T.C. Memo. 2001-260
UNITED STATES TAX COURT
BEMIDJI DISTRIBUTING CO., INC., Petitioner v.
COMMISSIONER OF INTERNAL REVENUE, Respondent
CORTLAND F. LANGDON AND JEAN M. LANGDON, Petitioners v.
COMMISSIONER OF INTERNAL REVENUE, Respondent
Docket Nos. 7186-99, 7264-99. Filed October 1, 2001.
Garry A. Pearson and Jon J. Jensen, for petitioners.
Blaine C. Holiday, for respondent.
MEMORANDUM FINDINGS OF FACT AND OPINION
PARR, Judge: In separate notices of deficiency,1
respondent determined deficiencies in petitioners' income taxes
as follows:
1
These cases have been consolidated for purposes of trial,
briefing, and opinion.
- 2 -
Petitioner Docket No. Year Deficiency
Bemidji Distributing Co.(BDC) 7186-99 2/28/93 $408,000
Cortland F. and Jean M. 7264-99 12/31/92 9,905
Langdon (the Langdons)
The deficiencies stem from the 1992 sale of the assets of
BDC, an ongoing wholesale beer distributor, to Bravo Beverage,
Ltd. (Bravo) for $2,017,461. Bravo required that the purchase
agreement between it, BDC, and petitioner Cortland F. Langdon
(Mr. Langdon) (BDC's president and sole shareholder), allocate
$1.2 million of the purchase price to two agreements with Mr.
Langdon: $200,000 to a 2-year consulting agreement and $1
million to a 5-year covenant not to compete. Nothing was
allocated to certain intangible assets, including goodwill, going
concern value, or exclusive distribution rights with two major
brewing companies.
After concessions,2 the issues for decision are: (1)
Whether all or part of Bravo's payment to Mr. Langdon for the
covenant not to compete was a disguised payment for intangibles,
taxable to BDC, and a nondeductible dividend to Mr. Langdon; and
(2) whether a portion of BDC's payment of sales expenses was a
nondeductible constructive dividend to Mr. Langdon, paid to
obtain the covenant not to compete and the consulting agreement.
2
Respondent concedes that the parties to the sale and
exchange properly allocated $200,000 to the 2-year consulting
agreement between Bravo and Mr. Langdon.
- 3 -
All section references are to the Internal Revenue Code in
effect for the taxable years in issue, and all Rule references
are to the Tax Court Rules of Practice and Procedure.
FINDINGS OF FACT
Some of the facts have been stipulated and are so found.
The stipulated facts and the accompanying exhibits are
incorporated herein by this reference.
BDC is a Minnesota corporation, whose primary place of
business was in Bemidji, Minnesota, when it filed its petition in
these cases. When they filed their petition, the Langdons
resided in Bemidji, Minnesota.
A. BDC and the Wholesale Beer and Beverage Distribution Business
In 1933, Mr. Langdon's father founded BDC. BDC grew to be
the largest wholesale beer distributor in northern Minnesota,
enjoying an estimated 53 percent of the wholesale beer sales in
its geographic market by 1990.
Mr. Langdon became part owner of BDC in 1943 and began full-
time employment with the company in 1945. He operated the
business for 46 years until he sold it to Bravo.
Since its founding, BDC maintained its business offices and
warehouse in Bemidji, the county seat of Beltrami County. It had
customers in seven counties in northern Minnesota, including all
of Beltrami, Clearwater, and Hubbard Counties and parts of Cass,
Itasca, Koochiching, and Polk Counties. Of its 242 customers
- 4 -
that year, 130 were "on-premises" retail outlets (i.e., bars and
restaurants), and 112 were "off-premises" retail outlets. Mr.
Langdon had lived in Bemidji all his life and had made it a point
to know all the tavern and restaurant operators in town. Some
customers had been personal friends for as long as 20 years, but
there was a large turnover of others because many were tavern
owners or operators who tended to turn over their businesses.
