County, Robert A.
Hutchison, Judge.
Plaintiff chiropractors appeal from a summary judgment entered
by the district court in favor of defendant health insurers on per se
antitrust claims under the Iowa Competition Law. AFFIRMED.
Glenn L. Norris of Hawkins & Norris, P.C., Des Moines; Harley C.
Erbe of Erbe Law Firm, Des Moines; Steven P. Wandro, Michael R. Keller,
and Shayla L. McCormally of Wandro & Associates, P.C., Des Moines, for
appellants.
Hayward L. Draper and Ryan G. Koopmans of Nyemaster Goode,
P.C., Des Moines, for appellees.
2
MANSFIELD, Justice.
Wellmark, Inc. is an Iowa-based health insurer that belongs to the
national Blue Cross and Blue Shield (BCBS) network. Wellmark has
contracted with health care providers in Iowa to provide services at
certain reimbursement rates. By agreement, Wellmark makes those
rates available both to self-insured Iowa plans that it administers and to
out-of-state BCBS affiliates when those entities provide coverage for
services provided in Iowa.
This appeal presents the question whether the foregoing
agreements between Wellmark and self-insuring employers and between
Wellmark and out-of-state BCBS affiliates amount to per se violations of
Iowa antitrust law. We conclude they do not. These arrangements are
not the simple horizontal conspiracies that historically have qualified for
per se treatment. Accordingly, and recognizing that the plaintiffs
stipulated they were proceeding only under a per se theory and not
under the rule of reason, we affirm the district court’s grant of summary
judgment to Wellmark.
I. Background Facts and Proceedings.
This case comes before us for the second time. See Mueller v.
Wellmark, Inc., 818 N.W.2d 244 (Iowa 2012).
Approximately seven years ago, a number of Iowa chiropractors
sued Wellmark, the largest health insurer in Iowa, in the Polk County
District Court. The suit challenged Wellmark’s reimbursement rates and
practices for chiropractic services and asked for class action certification.
One count of the plaintiffs’ petition sought relief under a variety of Iowa
insurance statutes. Mueller, 818 N.W.2d at 249 (noting plaintiffs sought
relief based upon allegations Wellmark engaged in discriminatory
practices in violation of Iowa Code sections 509.3(6), 514.7, 514.23(2),
3
514B.1(5)(c), 514F.2 (2007)). Another count pled that Wellmark had
entered into a contract, combination, or conspiracy in violation of section
553.4 of the Iowa Competition Law, the counterpart to section 1 of the
Federal Sherman Antitrust Act. Id.; see also 15 U.S.C. § 1 (2006). A
third count alleged that Wellmark had abused monopoly power in
violation of section 553.5 of the Iowa Competition Law, the counterpart
to section 2 of the Sherman Act. Mueller, 818 N.W.2d at 249; see also 15
U.S.C. § 2.
On Wellmark’s motion, the district court dismissed the claims
based on the insurance statutes. Mueller, 818 N.W.2d at 250. It found
no private cause of action was available under those laws. Id. The
district court later granted summary judgment to Wellmark on the
antitrust claims. Id. at 252. This ruling was primarily based on the
“state action” exemption in the Iowa Competition Law. Id.; see also Iowa
Code § 553.6(4) (providing that the Iowa Competition Law “shall not be
construed to prohibit . . . activities or arrangements expressly approved
or regulated by any regulatory body or officer acting under authority of
this state”). Plaintiffs appealed. Mueller, 818 N.W.2d at 253.
On appeal, we affirmed the dismissal of the claims under Iowa
insurance law. As we explained,
[O]ur legislature chose to provide the Iowa Insurance
Commissioner with exclusive powers to regulate health
insurance practices under these statutes. For these reasons,
we hold Iowa Code sections 509.3(6), 514.7, 514.23(2),
514B.1(5)(c), and 514F.2, enacted as part of H.F. 2219, do
not create a private cause of action.
Id. at 258.
However, we found that the state action exemption did not insulate
Wellmark’s reimbursement rates from antitrust review. We noted,
4
These regulations [cited by Wellmark] are not directed
to the regulation of rate differentials for particular services.
Their purpose, rather, is to insure that health insurers do
not abuse their overall relationship with patients and
providers through the use of preferred provider plans. Thus,
if a clinic decided to sue Wellmark under the Iowa
Competition Law alleging that Wellmark had engaged in
prohibited section 553.5 monopolization by excluding it from
a preferred provider arrangement, the section 553.6(4) state
action exemption might well apply. But, it does not appear
that the legislature has decided generally to remove the
setting of reimbursement rates by health insurance
companies from the operations of the marketplace or from
claims under the Iowa Competition Law.
