12‐4689‐cv
Cash & Henderson Drugs v. Johnson & Johnson
1 In the
2 United States Court of Appeals
3 For the Second Circuit
4 ________
5
6 August Term, 2014
7
8 No. 12‐4689‐cv
9
10 CASH & HENDERSON DRUGS, INC., OMEGA PHARMACY, LLC, DISCOUNT DRUGS OF
11 ELLIJAY, GA, INC., KLEINʹS PHARMACY & ORTHOPEDIC APPLIANCES, INC., MONROE
12 PHARMACY, INC., TRIANGLE PHARMACY, INC., THE TROUTMAN DRUG CO., GRAVES
13 DRUG STORE EMPORIA, INC., R.H. MOORE DRUG COMPANY OF FRANKLIN, INC.,
14 PELTA DRUG, INC., ACKALʹS IBERIA PHARMACY, INC., NORTHPARK PHARMACY, LTD.,
15 MILLER DRUGS, INC., RICKMAN & HAILE, INC., COLLINWOOD DRUGS, THRIFTY DRUG
16 STORE, INC., PHARMA‐CARD, INC., CREECH DRUG CO., INC., FELDMAN, INC., FAMILY
17 PRESCRIPTION CENTER, INC., HARRAH PHARMACY, INC., DAVID W. GARBER,
18 MARJORIE H. LAMAR, LIVELY DRUG CO., INC.,
19 Plaintiffs‐Appellants,
20
21 DRUG MART PHARMACY CORP., ET AL.,
22 Plaintiffs,
23
24 v.
25
26 JOHNSON & JOHNSON, CAREMARK L.L.C., EXPRESS PHARMACY SERVICES OF PA,
27 L.L.C.,
28 Defendants‐Appellees,
29
30 AMERICAN HOME PRODUCTS CORP., ET AL.,
31 Defendants.1
32 ________
33
1
The Clerk of Court is directed to amend the caption as set forth above.
2 No. 12‐4689‐cv
1 Appeal from the United States District Court
2 for the Eastern District of New York.
3 No. 93 CV 5148 (ILG) (SMG) ― Steven M. Gold, Magistrate Judge.
4 ________
5
6 Argued: February 4, 2015
7 Decided: August 27, 2015
8 ________
9 Before: PARKER, HALL, and LOHIER, Circuit Judges.
10 ________
11
12 Plaintiffs‐appellants, a group of retail pharmacies, appeal from a judgment
13 of the United States District Court for the Eastern District of New York (Gold,
14 M.J.). The district court dismissed their claims under the Robinson‐Patman Act
15 and the Clayton Act on the grounds that they had failed to show either
16 competitive or antitrust injury. See 15 U.S.C. §§ 13(a), 13(d), 13(f), 15 and 26.
17 AFFIRMED.
18 ________
19 NICHOLAS A. GRAVANTE, JR. (Steven I. Froot, Michael I. Endler,
20 Robert C. Tietjen, Benjamin D. Battles, on the brief), Boies
21 Schiller & Flexner LLP, New York and Albany, NY; (Wyatt B.
22 Durrette, Jr., Kenneth D. McArthur on the brief),
23 DurretteCrump PLC, Richmond, VA, for Plaintiffs‐Appellants.
24 WILLIAM F. CAVANAUGH JR. (Kathleen M. Crotty, Reed C.
25 Bienvenu, on the brief), Patterson Belknap Webb & Tyler LLP,
26 New York, NY, for Defendant‐Appellee Johnson & Johnson.
27 MICHAEL SENNETT (Paul W. Render, Erin L. Shencopp, on the
28 brief), Jones Day, Chicago, IL, for Defendant‐Appellees Caremark,
29 LLC, and Express Pharmacy Services of PA, LLC.
30 John M. Faust, Law Offices of John M. Faust, Washington, DC,
31 for Amicus Curiae National Community Pharmacists Association.
3 No. 12‐4689‐cv
1 David A. Balto, Law Offices of David A. Balto, Washington,
2 DC, for Amicus Curiae Organization for Competitive Markets.
3 ________
4 BARRINGTON D. PARKER, Circuit Judge
5 Plaintiffs‐appellants, a group of twenty‐eight retail pharmacies, appeal
6 from a judgment of the United States District Court for the Eastern District of
7 New York (Gold, M.J.) dismissing their claims for money damages and injunctive
8 relief under subsections 2(a), 2(d), and 2(f) of the Robinson‐Patman Act, 15 U.S.C.
9 § 13(a), 13(d), 13(f), and Sections 4 and 16 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 15, 26.