In 1990, BDC served a geographic market with approximately
74,000 permanent residents. Of those, about 25,000 lived within
5 miles of Bemidji, the only city of significant size within a
100-mile radius. In addition, a large number of part-time summer
residents, tourists, and others visit the area each year. There
are around 100 resorts in the region around Bemidji, with large
tracts of Federal, State, and privately owned forests, as well as
lakes and rivers. Itasca State Park is 32 miles southwest of
Bemidji.
During 1990, wholesale beer distributors in that market sold
about 700,000 cases of beer. Of that, BDC sold 369,864 cases of
beer on the basis of "24/12 ounce equivalents". BDC held
exclusive distribution rights from Miller Brewing Co., Stroh's
Brewing Co., Minnesota Brewing Co., Leinenkugel Brewing Co., and
Martlet Importing Co. in all of Beltrami, Clearwater, and Hubbard
Counties and in parts of Cass, Itasca, Koochiching, and Polk
Counties. The only large breweries with which it did not have
- 5 -
distribution agreements were Anheuser Busch (Budweiser), Pabst,
and Coors.
During its tax years ended February 28, 1991, and February
29, 1992, BDC generated $197,923 and $215,236 net after-tax
income, respectively. Net income before taxes was $337,554 in
1991 and $361,362 in 1992. Simple cashflow (before depreciation,
amortization, interest, and principal payments on debt and
taxes), with certain adjustments for optional or one-time
expenses, was $366,500 for 1990 and $420,500 for 1991.3
The company had 10 employees and owned all its operating
assets, including its delivery trucks and office and warehouse
space. In each of the years 1991 and 1992, the company paid Mr.
Langdon $90,000 in wages.
B. Sale of BDC's Assets
By early 1990, Mr. Langdon began to consider the possibility
of selling BDC's business. At that time, Mr. Langdon and his
wife, respectively, were approximately 69 years old and 68 years
old. Nevertheless, he was ambivalent about selling. He and his
wife were in good health, and Mr. Langdon worked every day,
actively managing every aspect of the business. He had expanded
the business throughout the 1980's and continued to do so up
until the time of sale. For instance, in 1988 Mr. Langdon added
3
These figures are included in the accountants' statement
furnished with the offering.
- 6 -
Matilda Bay wine coolers to his list of products. In 1989, he
obtained permission to purchase the distribution rights to Coors
Beer. After negotiations with Coors, however, Mr. Langdon
withdrew because he viewed Coors' sales quotas as impossible to
achieve in his region. The minutes of the April 24, 1989, annual
directors' meeting state that "Bemidji Distributing Company will
persue [sic] other brand acquisitions."
The minutes also reflect other plans for expansion:
The President also advised that an addition to the
warehouse will be necessary in the immediate future
because of the increasing number of brands and packages
introduced by brewery suppliers, and the fact that the
storage area for company owned vehicles has been beyond
capacity for a number of years. The demand by Miller
for a 45-day inventory from spring through summer also
presents a storage space problem.
At the time of the sale, the Anheuser Busch (the largest
brewery in the nation) distributorship and Skaar Distributing
(Skaar), who sold Pabst, were BDC's competitors. The owner of
Skaar had died, and his son sent out feelers to see whether Mr.
Langdon wanted to buy it.
However, Mr. Langdon had no sons and did not want to pass on
the business to his two daughters. More importantly, he also
dreaded having to renegotiate a Teamsters' contract that was set
to expire in May 1994, because past negotiations had been bitter.
No other distributor north of the Twin Cities had a union
contract.
- 7 -
Around April 1990, Mr. Langdon contacted Pohle Partners,
Inc. (Pohle Partners), a company that specialized in appraising
and brokering the sale of wholesale beer distribution businesses
throughout the United States, to discuss a possible sale of BDC.4
In mid 1990, Mr. Langdon agreed to have Pohle Partners
appraise BDC's business and to preliminarily market it to
potential purchasers. He made it clear that he had made no firm
decision to sell, and Pohle Partners so stated in the offering
package. It was understood that BDC and Mr. Langdon would have
to approve the terms of any offer. No fee would be owed to Pohle
Partners, unless a sale was consummated and BDC and Mr. Langdon
were paid. However, if the company were sold, Pohle Partners
would receive a specified percentage of the total purchase price.