Id. at 262 (footnote omitted). Yet, we affirmed the dismissal of some of
the chiropractors’ antitrust claims, including the Iowa Code section
553.5 monopolization claim, on alternate grounds that had been raised
by Wellmark. Id. at 264–66. Still, with respect to the section 553.4
conspiracy claim, “we reverse[d] the district court’s summary judgment
granting Wellmark a blanket exemption under section 553.6(4) from
charges that it engaged in anticompetitive price-fixing or term-fixing
schemes.” Id. at 264.
On remand, the plaintiffs stipulated that their only remaining
antitrust claims—alleging conspiracies between Wellmark and out-of-
state BCBS affiliates and between Wellmark and self-funding employers
that hired Wellmark to administer their plans—were being asserted on a
per se theory. As the plaintiffs stated,
Plaintiffs hereby agree and stipulate that the only violation of
Iowa Code § 553.4 alleged in the Fourth Amended and
Substituted Petition for Damages is for a contract,
combination or conspiracy between the Defendants and
(1) out-of-state Blues and (2) in-state self-funded employers
through administration contracts, to price fix by
establishment of a maximum price for services of Iowa
chiropractors in Wellmark’s provider network or through the
use of a restrictive or capitated payment system in
Wellmark’s HMO; and those alleged price fixing conspiracies
are alleged to violate Iowa Code § 553.4 based on Plaintiffs’
contention that they constitute per se violations of the Iowa
5
Competition Act. Plaintiffs’ allegations exclude a contention
that a rule of reason analysis is applicable to the violation of
Iowa Code § 553.4 alleged in the Fourth Amended and
Substituted Petition.
Thereafter, Wellmark moved for summary judgment again, this
time on the ground that neither of these alleged conspiracies was subject
to per se treatment. As Wellmark put it, “Sharing a provider network
does not amount to naked price fixing and is not subject to the per se
rule.” Wellmark urged that plaintiffs’ claims were potentially viable, if at
all, only under the rule of reason.
The summary judgment record revealed that employers wanting to
provide group health insurance to their employees can contract with
Wellmark in one of two ways. Either way, Wellmark makes its provider
network available at established reimbursement rates and handles
claims administration. However, if the employer self-insures, then the
employer is financially responsible for claims. On the other hand, when
Wellmark acts as an insurer in addition to a claims administrator, then
the employer pays premiums to Wellmark, and Wellmark must bear the
financial risk of the resulting claims.
The record also disclosed that Wellmark, which is the BCBS
licensee in Iowa and South Dakota, has a BlueCard® program with
BCBS licensees in other states. Under this arrangement, those out-of-
state licensees have access to Wellmark’s provider network in Iowa at the
rates negotiated by Wellmark whenever they have to pay Iowa claims.
Likewise, Wellmark has access to the other licensees’ negotiated provider
networks in their respective states at their rates whenever Wellmark has
to pay claims in those states. See Steward Health Care Sys., LLC v. Blue
Cross & Blue Shield of R.I., 997 F. Supp. 2d 142, 150 n.3 (D.R.I. 2014)
6
(describing the BlueCard® program); Solomon v. Blue Cross & Blue Shield
Ass’n, 574 F. Supp. 2d 1288, 1289 (S.D. Fla. 2008) (same).
The plaintiffs maintained that Wellmark had engaged in per se
price-fixing when it entered into agreements with self-insuring Iowa
employers to make its network and claims administration available to
them. Similarly, the plaintiffs urged that Wellmark had engaged in per
se price-fixing when it participated in the national BlueCard® program
under which BCBS entities agreed to make their in-state networks
available to each other when their respective customers needed out-of-
state services.
After hearing the parties’ arguments, the district court rejected
plaintiffs’ per se theories and entered summary judgment for Wellmark.
This appeal followed.
II. Standard of Review.
This court reviews grants of summary judgment for correction of
errors at law. Mueller, 818 N.W.2d at 253. Whether the per se rule or
the rule of reason applies to a given practice is a question of law. See
California ex rel. Harris v. Safeway, Inc., 651 F.3d 1118, 1124 (9th Cir.