10 Defendants‐appellees are primarily pharmaceutical manufacturers. It is
11 undisputed that, since the early 1990s, the defendants have offered lower
12 prices—typically through rebates or discounts—on brand name prescription
13 drugs to “favored purchasers.” These purchasers include entities such as staff‐
14 model health maintenance organizations (HMOs) and pharmacy benefit
15 managers. HMOs provide comprehensive, managed health care by their member
16 physicians with limited referral to outside specialists. As with traditional health
17 insurers, members make regular payments to the organization. Staff‐model
18 HMOs offer services provided by the HMO’s own staff, rather than by third‐
19 party providers that contract with the HMO. Pharmacy benefit managers manage
20 benefits for insurers and HMOs. The pharmacy benefit managers sometimes
21 engage in retail sales directly or through mail‐order pharmacies that they control.
22 The drugs in question include a wide variety of brand name medicines, such as
23 Lipitor, Celebrex, and Zoloft, used to treat high cholesterol, arthritis, and
24 depression, respectively.
25 Plaintiffs’ main contentions are that the lower prices offered by
26 manufacturers violate the Robinson‐Patman Act by harming their ability to
27 compete, and that favored purchasers violated the Act by using their drug
28 formularies to extract the lower prices.2 Plaintiffs sought to prove that the
2
A drug formulary specifies which medications are approved for reimbursement.
4 No. 12‐4689‐cv
1 discounts caused them to lose customers to the favored purchasers, and that as a
2 consequence they suffered injury under the antitrust laws. Defendants contended
3 that the plaintiffs could prove neither the competitive injury required to establish
4 a prima facie claim under the Robinson‐Patman Act, nor the antitrust injury
5 required to recover damages. Following discovery that lasted many years, the
6 defendants moved for summary judgment. The district court concluded that
7 plaintiffs could prove neither type of injury and granted defendants summary
8 judgment. See Drug Mart Pharmacy Corp. v. Am. Home Products Corp., No. 93‐CV‐
9 5148 (ILG) (SMG), 2012 WL 3544771 (E.D.N.Y. Aug. 16, 2012). This appeal
10 followed.
11 This case has a complicated history. Plaintiffs opted out of a class action
12 filed against drug manufacturers in the early 1990s that was part of a multi‐
13 district litigation consolidated in the Northern District of Illinois. The class action
14 alleged Sherman Act violations on the part of the manufacturers due to a two‐tier
15 pricing system. These claims ultimately failed. In re Brand Name Prescription
16 Drugs Antitrust Litigation, Nos. 94‐CV‐897, 94‐MDL‐997 (CPK), 1999 WL 33889
17 (N.D. Ill. Jan. 19, 1999), aff’d in part & vacated in part, 186 F.3d 781 (7th Cir. 1999).
18 The opt‐out plaintiffs’ cases were remanded. Those filed in the Eastern District of
19 New York were consolidated and assigned to Judge I. Leo Glasser. Plaintiffs
20 settled their Sherman Act claims, but litigated their Robinson‐Patman Act claims
21 before Judge Glasser and Magistrate Judge Steven M. Gold.
22 In those proceedings, certain plaintiffs and certain defendants were
23 designated to move forward with discovery, and the designated defendants
24 sought summary judgment. The district court denied summary judgment on the
25 designated plaintiffs’ Section 2(a) and 2(d) liability claims, of which competitive
26 injury was an element. Drug Mart Pharmacy Corp. v. Am. Home Products Corp., 472
27 F. Supp. 2d 385, 406, 420 (E.D.N.Y. 2007) amended by No. 93‐CV‐5148 (ILG), 2007
28 WL 4526618 (E.D.N.Y. Dec. 20, 2007). However, it granted summary judgment on
29 claims for damages and injunctive relief because the designated plaintiffs failed
30 to show that they, individually, suffered antitrust injury. Id. at 430‐32; Drug Mart
31 Pharmacy Corp. v. Am. Home Products Corp., No. 93‐CV‐5148 (ILG), 2007 WL
5 No. 12‐4689‐cv
1 4526618 (E.D.N.Y. Dec. 20, 2007). After these judgments, 3,700 non‐designated
2 plaintiff pharmacies at 3,987 locations remained.3 Drug Mart Pharmacy Corp., 2012
3 WL 3544771, at *1 n.2. Of the plaintiff locations, 3,101 concluded that they would
4 not be able to identify lost customers and filed stipulations of dismissal with
5 prejudice. Id.
6 In an attempt to cure the fatal defect in the designated plaintiffs’ case, these
7 remaining plaintiffs devised, under court supervision, a matching process under
8 which plaintiffs would attempt to identify customers they had lost to the favored
9 purchasers. Thirty plaintiffs were randomly selected to participate in the
10 matching process. After two additional plaintiffs dismissed their claims, there
11 were twenty‐eight remaining plaintiffs–who are the plaintiffs‐appellants here. Id.
12 at *4. Plaintiffs believed (and assured the court) that the matching process would
13 yield a “material number” of lost customers. Id. The process went forward
14 between March 2010 and May 2011, during which time plaintiffs obtained
15 extensive discovery from five favored purchasers: Caremark, LLC, Advance PCS,
16 Express Scripts, Medco, and Omnicare. Id. at *4‐5. This process was pivotal to the
17 resolution of the litigation because if plaintiffs could not show they lost
18 customers to the favored purchasers during the years the rebates were in place,
19 then they would be hard pressed to show competitive injury or damages.