For purposes of determining this fee, the total purchase price
4
Pohle Partners was well known throughout the wholesale beer
industry and enjoyed an excellent reputation as a broker. Since
about 1978, it had brokered hundreds of sales of wholesale beer
businesses. Mr. Langdon was acquainted with Paul L. Pohle and
Robert W. Pohle, the two principals of Pohle Partners. Paul
Pohle had previously owned and operated a wholesale beer
distribution business in the Minneapolis-St. Paul area.
- 8 -
would include any amount the purchaser paid for Mr. Langdon's
covenant not to compete and/or consulting agreement.5
Pohle Partners subsequently appraised BDC at almost $2
million.
Minutes of the annual meeting of BDC's board of directors on
April 18, 1991, reflect the following:
The president [Mr. Langdon] reported that Pohle
Partners have approximately ten firms interested in
acquiring Bemidji Distributing Company. An appraisal
of the sale value of Bemidji Distributing Company has
been made by Pohle Partners and it is in the
neighborhood of two million dollars. The president
feels that an offer to prospective buyers of the amount
of the appraisal is satisfactory and has accepted the
figure.
An information package was prepared by Pohle Partners for
potential purchasers. With respect to the nature of business and
franchise and territorial protections, the package states:
This is an opportunity to acquire a prosperous
beer distribution business in a broadly based,
progressive market with the brands of the second
largest national brewer, Miller Brewing Company, which
together with products of other suppliers, provides
excellent brand diversification.
* * * * * * *
5
In its letter dated July 19, 1990, to Mr. Langdon, Pohle
Partners enclosed the following fee schedule:
Purchase Price
Over But Not Over Fee
* * * * * * *
1,000,000 2,000,000 $50,000, plus 4 percent of
excess over $1,000,000
2,000,000 3,000,000 $90,000, plus 3 percent of
excess over $2,000,000
- 9 -
Franchise and Territory Protection: BDC has agreements
with its suppliers providing certain rights to the
wholesaler in its relationship with the supplier
and granting exclusive territories which is
supported by a strong state beer franchise law.
Regarding the nature of sale, price, and terms, the package
states:
VIII.
Nature of Sale, Price and Terms
Assets Purchased from BDC and Owner, Individually
Nature of Sale
Sale of certain corporate assets which are within the
general categories set forth below and a covenant not
to compete and a consulting agreement from the owner
individually.
Price
Asset Price
Accounts Receivable $60,000 (1)
Inventories 300,000 (1)
Equipment 105,000 (2)
Warehouse and Land 300,000
Intangibles 1,200,000 (3)
Total 1,965,000
Notes: (1) These are estimates; actual amounts will
be determined at closing with inventory
priced at current laid-in-costs, i.e.,
current supplier prices and freight charges
and taxes.
(2) As these assets will likely change in
the normal course of business, the purchase
price will change accordingly.
(3) Intangibles amount to be allocated among
company intangible assets (customer lists,
franchise rights, goodwill, etc.) and
agreements with owner.
Terms--Cash
- 10 -
On June 3 and 5, 1992, BDC, Mr. Langdon, and Bravo executed
a purchase agreement to sell all BDC's assets for $2,017,461.
The purchase agreement included the separate consulting agreement
and covenant not to compete, signed by Mr. Langdon and Bravo.
The principals of Bravo were from Hobbs, New Mexico. They had
never lived in Minnesota and had no experience either in Bemidji
or as beer distributors. In negotiations with Pohle Partners
they insisted on both a consulting contract and a strong,
enforceable covenant not to compete as conditions of the sale.