2011) (citing XI Phillip Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶
1909b, at 279 (2d ed. 2005)); Nat’l Bancard Corp. v. Visa U.S.A., Inc., 779
F.2d 592, 596 (11th Cir. 1986).
III. Legal Analysis.
A. The Iowa Competition Law. The general assembly has
directed that the Iowa Competition Law “shall be construed to
complement and be harmonized with the applied laws of the United
States which have the same or similar purpose.” Iowa Code § 553.2. As
the legislature has stated,
7
This construction shall not be made in such a way as to
constitute a delegation of state authority to the federal
government, but shall be made to achieve uniform
application of the state and federal laws prohibiting
restraints of economic activity and monopolistic practices.
Id.
Accordingly, in the past, when interpreting the Iowa Competition
Law, we have generally adhered to federal interpretations of federal
antitrust law. See Next Generation Realty, Inc. v. Iowa Realty Co., 686
N.W.2d 206, 208 (Iowa 2004) (per curiam); Max 100 L.C. v. Iowa Realty
Co., 621 N.W.2d 178, 181–82 (Iowa 2001); Fed. Land Bank of Omaha v.
Tiffany, 529 N.W.2d 294, 296–97 (Iowa 1995); Neyens v. Roth, 326
N.W.2d 294, 297 (Iowa 1982); State v. Cedar Rapids Bd. of Realtors, 300
N.W.2d 127, 128 (Iowa 1981). In Comes v. Microsoft Corp., we declined to
follow federal precedent on whether indirect purchasers had standing to
sue under the Iowa Competition Law. 646 N.W.2d 440, 445–49 (Iowa
2002). We did so because: (1) the language of the relevant provision
(Iowa Code section 553.12 (1997)) supported indirect purchaser
standing; (2) uniformity only requires a uniform standard of conduct
under state and federal law, not a uniform rule as to who may sue; and
(3) most federal courts allowed indirect purchasers to sue at the time the
Iowa Competition Law was enacted in 1976. See id.
This case involves section 553.4 of the Iowa Competition Law. It
provides, “A contract, combination, or conspiracy between two or more
persons shall not restrain or monopolize trade or commerce in a relevant
market.” Iowa Code § 553.4 (2007). This provision of the Iowa
Competition Law is the counterpart to section 1 of the Sherman Act,
which states, “Every contract, combination in the form of trust or
otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the
several States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal.” 15
8
U.S.C. § 1. The wording of the two provisions is notably similar. If
anything, the Iowa Competition Law tilts more in the direction of an
economics-based approach to antitrust, since it condemns only those
contracts, combinations, and conspiracies that restrain trade “in a
relevant market”—a distinctly economic concept. Iowa Code § 553.4;
see, e.g., United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 587, 86 S. Ct.
1698, 1712, 16 L. Ed. 2d 778, 795 (1966) (Fortas, J., dissenting) (noting
that “the search for ‘the relevant market’ must be undertaken and
pursued with relentless clarity” and “is, in essence, an economic task put
to the uses of the law”); United States v. Phila. Nat’l Bank, 374 U.S. 321,
362, 83 S. Ct. 1715, 1741, 10 L. Ed. 2d 915, 944 (1963) (noting that a
prediction of anticompetitive effects “is sound only if it is based upon a
firm understanding of the structure of the relevant market [and that] the
relevant economic data are both complex and elusive”).
B. The Per Se Rule vs. the Rule of Reason. Under the federal
antitrust laws, challenged agreements or conspiracies are presumptively
analyzed through the “rule of reason.” Texaco Inc. v. Dagher, 547 U.S. 1,
5, 126 S. Ct. 1276, 1279, 164 L. Ed. 2d 1, 7 (2006). This requires
plaintiffs to demonstrate that a particular arrangement “is in fact
unreasonable and anticompetitive before it will be found unlawful.” Id.
“Per se liability is reserved for only those agreements that are so plainly
anticompetitive that no elaborate study of the industry is needed to
establish their illegality.” Id. (internal quotation marks omitted). “Some
types of restraints . . . have such predictable and pernicious
anticompetitive effect, and such limited potential for procompetitive
benefit, that they are deemed unlawful per se.” State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522
U.S. 3, 10, 118 S. Ct. 275, 279, 139 L. Ed. 2d 199, 206 (1997).
9
In applying the rule of reason, “the factfinder weighs all of the
circumstances of a case in deciding whether a restrictive practice should
be prohibited as imposing an unreasonable restraint on competition.”
