[EDITORS' NOTE: THIS PAGE CONTAINS HEADNOTES. HEADNOTES ARE NOT AN OFFICIAL PRODUCT OF THE COURT, THEREFORE THEY ARE NOT DISPLAYED.] *Page 149 It is not necessary, for the determination of this case, to inquire whether the effect of the agreement between the parties was in fact detrimental to the town of Oswegatchie. The true inquiry is, is it the natural tendency of such an agreement to injuriously influence the public interests? The rule is, that agreements, which in their necessary operation upon the action of the parties to them, tend to restrain their natural rivalry and competition, and thus to result in the disadvantage of the public, or of third parties, are against the principles of sound public policy, and are void. (Gulick v. Bailey, 5 Halst., 87;Mills v. Mills, *Page 150 40 N.Y., 545-6.) The object of the act of 1866 is plain. It was to reduce to the tax-payers of the town of Oswegatchie the expense of the collection of taxes upon them, either directly, by securing the collection at a lower rate of compensation therefor, or indirectly, by the payment into the town treasury of a bonus in money, for the privilege of serving as collector. The object and policy of the statute was to be achieved, only by exciting the rivalry and competition of men seeking this privilege. This competition was to be excited by calling by advertisement for sealed and secret proposals. Each bidder, ignorant of what his rival was about to offer, would be under stimulus, to make a bid at the best rate to the town, which his judgment would sanction, as of profit to himself. Whatever made known to one bidder, the views and proposal of another, abated his stimulus, and tended to weaken rivalry and deaden competition. And when an agreement was made between bidders, to share in the acceptance of the offer of either, it is apparent that the competition must materially slacken. Each of these parties had intended to make a proposal on his own account, and it was after each knew of the other's intention that the agreement between them was proposed and entered into. Until it can be truthfully said, that men's actions will not be affected by a consideration of their self-interest, it cannot be maintained that the parties to this agreement were likely, after it was formed, to be as strong competitors as they were before. Such is the natural effect of agreements of this nature; and it is for this reason, and not on account of the actual results upon the public or upon third persons, of particular contracts that they are held void. It is because men with these agreements in their hands, and relying upon them for their gain, do not act toward the public and third persons as they would without them, under the stimulus of competing opposition. If Mallon had promised Atcheson a sum of money, if he would refrain from making any proposal, and Atcheson relying upon it, had made none, and then had sought to enforce the agreement, there can be no doubt that the law would have held the promise void. *Page 151 And why? Not out of any consideration for the parties to it, but because its effect was to remove Atcheson from the number of earnest bidders, and thus by lessening competition to detriment the public. And the agreement which was made, laying open to Mallon, just what was the judgment of Atcheson of a profitable bid, and removing in effect an interested rival, tended to affect Mallon's action. While Atcheson, confident that if Mallon succeeded it was also his own success, lost the impulse to a real competition with him. It seems beyond cavil that the agreement is obnoxious to the rule above stated, and such agreements courts refuse to enforce.
Perhaps there is nothing in the statute which would have prevented the parties making an avowedly joint proposal. Though the language of its second, third, and fourth sections, and the analogy of the laws for the collection of taxes, contemplate but one person as town collector. But a joint proposal, the result of honest co-operation though it might prevent the rivalry of the parties, and thus lessen competition, is not an act forbidden by public policy. Joint adventures are allowed. They are public and avowed and not secret. The risk as well as the profit, is joint and openly assumed. The public may obtain at least the benefit of the joint responsibility, and of the joint ability to do the service. The public agents know, then, all that there is in the transaction, and can more justly estimate the motives of the bidders and weigh the merits of the bid.
The order of the General Term should be affirmed, with costs to the respondent.
All the judges concurring, except PECKHAM and RAPALLO, JJ., who, not having heard the argument, did not sit.
Order affirmed and judgment final for the defendant. *Page 152