The purchase agreement allocated $817,461 to BDC's tangible
operating assets and accounts receivable, $200,000 to a 2-year
consulting agreement, and $1 million to a 5-year covenant not to
compete between Mr. Langdon and Bravo. Nothing was allocated to
any of BDC's intangible assets such as goodwill, going concern
value, and exclusive distribution rights. The purchase agreement
stated:
D. Seller's Intangible Property: No additional
consideration shall be due from Buyer to Seller for
Seller's Intangible Property, such assets to be
transferred from Seller to Buyer in consideration of
the benefits to be derived by Seller under the
remaining provisions of this Agreement.
Mr. Langdon did not negotiate with Bravo over the
allocations. He knew that Bravo's offer to purchase was
contingent upon the execution of a covenant not to compete, and
accepted Bravo's proposal that full value for the intangibles be
allocated to the consulting agreement and the covenant.
- 11 -
The sale of the business under the June 3 and 5, 1992,
purchase agreement closed on or about October 30, 1992.
BDC incurred and deducted $107,815 for expenses of the sale
transaction.
C. Notices of Deficiency
In the notice of deficiency issued to BDC, respondent
determined, among other things, that BDC failed to report $1.2
million of income received from Bravo.6 Alternatively, if the
allocations should be upheld, respondent determined that the
selling expenses incurred by BDC were improperly allocated, and
these expenses attributable to the consulting agreement and
covenant (59.48 percent) are a constructive dividend to Mr.
Langdon and not deductible by BDC.
The notice of deficiency issued to the Langdons was
consistent, determining that 59.48 percent of selling expenses is
a constructive dividend to Mr. Langdon.
Shortly before the trial in the instant cases, respondent
conceded that Mr. Langdon's consulting agreement with Bravo had a
value of $200,000. At trial and on brief, respondent conceded
that the covenant had a value of $121,000.
6
The Langdons reported and paid personal income tax on the
$1.2 million, in keeping with the purchase agreement allocation.
- 12 -
OPINION
Issue 1. Fair Market Value of the Covenant Not To Compete
Entered Into by Mr. Langdon and Bravo
The amounts of any tax deficiencies of the parties herein
turn on the value of the covenant not to compete. That is so
because, as to BDC, the amount properly allocated to intangibles
(in excess of basis) is taxable as capital gain. When it is
distributed to the shareholder (Mr. Langdon), it is treated as a
nondeductible dividend and taxed again to him. See secs.
61(a)(7), 11, 301(c)(1).
On the other hand, the amount allocated to the covenant will
be taxed to the shareholder as ordinary income, but such amount
will escape tax at the corporate level. Thus, it is only taxed
once, not twice. The same applies to the consulting agreement.
In other words, the consulting agreement and covenant, even
though part of a total package, are treated as separate
agreements between the buyer and shareholder, and the selling
company is not taxed thereon.
The buyer's interests are not adverse. It can ratably
deduct the cost of the covenant not to compete over the life of
the covenant-–in this case 5 years. See sec. 1.167(a)-3, Income
Tax Regs. So once again, the more that is allocated to the
covenant, the greater the tax benefit to all parties.7
7
Bravo, the buyer, was not before the Court.
- 13 -
Allocation rules are governed by section 1060, which
generally mandates the use of the residual method of purchase
price allocation as set forth in section 338(b)(5) and the
accompanying regulations. Sec. 1.1060-1T(a)(1), Temporary Income
Tax Regs., 53 Fed. Reg. 27039 (July 18, 1988).
However, as amended by the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act
of 1990 (OBRA 1990), Pub. L. 101-508, sec. 11323(a), 104 Stat.
1388, 1388-464, section 1060(a) further provides:
If in connection with an applicable asset acquisition,
the transferee and transferor agree in writing as to
the allocation of any consideration, or as to the fair
market value of any of the assets, such agreement shall
be binding on both the transferee and transferor unless
the Secretary determines that such allocation (or fair
market value) is not appropriate.
This amendment is generally effective for acquisitions made after
October 9, 1990, and applies to these cases. OBRA 1990 sec.