Bus. Elecs. Corp. v. Sharp Elecs. Corp., 485 U.S. 717, 723, 108 S. Ct.
1515, 1519, 99 L. Ed. 2d 808, 816 (1988) (internal quotation marks
omitted). By contrast, when a practice falls under the per se rule, there
is no need for “case-by-case evaluation.” Id. “The per se rule, treating
categories of restraints as necessarily illegal, eliminates the need to study
the reasonableness of an individual restraint in light of the real market
forces at work . . . .” Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc.,
551 U.S. 877, 886, 127 S. Ct. 2705, 2713, 168 L. Ed. 2d 623, 634
(2007).
Thus, “ ‘[i]t is only after considerable experience with certain
business relationships that courts classify them as per se violations
. . . .’ ” Broad. Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broad. Sys., Inc., 441 U.S. 1, 9, 99
S. Ct. 1551, 1557, 60 L. Ed. 2d 1, 10 (1979) [hereinafter BMI] (alteration
in original) (quoting United States v. Topco Assocs., Inc., 405 U.S. 596,
607–08, 92 S. Ct. 1126, 1133, 31 L. Ed. 2d 515, 525 (1972)). Price-fixing
agreements between competitors have been viewed as per se violations.
Texaco, 547 U.S. at 5, 126 S. Ct. at 1279, 164 L. Ed. 2d at 7.
But not all agreements on price are governed by the per se rule.
When Texaco and Shell formed a joint venture known as “Equilon” to
collaborate in the refining and marketing of gasoline in the western
United States, the fact that the resulting gas was sold under the Texaco
and Shell names at a single price did not amount to per se illegal price
fixing. See id. at 5–8, 126 S. Ct. at 1279–81, 164 L. Ed. 2d at 7–9. As
the United States Supreme Court explained,
10
Texaco and Shell Oil did not compete with one another in the
relevant market—namely, the sale of gasoline to service
stations in the western United States—but instead
participated in that market jointly through their investments
in Equilon. . . . [T]hough Equilon’s pricing policy may be
price fixing in a literal sense, it is not price fixing in the
antitrust sense.
Id. at 5–6, 126 S. Ct. at 1279–80, 164 L. Ed. 2d at 7–8.
Similarly, in the BMI case, the Court held that the per se rule did
not govern agreements among copyright holders to join together and
issue blanket licenses at fixed rates. BMI, 441 U.S. at 16, 99 S. Ct. at
1560, 60 L. Ed. 2d at 14. As the Court said,
[T]his is not a question simply of determining whether two or
more potential competitors have literally “fixed” a “price.” As
generally used in the antitrust field, “price fixing” is a
shorthand way of describing certain categories of business
behavior to which the per se rule has been held applicable.
The Court of Appeals’ literal approach does not alone
establish that this particular practice is one of those types or
that it is “plainly anticompetitive” and very likely without
“redeeming virtue.” Literalness is overly simplistic and often
overbroad. When two partners set the price of their goods or
services they are literally “price fixing,” but they are not per
se in violation of the Sherman Act.
Id. at 8–9, 99 S. Ct. at 1556–57, 60 L. Ed. 2d at 9–10. The Court
emphasized that the blanket license was not a “ ‘naked restrain[t] of
trade with no purpose except stifling of competition,’ ” but instead
“accompanies the integration of sales, monitoring, and enforcement
against unauthorized copyright use.” Id. at 20, 99 S. Ct. at 1562, 60
L. Ed. 2d at 16 (alteration in original) (quoting White Motor Co. v. United
States, 372 U.S. 253, 263, 83 S. Ct. 696, 702, 9 L. Ed. 2d 738, 746
(1963)). The Court noted that the costs of individual sales transactions
would be “prohibitive” and thus some form of blanket license was a
necessity. Id. at 20–21, 99 S. Ct. at 1562–63, 60 L. Ed. 2d at 16–17.
11
C. Monopsony vs. Monopoly. As the plaintiffs point out, the
present case does not involve cooperation on sales but rather
collaboration on purchases—specifically, purchases of health care
services. Thus, the concern is about potential monopsony power, not
monopoly power. See Mueller, 818 N.W.2d at 249 n.3 (noting that the
issue in the case is Wellmark is an alleged monopsonist rather than an
alleged monopolist).