20 The process was overseen by Magistrate Judge Gold and carefully
21 designed and supervised to produce reliable matches. The parties focused their
22 efforts on patients purchasing drugs used for chronic conditions, a population
23 likely to continue to need the same or substantially similar drugs. The twenty‐
24 eight plaintiffs identified customers they had lost from among this group. They
25 compared their databases of lost customers with the five favored purchasers’
26 customer lists over a period from 1998 to 2010. Under this system, a “matched
27 customer” was one who filled a prescription for one of the specified drugs, or a
28 common substitute, at one of the five favored purchasers’ pharmacies within six
29 months of the last time they filled that prescription at one of the twenty‐eight
3
Several of the plaintiff pharmacies had more than one location.
6 No. 12‐4689‐cv
1 plaintiff pharmacies. Drug Mart, 2012 WL 3544771, at *5. At the conclusion of the
2 matching process, the parties stipulated that it had been used to “determine the
3 universe of potential lost customers that Plaintiffs claim they lost as a result of
4 the pricing practices of Defendants.” Id. at *7.4 In contrast to what plaintiffs had
5 anticipated, the matching process showed exceedingly few lost customers.
6 Based on the results of the matching process, defendants moved for
7 summary judgment against the twenty‐eight matching process plaintiffs, which
8 the district court granted on all claims.5 Critical to this conclusion was the fact
9 that the elaborate matching process showed that the plaintiffs had lost a
10 minuscule number of customers to favored purchasers. As the district court
11 noted, only approximately three percent of potential lost customers in plaintiffs’
12 records could be identified as a customer who later filled his or her prescription
13 with a favored purchaser. Id. at *5. National Community Pharmacists Association
14 data showed that independent retail pharmacies filled between 22,000 and 28,000
15 prescriptions per year during the relevant time period. The district court
16 contrasted these figures with the matching process data that showed an average
17 of approximately eighteen lost customers and fifty‐four lost transactions per
18 pharmacy per year, a number of transactions that represented only one quarter of
19 one percent of the average number of transactions of such pharmacies during
20 that period. Id. at *6. It observed that many pharmacies lost no more than ten
21 customers per defendant during the entire twelve‐year period covered by the
22 process. Id.
23 The district court noted plaintiffs’ initial representations that they were
24 “not proposing any kind of extrapolations,” id. at *3, and that the results of the
25 matching process represented the set of lost customers plaintiffs were claiming,
4
Plaintiffs note that the stipulation also referred to “any other data Plaintiffs may seek to use” and argue
that they remain able to rely on other evidence to prove their case. Joint App’x 314. In a conference
shortly after the parties filed their stipulation, plaintiffs asked for additional discovery, which defendants
opposed, and the court invited them to submit a motion with their request. Plaintiffs never did so. Drug
Mart Pharmacy Corp., 2012 WL 3544771, at *4.
5
The parties agreed that the motion would be decided by Magistrate Judge Gold.
7 No. 12‐4689‐cv
1 id. at *4. After the matching process was complete, and the results were less
2 impressive than plaintiffs had expected, they sought to introduce additional data.
3 Drug Mart Pharmacy Corp., 2012 WL 3544771, at *5. Specifically, plaintiff Pharma‐
4 Card sought to introduce affidavits that it claimed showed additional lost
5 customers. Id. at *5‐7. The district court did not, as plaintiffs contend, ignore this
6 evidence. On the contrary, the district court determined that including this data
7 did not change its conclusion because Pharma‐Card still demonstrated that it lost
8 only about eighteen customers a year per location. Id. at *7. Without this
9 additional data, the results were even more stark. When the district court
10 examined the matching process data alone on a per‐plaintiff basis, it found that
11 no pharmacy lost more than around one percent of the total brand name
12 prescription drug transactions conducted by the average independent pharmacy
13 in a year. Id. at *6.
14 Relying on the results of this matching process, the district court
15 concluded that plaintiffs had failed to come forth with evidence of competitive
16 injury. Id. at *13‐14. Although plaintiffs complained of a dramatic drop in sales,
17 the district court concluded that their evidence suggested that only a very small
18 percentage of each plaintiff’s customers were lost to pharmacies that were
19 alleged to have benefitted from the defendant manufacturers’ discriminatory
20 pricing. Id. at *8. The district court determined that plaintiffs’ inability to show
21 more than de minimis evidence of customers lost to favored purchasers meant
22 that they failed to adduce sufficient evidence of competitive injury, a showing
23 required for liability and damages for a Robinson‐Patman Act claim. As a result,
24 the district court granted summary judgment as to plaintiffs’ Section 2(a) claims
25 for declaratory relief and for damages. Id. at *12‐15.