11323(d), 104 Stat. 1388-465.
The legislative history concerning the above amendment to
section 1060(a), among other things, provides, in pertinent part:
The committee does not intend to restrict in any
way the ability of the IRS to challenge the taxpayers'
allocation to any asset or to challenge the taxpayers'
determination of the fair market value of any asset by
any appropriate method, particularly where there is a
lack of adverse tax interests between the parties. [H.
Rept. 101-881, at 351 (1990).]
- 14 -
As we have observed, there are no adverse tax interests between
the parties here.8 We strictly scrutinize an allocation if it
does not have adverse tax consequences for the parties; adverse
tax interests deter allocations which lack economic reality.
Wilkof v. Commissioner, 636 F.2d 1139 (6th Cir. 1981), affg. per
curiam T.C. Memo. 1978-496; see also Lorvic Holdings, Inc. v.
Commissioner, T.C. Memo. 1998-281 (and cases cited therein).
In Buffalo Tool & Die Manufacturing Co. v. Commissioner, 74
T.C. 441, 446-448 (1980), we noted that where the Commissioner
challenges a contractual allocation (as in the cases at hand),
two tests are applied by the courts. In Buffalo Tool & Die
Manufacturing Co., we stated:
[Those tests are] whether (a) the contractual
allocation has "some independent basis in fact or some
arguable relationship with business reality such that
reasonable [persons], genuinely concerned with their
economic future, might bargain for such agreement," in
which event, the allocation will generally be upheld
(Schulz v. Commissioner, 294 F.2d at 55), or (b) the
allocation by the buyer and the seller of a lump-sum
purchase price is unrealistic, which neither the
respondent nor this Court is bound to accept (Rodman v.
Commissioner, 542 F.2d 845 (2d Cir. 1976), affg. on
8
Prior to repeal of the preferential tax rate for capital
gain in the Tax Reform Act of 1986 (TRA 1986), Pub. L. 99-514,
100 Stat. 2085, the grantor of a covenant not to compete had an
incentive to minimize the amount paid for such a covenant because
payments received in exchange therefor constituted ordinary
income to the grantor, while the amount realized from the sale of
other business assets might qualify for the preferential tax rate
applied to net capital gain. See Schulz v. Commissioner, 294
F.2d 52, 55 (9th Cir. 1961), affg. 34 T.C. 235 (1960).
- 15 -
this issue a Memorandum Opinion of this Court; F. & D.
Rentals, Inc. v. Commissioner, 44 T.C. 335, 345 (1965),
affd. 365 F.2d 34 (7th Cir. 1966)).
In determining which test to apply herein, we
first look to the circumstances under which the
allocation * * * [was agreed to]. * * * [Id. at 447.]
Although respondent originally argued that neither the
consulting agreement nor the covenant had economic reality,
respondent now concedes that the consulting agreement was worth
the $200,000 alotted to it, and that the covenant has economic
reality to the extent of $121,000. Our task, then, is to
establish the value of the covenant.
Relevant Factors
Courts have spelled out the relevant circumstances that must
be considered in evaluating a covenant not to compete. These
include: (a) The seller's (i.e., covenantor's) ability to
compete; (b) the seller's intent to compete; (c) the seller's
economic resources; (d) the potential damage to the buyer posed
by the seller's competition; (e) the seller's business expertise
in the industry; (f) the seller's contacts and relationships with
customers, suppliers, and others in the business; (g) the buyer's
interest in eliminating competition; (h) the duration and
geographic scope of the covenant, and (i) the seller's intention
to remain in the same geographic area. Lorvic Holdings, Inc. v.
Commissioner, supra (and cases cited therein); see also Thompson
v. Commissioner, T.C. Memo. 1997-287.
- 16 -
Petitioners rely on these factors to sustain the allocation.