Still, monopsonistic conduct can create economic dislocation by
forcing supplier prices down below the competitive level, just as
monopolistic conduct can lead to dislocation by driving consumer prices
above a competitive level. See id. (citing Herbert Hovenkamp, Federal
Antitrust Policy: The Law of Competition and Its Practice § 1.2(b), at 14
(4th ed. 2011)). In Mandeville Island Farms, Inc. v. American Crystal
Sugar Co., the Supreme Court reversed the dismissal of a complaint
brought by sugar beet growers, alleging that three sugar refiners had
entered into an agreement to pay uniform prices for beets. 334 U.S. 219,
221, 246, 68 S. Ct. 996, 999, 1011, 92 L. Ed. 1328, 1333, 1345 (1948).
As the Court put it, this arrangement “deprived the beet growers of any
competitive opportunity for disposing of their crops by the immediate
operation of the uniform price provision.” Id. at 242, 68 S. Ct. at 1009,
92 L. Ed. at 1343; see also W. Penn Allegheny Health Sys., Inc. v. UPMC,
627 F.3d 85, 104 (3d Cir. 2010) (citing Mandeville Island Farms, 334 U.S.
219, 68 S. Ct. 996, 92 L. Ed. 1328) (noting that a conspiracy to depress
reimbursement rates to medical providers can “pose[] competitive threats
similar to those posed by conspiracies among buyers to fix prices and
other restraints that result in artificially depressed payments to
suppliers—namely, suboptimal output, reduced quality, allocative
12
inefficiencies, and (given the reductions in output) higher prices for
consumers in the long run” (citation omitted)).
D. Is This a Per Se Case? Having said this, we nevertheless
agree with the district court that Wellmark’s arrangements with self-
insured employers and out-of-state BCBS affiliates are governed by the
rule of reason, not the per se rule. We reach this conclusion for several
reasons.
To begin with, these arrangements are not naked price-fixing
arrangements but are more akin to joint ventures. The self-insureds are
not entering into bare agreements to refrain from competing on price
with Wellmark—they are buying claims-administration service from
Wellmark. Part of that service consists of Wellmark’s negotiated pricing.
As in BMI, the record indicates that it would be highly impractical for the
vast majority of participants in the alleged conspiracy (i.e., the vast
majority of the self-insured employers) to engage in the numerous
individual transactions that would be needed if they could not latch on to
Wellmark’s pricing. 1 Cf. BMI, 441 U.S. at 20–21, 99 S. Ct. at 1563, 60
L. Ed. 2d at 17.
Wellmark’s health care provider network is analogous to the
blanket license in BMI. It provides a mechanism by which an otherwise
unavailable product (self-financed health coverage) can be offered. Cf. id.
If the only lawful choice for a self-insured employer were the time-
consuming process of negotiating individual rates with health care
1The plaintiffs have included numerous pages of Wellmark reimbursement rates
in the record. For example, for chiropractic services alone, Wellmark has approximately
forty-eight different reimbursement rates in a given year, including twenty-one different
rates for examination of X-rays. It seems implausible that a typical employer would
have enough information about the value of chiropractic services to be able to negotiate
with chiropractors on appropriate pricing for all these different procedures.
13
providers, the record indicates that almost all employers would avoid
self-insuring. This would eliminate one possible way to render the health
care market more efficient and reduce the costs of health care coverage—
by allowing employers to bear the financial risk of health claims
themselves.
Insurance involves both claims-handling and risk-spreading. A
large number of Iowa employers, according to the summary judgment
record, want some of the package but not all of it. That is, they do not
wish to go into the health insurance business themselves but instead
desire to purchase typical health insurance services from an outside
entity like Wellmark. At the same time, those employers apparently have
enough financial wherewithal to assume the ultimate risk that workforce
claims will exceed workforce premiums. 2 Why should this additional
option for employers be a per se violation of the antitrust laws?
Similar efficiency-related observations can be made about
Wellmark’s reciprocal arrangements with out-of-state BCBS licensees.
Iowans insured by Wellmark occasionally need health care services
outside Iowa. Rather than attempt to negotiate its own rates in all fifty
states, Wellmark has a reciprocal arrangement with the BCBS affiliates
in those states. Under that arrangement, Wellmark can utilize the other
licensees’ negotiated rates in their respective states, and they can use
Wellmark’s negotiated rates in Iowa (and South Dakota, where Wellmark
also operates). This enables Wellmark to offer a fifty-state product that
meets the needs of its customers while saving Wellmark from the
2Or they believe they can buy a different, cheaper form of protection against that
risk, such as a stop-loss.