26 The district court also granted defendants’ motion for summary judgment
27 on plaintiffs’ claim for injunctive relief. While acknowledging that injunctive
28 relief under the Robinson‐Patman Act does not necessarily require proof of past
29 injury, the court concluded that failure to prove past injury over the significant
30 period of time at issue weighed decisively against finding the probability of
31 future injury required for an injunction. Id. at *15‐16. Finally, the district court
8 No. 12‐4689‐cv
1 held that plaintiffs’ Section 2(d) and 2(f) claims also failed because liability under
2 these sections requires establishing antitrust and competitive injury, respectively.
3 Id. at *16. This appeal followed. For the reasons below, we affirm.6
4 DISCUSSION
5 This Court reviews a district court’s disposition of a motion for summary
6 judgment de novo, treating all facts in the light most favorable to the non‐moving
7 party. Johnson v. Killian, 680 F.3d 234, 236 (2d Cir. 2012). We have noted that the
8 summary judgment phase is particularly important in antitrust matters because
9 of the high cost of antitrust litigation and its potential chilling effect on the
10 market as a whole. Capital Imaging Assocs., v. Mohawk Valley Med. Assocs., 996 F.2d
11 537, 541 (2d Cir. 1993). Additionally, the Supreme Court has cautioned against
12 extending the Robinson‐Patman Act beyond its original bounds lest our
13 interpretations “give rise to a price uniformity and rigidity in open conflict with
14 the purposes of other antitrust legislation.” Automatic Canteen Co. of Am. v. FTC,
15 346 U.S. 61, 63 (1953); see also Volvo Trucks N. Am., Inc. v. Reeder‐Simco GMC, Inc.,
16 546 U.S. 164, 181 (2006) (Robinson‐Patman Act should be read “consistently with
17 broader policies of the antitrust laws”).
18 I. Section 2(a) Claims
19 A. Competitive Injury
20 Section 2(a) of the Robinson‐Patman Act makes it unlawful “to
21 discriminate in price between different purchasers of commodities of like grade
22 and quality . . . where the effect of such discrimination may be substantially to
23 lessen competition . . . or to injure, destroy, or prevent competition with any
24 person who either grants or knowingly receives the benefit of such
25 discrimination, or with customers of either of them[.]” 15 U.S.C. § 13(a). “Price
26 discrimination” in this context means a difference in the price charged for the
27 items of like grade and quality to two different buyers. Best Brands Beverage, Inc.
6
Although the judgment below concerns only the twenty‐eight plaintiffs who appeal here, the remaining
plaintiffs have stipulated that they will be bound by this court’s determination. If the district court’s
judgment is affirmed and any further appeal fails, they will dismiss their claims with prejudice.
9 No. 12‐4689‐cv
1 v. Falstaff Brewing Corp., 842 F.2d 578, 584 (2d Cir. 1987).
2 The type of competitive injury that appellants assert is “secondary line
3 injury,” which is an injury to competition between different purchasers of the
4 same product. Volvo, 546 U.S. at 176; Blue Tree Hotels Inv. (Can.), Ltd. v. Starwood
5 Hotels & Resorts Worldwide, Inc., 369 F.3d 212, 219 (2d Cir. 2004). To establish
6 secondary line injury through price discrimination, a plaintiff must show “(1)
7 that [the] seller’s sales were made in interstate commerce; (2) that the seller
8 discriminated in price as between the two purchasers; (3) that the product or
9 commodity sold to the competing purchasers was of the same grade and quality;
10 and (4) that the price discrimination had a prohibited effect on competition.”
11 George Haug Co. v. Rolls Royce Motor Cars Inc., 148 F.3d 136, 141 (2d Cir. 1998); see
12 also Volvo, 546 U.S. at 176.
13 Since defendants freely admit that they sold the same brand name drugs
14 interstate and to different buyers at different prices, the dispositive issue is
15 whether doing so had a prohibited effect on competition. Plaintiffs attempting to
16 establish competitive injury generally have two routes available to them:
17 showing substantial discounts to a competitor over a significant period of time,
18 known as the Morton Salt inference, or proof of sales lost to favored purchasers.
19 Falls City Indus., Inc. v. Vanco Beverage, Inc., 460 U.S. 428, 435 (1983); see also FTC v.
20 Morton Salt Co., 334 U.S. 37, 50‐51 (1948) (violation inferred from substantial price
21 discrimination between competitors). See pages 12‐15, infra.