They did not offer an expert witness. Respondent did not discuss
these factors, at trial or on brief, relying instead on the
testimony of an expert witness, Nhoth Chouravong, to establish
the value. Neither party offered any evidence as to the value of
the other intangibles. We first apply the enumerated factors to
the facts of these cases and then turn to Mr. Chouravong's
report.
All the factors, with the possible exception of one, favor a
substantial allocation to the covenant.
(a) The seller's ability to compete. Mr. Langdon certainly
had the ability to compete. Neither his health nor his age was
an impediment, and he was working at full throttle, continuing to
expand the business when it was sold. Respondent argues that,
because of existing exclusive distributorships, the only avenues
open for petitioner were to start from scratch with specialty
beers. But that is not correct: Mr. Langdon could have
purchased Skaar, which was a business in place representing
Pabst, or he could have gone to work for the Budweiser
wholesaler.
(b) The seller's intent to compete. At the time of the
sale, Mr. Langdon did not intend to compete. He believed it
would be unethical to do so, especially during the 2 years of his
consulting contract. However, he could have changed his mind.
- 17 -
Moreover, the existence of a consulting contract does not negate
the need for a covenant: The purchaser could abrogate the
contract for instance, or be terminated for cause. See Peterson
Mach. Tool, Inc. v. Commissioner, 79 T.C. 72, 85 (1982) (holding
that an employment contract of a covenantor for the duration of
the covenant not to compete is entitled to some weight, but is
not determinative).
Mr. Langdon's primary reason for selling was not to retire
but to avoid negotiating with the union once again. Since no
other distributor in his region was unionized, that factor would
not have prevented him from reentering the business. Therefore,
the factor of the seller's intention to compete may slightly
favor respondent, but only slightly.
(c) The seller's economic resources. After the sale, Mr.
Langdon had ample economic resources to either start from scratch
or buy an existing business.
(d) Potential damage to the buyer. If Mr. Langdon had
competed with Bravo, he could have greatly harmed the company.
Because of his long personal friendships with customers, they
certainly would have redirected a portion of their business to
him. However, because of the limited brand names available from
Skaar or Budweiser, it is probable that BDC's customers would
have continued to purchase from Bravo as well. Mr. Langdon might
also have been able to attract some of his former employees,
- 18 -
thereby weakening Bravo. Using the record and our best judgment,
we find that Bravo would have lost about one-third of its
business (from loss of sales and efficiency due to lost
personnel) if Mr. Langdon had reentered the market.
(e) The seller's business expertise in the industry. Mr.
Langdon had 46 years of experience with every phase of the beer
distribution business and had built BDC to be the leading
distributor in the region. His expertise cannot be doubted.
(f) The seller's relationships with customers, suppliers,
and others in the business. Mr. Langdon had cultivated business
and personal relationships with his customers and suppliers over
many years. It is reasonable to assume they would have been
loyal to him.
(g) The buyer's interest in eliminating competition.
Bravo's need and desire to eliminate competition from Mr. Langdon
were clear from the beginning of negotiations. Indeed, the sale
was contingent on a strong covenant not to compete. As noted
above, there were good reasons for this. Bravo might not have
survived if Mr. Langdon had gone into competition with it.
(h) The duration and geographic scope of the covenant.
Five years was a reasonable length of time to extend the
covenant. Mr. Langdon would have been 76 years old by the time
it expired and not likely to reenter the market after a 5-year
hiatus. The geographic scope of the covenant was also
- 19 -
reasonable, being apparently limited to the places where BDC
already had customers.
(i) The seller's intention to remain in the same geographic
area. Mr. Langdon had lived in Bemidji all his life and intended
to remain there. He was still living there at time of trial.
Respondent's Expert
Respondent submitted the expert witness report and testimony
of Nhoth Chouravong to establish the value of Mr. Langdon's
covenant not to compete.
Expert testimony may help the Court understand an area
requiring specialized training, knowledge, or judgment. Snyder
v. Commissioner, 93 T.C. 529, 534 (1989). We may be selective in
deciding what part of an expert's testimony we accept. Helvering
v. Natl. Grocery Co., 304 U.S. 282, 295 (1938); Silverman v.