14
expense of having to maintain a network and rate structure in states
where it has relatively few claims. 3
In a somewhat different context, the Supreme Court has
recognized that joint buying can “achieve economies of scale . . . that
would otherwise be unavailable.” Nw. Wholesale Stationers, Inc. v. Pac.
Stationery & Printing Co., 472 U.S. 284, 286–87, 105 S. Ct. 2613, 2615,
86 L. Ed. 2d 202, 206 (1985). In Northwest Wholesale Stationers, the
Court declined to apply a per se analysis to a member’s claim that it had
been wrongfully expelled from a nonprofit wholesale purchasing
cooperative, noting that “such cooperative arrangements would seem to
be ‘designed to “increase economic efficiency and render markets more,
rather than less, competitive.” ’ ” Id. at 295, 105 S. Ct. at 2620, 86
L. Ed. 2d at 212 (quoting BMI, 441 U.S. at 20, 99 S. Ct. at 1562, 60
L. Ed. 2d at 16); see also All Care Nursing Serv., Inc. v. High Tech Staffing
Servs., Inc., 135 F.3d 740, 744, 747–49 (11th Cir. 1998) (declining to
apply a per se analysis to an arrangement whereby competing hospitals
agreed to seek bids as a group for temporary nursing services); Kartell v.
Blue Shield of Mass., Inc., 749 F.2d 922, 925 (1st Cir. 1984) (rejecting
antitrust claims and contrasting a legitimate, independent medical cost
insurer with a “ ‘sham’ organization seeking only to combine otherwise
independent buyers in order to suppress their otherwise competitive
instinct to bid up price”).
3If the plaintiffs were right, then an Iowa bank and a Florida bank could not
reach an agreement on what they would charge each other’s customers for use of their
ATMs, for example, when a customer of the Iowa bank travels to Florida or a Florida
customer travels to Iowa. See In re ATM Fee Antitrust Litig., 554 F. Supp. 2d 1003,
1007, 1017 (N.D. Cal. 2008) (finding that an agreement among banks concerning an
ATM interchange fee should be governed by the rule of reason, not the per se rule).
15
Furthermore, neither of these types of Wellmark arrangements
truly represents a horizontal agreement between competitors. Cf. Texaco,
547 U.S. at 5, 126 S. Ct. at 1279, 164 L. Ed. 2d at 7. Wellmark does not
really compete with its self-insured clients. While a self-insured might
elect not to use Wellmark’s services, plaintiffs cite no example of a self-
insured that markets those kinds of services to anyone else in competition
with Wellmark. Nor does Wellmark compete with the out-of-state BCBS
licensees. Its customers are in Iowa and South Dakota; the other
licensees are licensed to sell health insurance in other states. 4
Additionally, we agree with Wellmark that a decision of the United
States District Court for the Northern District of Illinois is helpful and on
point. See N. Jackson Pharmacy, Inc. v. Caremark Rx, Inc., 385 F. Supp.
2d 740 (N.D. Ill. 2005). In North Jackson, a retail pharmacy sued a
pharmacy benefits manager that “administer[ed] prescription drug
benefit plans on behalf of employers, health insurers and other third-
party payors of prescription drug costs (‘Plan Sponsors’).” Id. at 744. As
the court stated, “By negotiating prescription drug reimbursement rates
on behalf of the 1,200 Plan Sponsors it represents, Caremark acts on
behalf of what is essentially a cooperative purchasing group.” Id. at 746.
The pharmacy alleged a per se violation of section 1 of the Sherman Act
on the theory that the plan sponsors were engaged in a horizontal
conspiracy to fix prescription drug prices. Id. at 744–46.
The district court rejected the per se categorization. Id. at 747–51.
The arrangement in question was not a “naked restraint,” but one which
4The plaintiffs make a passing assertion that Wellmark and the other out-of-
state BCBS affiliates have entered into an illegal horizontal market division agreement
not to sell health insurance in each other’s territories. This theory is not alleged in the
petition nor supported by evidence in the record, and hence we will not consider it.
16
was “ancillary” to a broader venture with procompetitive potential. See
id. at 747–48. The court elaborated,
Any alleged agreement between Plan Sponsors to set the
price paid for prescription drugs thus cannot be viewed in a
vacuum, but must instead be looked at as a corollary of the
cooperative arrangement between Caremark and the Plan
Sponsors under which Caremark performs a variety of
functions in the administration of Plan Sponsors’ drug
benefit plans. Those functions include not only the
negotiation of reimbursement rates with retail pharmacies
but also the processing of reimbursement claims,
maintenance of patient records, design and management of
drug formularies, negotiation of manufacturer rebates and
maintenance of a mail order pharmacy. According to
Caremark, those functions contribute to increased efficiency
and a reduction in the cost of prescription drugs delivered to
Plan Subscribers.