22 The Supreme Court has refined these principles over the course of several
23 decades, including most recently in Volvo Trucks North America v. Reeder‐Simco
24 GMC, Inc., 546 U.S. 164 (2006). In Volvo, the Court made clear that in a secondary‐
25 line Robinson‐Patman case the “hallmark of the requisite competitive injury” is
26 the diversion of sales from a disfavored purchaser to a favored purchaser. Id. at
27 177. The Court also made clear that any “price discrimination” must “affect
28 substantially” competition between the favored purchaser and the plaintiff. Id. at
29 180; 15 U.S.C. § 13(a) (prohibiting price discrimination where the effect “may be
30 substantially to lessen competition”). Plaintiffs argue that Volvo’s discussion of
10 No. 12‐4689‐cv
1 substantiality with respect to “price discrimination” pertains only to the alleged
2 difference in the prices charged to different purchasers. However, the Court’s
3 focus in this sentence and throughout the opinion is on the existence and degree
4 of actual competition among different purchasers. Volvo, 546 U.S. at 177, 179‐80;
5 see also id. at 186 (Stevens, J., dissenting) (identifying competition as the main
6 issue in the majority opinion). In particular, the Court inquired into the number
7 of instances in which plaintiff and a favored purchaser competed head‐to‐head,
8 and sought instances where sales had been diverted from the former to the latter.
9 Id. at 179‐80. The Court concluded that the small number of instances in which
10 the plaintiff and a favored purchaser competed directly for customers could not
11 support a finding of competitive injury. Id. at 180. It follows from Volvo that if the
12 loss attributable to impaired competition is de minimis, then the challenged
13 practice cannot be said to have had a “substantial” affect on competition.
14 Our review of the evidence before the district court convinces us that
15 plaintiffs failed to raise a question of material fact as to whether they suffered
16 competitive injury. The results of the matching process make clear that plaintiffs
17 could not generate evidence tending to show that they lost more than a de
18 minimis number of customers to the favored purchasers, indicating that
19 competition was not substantially harmed or threatened by the price difference
20 in question. Id.
21 Some plaintiffs were able to demonstrate that they occasionally lost
22 customers to some favored purchasers. However, the matching process shows
23 very few customers lost in this way, especially when the number of customers
24 lost by a plaintiff pharmacy is considered as a percentage of total lost customers
25 over the period covered by the matching process. Specifically, the evidence
26 showed that only approximately three percent of lost customers could be
27 confirmed as lost to the favored purchasers through the matching process. Drug
28 Mart, 2012 WL 3544771, at *5. The participants in the matching process lost an
29 average of approximately eighteen customers and fifty‐four transactions per
30 year. Id. at *6. This loss must be measured in the context of the tens of thousands
31 of prescriptions that an independent retail pharmacy fills every year. Id. Pharma‐
11 No. 12‐4689‐cv
1 Card, which alleges the highest absolute number of lost transactions, claims it
2 lost 2,586 customers over the relevant period—nearly half of the total customers
3 that all plaintiffs claim their data shows were lost. Id. at *7. Pharma‐Card had
4 fourteen retail locations, and so its numbers translate into a loss of an average of
5 184 customers per location over ten years—or approximately eighteen per year.
6 Id. Klein’s Pharmacy, the plaintiff with the highest number of lost transactions
7 identified by the matching process as lost to favored purchasers, lost slightly
8 more than one percent of brand name prescription drug transactions per year. Id.
9 at *6. Even assuming that plaintiffs lost the ability to fill several prescriptions for
10 each customer lost, this loss of customers is de minimis and therefore insufficient
11 to demonstrate competitive injury.
12 Our conclusion that de minimis evidence of lost sales is insufficient to
13 establish competitive injury is consistent not only with Volvo, but also with the
14 approach of other circuits. See, e.g., Volvo, 546 U.S. at 180 (diversion of sale of
15 twelve trucks found insubstantial); Boise Cascade Corp. v. FTC, 837 F.2d 1127,
16 1135‐37, 1145 (D.C. Cir. 1988) (reasons for small number of lost customers varied,
17 suggesting no competitive injury); Chrysler Credit Corp. v. J. Truett Payne Co., 670
18 F.2d 575, 580 (5th Cir. 1982) (“[A] plaintiff must demonstrate that the likely effect
19 of the alleged price discrimination was to allow a favored competitor to draw
20 significant sales or profits away from him[.]”(emphasis added)); Lupia v. Stella
21 DʹOro Biscuit Co., 586 F.2d 1163, 1171 (7th Cir. 1978) (granting summary
22 judgment on a Section 2(a) claim because the plaintiff failed to allege lost sales
23 were more than de minimis).7
24 Plaintiffs do not seriously dispute that the number of diverted sales and
25 customers was de minimis, but they contend that they are entitled to an inference
26 of competitive injury under the Morton Salt doctrine. In Morton Salt, the
27 defendant manufacturer sold several types of table salt directly to large retailers
28 as well as to wholesalers, who then resold the salt to small retailers. Morton Salt,
7
One of our sister circuits does not agree. See, e.g., Feesers, Inc. v. Michael Foods, Inc., 498 F.3d 206, 214‐16
(3d Cir. 2007) (small number of lost customers still sufficient for plaintiff’s claims to survive summary
judgment when combined with other evidence).