....
As described by the [complaint] and the parties’
submissions on the current motion, the arrangement
between Plan Sponsors and Caremark clearly has efficiency-
enhancing potential. Caremark specializes in various
functions of benefit plan administration and is likely able to
achieve economies of scale in the performance of those
functions that would otherwise be unavailable to Plan
Sponsors. And the creation of retail pharmacy networks,
which necessarily involves the setting of reimbursement
rates, undoubtedly contributes to the success of that larger
endeavor.
....
. . . That is of particular relevance here, where (as
North Jackson itself alleges) PBMs [Pharmacy Benefits
Managers] such as Caremark administer the prescription
drug benefits of “approximately 210 million Americans; 70%
of the U.S. population”. Any premature ruling that one of
the primary functions performed by PBMs is per se illegal
would have particularly far-reaching consequences for the
delivery of affordable prescription drugs to a large portion of
the population, a consideration that further supports
thorough rule of reason analysis.
What has been said to this point should not be read as
expressing an ultimate view as to the lawfulness of the
alleged conspiracy between Plan Sponsors. If the required
rule of reason inquiry were to reveal that the anticompetitive
17
consequences of any such conspiracy sufficiently outweigh
its procompetitive benefits so that the restraint is ultimately
judged unreasonable under Section 1, this Court would not
hesitate to rule accordingly. But because no authority even
suggests that all cooperative purchasing agreements run
afoul of Section 1, and because the agreement at issue here
is part of a larger and potentially procompetitive enterprise,
the rule of reason must be applied to North Jackson’s Claim
I.
Id. at 748–51.
Another and related factor arises from a concern explained by
Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 749 F.2d 922, 931 (1st Cir.
1984):
[T]he subject matter of the present agreement—medical
costs—is an area of great complexity where more than solely
economic values are at stake. How to provide affordable,
high quality medical care is much debated. And, many
different solutions—ranging from stricter regulation to
greater reliance on competing service organizations—have
been proposed. This fact, too, warrants judicial hesitancy to
interfere.
The conditions that were present in North Jackson Pharmacy
prevail here as well. The arrangements here are not bare price-fixing
agreements; indeed, unlike in North Jackson Pharmacy, there is not even
an allegation that the various self-insureds have entered into agreements
with each other. Rather, the self-insured employers have entered into
significant relationships with Wellmark under which Wellmark provides
much more than a price list—i.e., a network of providers; rules for
eligibility, limitations, copays, and deductibles; and claims
administration and processing. From the employee’s standpoint,
Wellmark appears to be providing traditional health insurance. The only
difference is that the employer and not Wellmark is the ultimate financial
backstop.
18
Also, similar to the situation in North Jackson Pharmacy, the
record here indicates that there are potential efficiencies and economies
of scale when employers rely on Wellmark to perform these functions, in
which it has experience and expertise. The vast majority of employers
could not realistically perform these duties on their own. There are also
potential efficiencies and economies of scale when out-of-state insurers
collaborate with Wellmark instead of trying to set up their own network
for a relatively small number of Iowa claims.
Additionally, as in North Jackson Pharmacy, there are reasons for
“judicial hesitancy” in classifying the challenged practices as per se
violations of antitrust law. The plaintiffs themselves admit the practices
are widespread. A large percentage of Iowans are covered by self-insured
employer plans administered by Wellmark. The BlueCard® network is a
national program used by health insurers and clients across the country.
We should be reluctant to declare these arrangements flatly illegal,
without considering their relative procompetitive or anticompetitive
effects.
Plaintiffs seek to distinguish North Jackson Pharmacy on the
ground that Wellmark is not a “mere independent third-party
‘administrator’ ” but a “major competitor in the market for Iowa
healthcare provider services.” Yet we fail to see how this distinction
helps the plaintiffs’ cause. It is true that Wellmark provides a higher
level of service than a “mere administrator.” It is also true that
Wellmark’s health care provider network was set up at least in part for
its own purposes, not merely as a device to enable group purchasing of
health care services. But these factors, if anything, take the challenged
arrangements even further out of the realm of naked restraints. The self-
19
insured employers are purchasing a bundle of preexisting services from
Wellmark that most of them could not provide themselves.