12 No. 12‐4689‐cv
1 334 U.S. at 40‐41. The company instituted a quantity discount program that
2 benefitted five large chains. Although theoretically the discounts were available
3 to all, they were functionally unavailable to the small retailers and wholesalers
4 because other companies and even wholesalers could not match the volume of
5 sales to the largest purchasers. Id. at 42. Under the circumstances, the Supreme
6 Court stated that evidence of individual lost sales was not necessary to show
7 competitive injury. A reasonable possibility of harm to smaller retailers, the
8 Court believed, was “obvious” and “self‐evident,” because small retailers were
9 constrained to sell the same brand of the same commodity at higher prices than
10 certain large chains. Id. at 46‐47, 50. Thirty‐five years later, the Supreme Court
11 restated this inference, affirming that a reasonable possibility of competitive
12 injury may be inferred from “a substantial price difference . . . over a significant
13 period of time.” Falls City, 460 U.S. at 437; see Volvo, 464 U.S. at 177 (“a
14 permissible inference of competitive injury may arise from evidence that a
15 favored competitor received a significant price reduction over a substantial
16 period of time”); George Haug, 148 F.3d at 142 (“Morton Salt permits an inference
17 of injury to competition from evidence of a substantial price difference over time,
18 because such a price difference may harm the competitive opportunities of
19 purchasers, and thus create a ‘reasonable possibility’ that competition itself may
20 be harmed.”). It is well established, however, that the Morton Salt inference is
21 simply an inference and may be rebutted. Specifically, the inference may be
22 rebutted by evidence that favored purchasers were diverting only a de minimis
23 number of customers.
24 Plaintiffs contend that the Morton Salt inference should be regarded as
25 irrebuttable where, as here, the preferred purchasers have received substantial
26 discounts over a considerable period and plaintiffs offer some evidence of
27 diverted sales. In support of this proposition, they rely on a dictum in Falls City
28 that “in the absence of direct evidence of displaced sales, the [Morton Salt]
29 inference may be overcome by evidence breaking the causal connection between
30 a price differential and lost sales or profits.”460 U.S. at 437. According to
31 plaintiffs, Falls City provides that where direct (even de minimis) evidence of
13 No. 12‐4689‐cv
1 displaced sales exists, the Morton Salt inference may not be rebutted even by
2 evidence breaking the causal connection between price discrimination and losses.
3 At minimum, they claim, Falls City entitles them to trial on their claims for a
4 declaratory judgment under Section 2(a).
5 This assertion rests on a misreading of Falls City. First, the conclusion that
6 de minimis losses are insufficient to establish competitive injury follows from the
7 text of the Robinson‐Patman Act itself, not from the case law. As we have seen,
8 Section 2(a) provides that price discrimination is illegal “where the effect of such
9 discrimination may be substantially to lessen competition.” 15 U.S.C. § 13(a). The
10 Act itself thus requires at least the potential for substantial harm to competition.
11 Additionally, the relevant language in Falls City simply does not stand for the
12 proposition that if the Morton Salt inference is accompanied by evidence of
13 displaced sales–regardless of the substantiality of that evidence–the inference
14 becomes irrebuttable, and competitive injury is thus conclusively proven. Under
15 plaintiffs’ theory, even a single lost sale would bolt the inference in place–an
16 outcome that cannot be squared with the Act’s substantiality requirement.
17 Moreover, we do not believe the Morton Salt inference may ever be completely
18 irrebuttable because, after all, the ultimate question is whether there has been an
19 injury to competition. Finally, Falls City does not indicate that in the absence of
20 evidence of substantial diverted sales, defendants may only rebut the Morton Salt
21 inference by breaking the causal connection between a price differential and lost
22 sales.
23 When confronted with a similar situation, the D.C. Circuit has held that “if
24 the respondent’s evidence demonstrates that there is no competitive injury (or
25 reasonable possibility of competitive injury) to begin with . . . [t]here is, under
26 those circumstances, no causal connection to break.” Boise Cascade, 837 F.2d at
27 1144. We agree with this logic. To accept plaintiffs’ minimal evidence of
28 displaced sales as creating an irrebuttable presumption of competitive injury
29 makes little sense because it introduces theoretical rigidity into an area of law
30 that aims to respond to economic reality. See id. at 1146 (“Robinson‐Patman has
31 not ushered in a bizarre rule of law that exalts theory ‘no matter what’ in the face
14 No. 12‐4689‐cv
1 of hard, cold facts.”). As the D.C. Circuit has noted, a fact intensive inquiry into
2 competition “is dictated by the statute itself, which . . . calls for an inquiry into
3 whether the effect of a price discrimination has been or ‘may be substantially to
4 lessen . . . injure, destroy or prevent competition.’” Id. at 1130 (citing 15 U.S.C. §
5 13(a)). Finally, an irrebuttable presumption would permit the protection of
6 competitors to trump consideration of competition generally, which the Supreme
7 Court has expressly counseled against, see Volvo, 546 U.S. at 181 (“we would
8 resist interpretation geared more to the protection of existing competitors than to
9 the stimulation of competition”), and may conceivably limit a court’s ability “to
10 construe the Act consistently with broader policies of the antitrust laws,” id.
11 (internal quotation omitted).
12 This is an unusual case. The plaintiffs have undertaken extensive discovery
13 in an attempt to prove that sales were diverted from themselves to favored
14 purchasers, a showing which the Supreme Court has identified as “[a] hallmark”
15 of competitive injury. That discovery has come up well short of its mark. The de
16 minimis results of the matching process show “an absence of competitive injury
17 within the meaning of the Robinson‐Patman Act,” id. at 1144, and are sufficient to
18 rebut a contrary inference created by Morton Salt.
19 Finally, plaintiffs claim that the district court relied entirely on the
20 matching process in reaching its decision, improperly excluding other evidence
21 from consideration. After the results of the matching process showed practically
22 no lost sales to favored purchasers and with summary judgment looming,
23 plaintiffs shifted gears and requested that the district court consider new
24 evidence in addition to that generated by the matching process. Drug Mart, 2012
25 WL 3544771, at *4‐5. In their summary judgment submissions, plaintiffs sought to
26 include non‐specific evidence of damages and affidavits claiming additional lost
27 customers from Pharma‐Card. Id. at *7. The district court did not mechanically
28 reject any evidence outside the matching process. It noted plaintiffs’ earlier
29 representations that they would rely on the matching process, but nonetheless
30 considered the additions that plaintiffs wanted to make, including Pharma‐
31 Card’s evidence. Id. at *3‐4, 7. The district court ultimately decided that this
15 No. 12‐4689‐cv
1 additional evidence was insufficient to create a genuine factual dispute as to
2 competitive injury or damages. Id. at *7. The Pharma‐Card evidence, for instance,
3 accounted for nearly half of the total amount of lost customers alleged by
4 plaintiffs. Id. Even with this evidence included, Pharma‐Card’s per‐store loss of
5 customers remained small. Id. The court also found that other affidavits
6 concerning lost customers were not sufficiently probative. Id. We are satisfied
7 that the district court fully considered the relevant evidence. Given that an
8 extended discovery process resulted in almost no evidence of diverted sales or
9 other indicia of potential competitive injury, summary judgment was
10 appropriate. See PepsiCo. Inc. v. Coca‐Cola Co., 315 F.3d 101, 105 (2d Cir. 2002)
11 (reaffirming that “the burden on the moving party may be discharged by
12 showing–that is pointing out to the district court–that there is an absence of
13 evidence to support the nonmoving party’s case”) (quotations omitted).
14 B. Antitrust Injury
15 In addition to declaratory relief, plaintiffs sought damages. To recover
16 damages, plaintiffs must overcome an additional hurdle: they must show injury
17 to competition, which consists of both competitive injury and antitrust injury. J.
18 Truett Payne Co. v. Chrysler Motors Corp., 451 U.S. 557, 562 (1981); Brunswick Corp.
19 v. Pueblo Bowl‐O‐Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477, 489 (1977).8 Competitive injury and
20 antitrust injury under the Clayton Act are distinct concepts. Competitive injury
21 involves injury to competition through defendant’s actions. Antitrust injury
22 involves competitive injury to the plaintiff that resulted in specific losses.
23 Brunswick Corp., 429 U.S. at 489. Proving that a plaintiff has suffered antitrust
24 injury requires “(1) an injury‐in‐fact; (2) that has been caused by the violation;
25 and (3) that is the type of injury contemplated by the statute.” Blue Tree Hotels,
26 369 F.3d at 220 (citing Brunswick Corp., 429 U.S. at 489).
27 As discussed above, plaintiffs failed to raise a genuine issue of material
28 fact as to competitive injury. It follows that they also fail to raise a question of
8
The Robinson‐Patman Act contains no damages provision, but plaintiffs have a private right of action
under the Robinson‐Patman Act through Section 4 of the Clayton Act, which provides for recovery of
treble damages. 15 U.S.C. § 15.
16 No. 12‐4689‐cv
1 material fact with respect to whether their injuries are the type of injury
2 contemplated by the Robinson‐Patman Act, as required to prove antitrust injury.
3 See Texaco, Inc. v. Hasbrouck, 496 U.S. 543, 572 (1990) (“[A] plaintiff may not
4 recover damages merely by showing a violation of the Act; rather, the plaintiff
5 must also make some showing of actual injury attributable to something the
6 antitrust laws were designed to prevent.”) (quotation marks omitted). The de
7 minimis loss of sales, as well as of customers, to the favored purchasers is a
8 powerful indication that price discrimination did not harm competition. See J.