Plaintiffs analogize this case to Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical
Society, but we think the analogy is imperfect. See 457 U.S. 332, 102
S. Ct. 2466, 73 L. Ed. 2d 48 (1982). That case involved naked price-
fixing: The physician members of a trade association were agreeing to
abide by fee schedules. Id. at 340–41, 102 S. Ct. at 2471, 73 L. Ed. 2d at
56. There was no joint product or service being developed or sold. See
id. at 339–40, 102 S. Ct. at 2470, 73 L. Ed. 2d at 55–56. The two
wrinkles in the case were that the agreed-upon fees were maximum
prices and the price-fixers were professionals. Id. at 348–49, 102 S. Ct.
at 2475, 73 L. Ed. 2d at 61–62. Yet the Court found that neither of these
considerations mattered and that the per se rule still applied. Id. It took
note of Arizona’s contention that so-called maximum prices can have the
effect of stabilizing and enhancing the level of actual charges. Id. at 341–
42, 102 S. Ct. at 2471–72, 73 L. Ed. 2d at 57.
This case might be comparable to Maricopa County Medical Society
if the plaintiffs were claiming that Wellmark and other Iowa health
insurers had simply agreed they would pay the same reimbursements to
health care providers, without exchanging any meaningful services.
Under Maricopa County Medical Society, it would not be a defense that
the health insurers had agreed on minimum rather than maximum
reimbursement rates. 5 457 U.S. at 348–49, 102 S. Ct. at 2475, 73
L. Ed 2d at 61–62. But that is not the situation here. We do not have a
naked price-fixing agreement among competitors.
5Note again that the ultimate concern relates to monopsony rather than
monopoly effects.
20
The plaintiffs also argue at some length that Wellmark has market
power in health insurance in Iowa. This may be true, but it is not
relevant to a per se claim. If plaintiffs’ per se argument were correct,
then it would be illegal for any insurer to make its insurance network
pricing available to a self-insured that used the insurer’s administrative
and claims services even if the insurer had only a miniscule market
share.
Additionally, the plaintiffs rely on Department of Justice and
Federal Trade Commission guidance on health care. However, we believe
the line that those agencies have drawn between per se and rule of
reason conduct is consistent with the decision in this case. Consider the
following passage from the 1996 Statements of Antitrust Enforcement
Policy in Health Care:
An agreement among purchasers that simply fixes the price
that each purchaser will pay or offer to pay for a product or
service is not a legitimate joint purchasing arrangement and
is a per se antitrust violation. Legitimate joint purchasing
arrangements provide some integration of purchasing
functions to achieve efficiencies.
U.S. Dep’t of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm’n, Statements of Antitrust
Enforcement Policy in Health Care 67 n.17 (1996), available at
http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/guidelines/0000.pdf. The challenged
arrangements here are not simply agreements among purchasers to fix a
price, which would be subject to per se treatment. To the contrary, both
the self-insureds and the out-of-state BCBS licensees are obtaining a
block of Iowa claims-related services from Wellmark. In other words,
there is “integration of purchasing [and other related] functions to
achieve efficiencies.” Id.
We are not today foreclosing a rule of reason claim against
Wellmark if it were shown that the anticompetitive consequences of its
21
practices exceeded their procompetitive benefits. 6 We simply uphold the
district court’s ruling that Wellmark’s arrangements with self-insured
employers and out-of-state BCBS licensees are not subject to the per se
rule. Because the plaintiffs by stipulation limited themselves to a per se
claim, we affirm the district court’s grant of summary judgment.
IV. Conclusion.
For the foregoing reasons, the district court’s judgment is affirmed.
AFFIRMED.
All justices concur except Hecht and Appel, JJ., who take no part.
6As the court put it in North Jackson Pharmacy,
If the required rule of reason inquiry were to reveal that the
anticompetitive consequences of any such conspiracy sufficiently
outweigh its procompetitive benefits so that the restraint is ultimately
judged unreasonable under Section 1 [of the Sherman Act], this Court
would not hesitate to rule accordingly. But because no authority even
suggests that all cooperative purchasing agreements run afoul of Section
1, and because the agreement at issue here is part of a larger and
potentially procompetitive enterprise, the rule of reason must be applied
to North Jackson’s Claim I.
385 F. Supp. 2d at 750–51.