9 Truett Payne, 451 U.S. at 561‐62; H.L. Hayden Co. of New York v. Siemens Med. Sys.,
10 Inc., 879 F.2d 1005, 1022 (2d Cir. 1989) (holding that plaintiff failed to
11 demonstrate sufficient antitrust injury because it could not connect its losses to
12 behavior violating the Robinson‐Patman Act); Interstate Cigar Co. v. Sterling Drug
13 Inc., 655 F.2d 29, 31 (2d Cir. 1981) (“[P]laintiffs failed to introduce substantial
14 evidence showing that they were actually injured” by the alleged antitrust
15 violation).
16
17 C. Injunctive Relief
18
19 Plaintiffs also challenge the district court’s determination that they are not
20 entitled to injunctive relief under Section 16 of the Clayton Act. 15 U.S.C. § 26.
21 Under that provision, injunctive relief is available to plaintiffs who “show a
22 threat of antitrust injury” that, if it occurred, would be an injury under Section 4
23 of the Clayton Act. Cargill, Inc. v. Monfort of Colorado, Inc., 479 U.S. 104, 122 (1986).
24 Although the issue was not explicitly raised in the parties’ motion papers, the
25 district court granted summary judgment for defendants on plaintiffs’ claim for
26 injunctive relief because it concluded that if “the allegedly anticompetitive
27 conduct has been ongoing for a substantial period of time,”plaintiffs’ inability to
28 show past antitrust injury creates a presumption that they cannot establish future
29 injury. Drug Mart, 2012 WL 3544771, at *15 (citing Drug Mart, 2007 WL 45266618,
30 at *13). The district court relied heavily on Judge Glasser’s earlier decision, which
31 held that injunctive relief was inappropriate because the representative plaintiffs’
32 failure to prove antitrust injury over the long period of time during which they
17 No. 12‐4689‐cv
1 allege they were damaged allowed the court to infer that they would not suffer
2 antitrust injury in the future. Drug Mart, 2007 WL 45266618, at *13.
3 Typically, the inability to prove past damages does not compel a finding
4 that the plaintiff faces no threat of antitrust injury in the future. Zenith Radio Corp.
5 v. Hazeltine Research, Inc., 395 U.S. 100, 130 (1969). However, in certain situations,
6 the lack of past injury may indicate that future injury is improbable. Here,
7 plaintiffs cannot show a reasonable probability of future injury because, although
8 they have alleged injury to competition over an extended period of time, the
9 allegations fail for lack of evidence. That failure militates strongly against
10 injunctive relief. See Van Dyk Research Corp. v. Xerox Corp., 631 F.2d 251, 255 n.2
11 (3d Cir. 1980) (“[A]lthough injunctive relief may be appropriate where damages
12 are not, in the circumstances present here, the failure to prove the fact of injury is
13 conclusive as to both forms of relief.”); Merit Motors, Inc. v. Chrysler Corp., 569
14 F.2d 666, 670 n.14 (D.C. Cir. 1977) (“[W]here the programs in question have been
15 in existence long enough for their potential effects on dealers to manifest
16 themselves, the difference in the two standards [for past and potential antitrust
17 injury] is not so consequential.”). Plaintiffs have offered no argument that future
18 conditions will change in such a way as to make the injuries they claim to have
19 suffered more pronounced than currently alleged. Thus, injunctive relief is
20 inappropriate.
21 II. Remaining Claims Under Sections 2(d) and 2(f)
22 Finally, plaintiffs appeal the grant of summary judgment on their claims
23 under Sections 2(d) and 2(f) of the Robinson‐Patman Act. Section 2(d) of the
24 Robinson‐Patman Act prohibits offering promotional allowances or services
25 “unless such payment or consideration is available on proportionally equal terms
26 to all other customers competing in the distribution of such products or
27 commodities.” 15 U.S.C. § 13(d). Although Section 2(d) does not require plaintiffs
28 to establish competitive injury, it does require them to establish antitrust injury.
29 Blue Tree Hotels, 369 F.3d at 219‐20. Section 2(f) makes favored purchasers liable
30 for “knowingly . . . . induc[ing] or receiv[ing] a discrimination in price”
18 No. 12‐4689‐cv
1 prohibited by the Act. 15 U.S.C. § 13(f). A buyer cannot be liable unless the seller
2 of the goods is liable under another section of the Act. Great Atl. & Pac. Tea Co. v.
3 FTC, 440 U.S. 69, 78‐79 (1979).
4 Although the record contains evidence that the favored purchasers
5 induced other defendants to offer them lower prices, there is insufficient
6 evidence that doing so injured plaintiffs’ ability to compete. Plaintiffs
7 acknowledge that “the analyses for antitrust and competitive injury do not differ
8 [from the Section 2(a) analysis] for these claims,” except that Section 2(d) does
9 not require proof of competitive injury. Pl. Br. at 56. Since plaintiffs failed to
10 show competitive or antitrust injury with regard to their Section 2(a) claim,
11 summary judgment is appropriate with respect to their claims under Sections
12 2(d) and 2(f) as well.
13 CONCLUSION
14 For the reasons explained above, we AFFIRM the judgment of the district
15 court.
16
17