Commissioner, 538 F.2d 927, 933 (2d Cir. 1976), affg. T.C. Memo.
1974-285; Parker v. Commissioner, 86 T.C. 547, 561 (1986).
Mr. Chouravong is employed as a general and industrial
engineer with the IRS and has valued closely held businesses and
various types of tangible (real and personal) and intangible
property. He has a B.S. degree in industrial engineering and an
M.B.A. with a major in finance.
However, only 20 percent of Mr. Chouravong's actual job
duties involves doing valuations. He is not certified by any
professional organization. He has never valued a beer
- 20 -
distributorship, although he has valued three covenants not to
compete in other businesses over the past 5 years. He did not
interview Mr. Langdon nor anyone associated with the business.
Mr. Chouravong opined that the fair market value of the
covenant was $121,000, based upon a number of assumptions of
dubious validity. He assumed, for instance, a growth in the
business of 2.7 percent per year, "based on the average growth
rate from 1988 through 1991". We cannot verify this figure since
he does not identify the source of this information and no
documents demonstrating this were attached to the report or are
otherwise in the record. We do know, however, that for the 2
most recent (and relevant) fiscal years, those ending February
28, 1991, and February 29, 1992, the rate of growth was 9.19
percent (from $197,923 to $215,236).
Mr. Chouvarong then piled discounts upon discounts.
Beginning with a potential net income of $217,700, he seems to
have assumed a potential 50 percent loss of business if Mr.
Langdon were to compete. He then halved this on the ground that
Mr. Langdon would need 6 months of startup time, an assumption
that would not apply under either of the most likely scenarios,
buying an existing distributorship or going to work for one.
Further, Mr. Chouravong assumed only a 45 percent likelihood
that Mr. Langdon would actually compete in the first year (with
decreasing percentages in subsequent years). On the other hand,
- 21 -
if Mr. Langdon had begun to compete in year one, it seems to us
equally reasonable to increase the amount of loss that Bravo
would have experienced in the out years. See Buckley v.
Commissioner, T.C. Memo. 1994-470. Mr. Chouravong's assumption
that Mr. Langdon would not compete was based upon four additional
assumptions. Two are not supported at all by the record, and the
others are on shaky ground: (1) That Mr. Langdon would not
compete because he wanted to be free of the union; however, none
of the other distributorships were unionized, so this was clearly
not a deterrent. (2) That Mr. Langdon would have to work with
only microbreweries, which was not true. (3) That the consulting
agreement would be a deterrent. We agree that it would have some
effect but, for reasons stated above, it is not determinative.
(4) That Mr. Langdon’s age, time in business, and personal
reasons would deter him. Although one might suppose that a 71-
year-old person would want to retire, Mr. Langdon did not cite
that as a consideration in his testimony, which we found to be
credible. It is equally reasonable to believe that Mr. Langdon's
lengthy time in business might cause him to want to continue,
since he was obviously continuing to build and enjoy the business
at time of sale.
The "other personal reasons" presumably refers to the lack
of a male heir. Mr. Langdon did not name that as a reason, and,
in any event, it would not deter him from going to work for
- 22 -
another distributor or from taking over a business that his
daughters could sell at his death. In short, we are persuaded
that the likelihood (and certainly the ability) of Mr. Langdon's
reentering the business should not be discounted.
Mr. Chouravong also applied an additional 24.2-percent
discount on the basis of various cumulative "risk" factors. We
cannot discern a risk factor in a covenant not to compete, other
than that the covenant will be violated. However, the covenant
provided for remedies in the case of breach, including injunctive
relief and money damages. The entire value of the covenant was
paid "up front". A covenant is not like an investment on which a
return is earned over time. The only return bargained for is the
grantor's forbearance. If Mr. Langdon died before the 5 years
expired, he would still be unable to compete. A discount for
risk thus also seems inappropriate.
It may be that Mr. Chouravong was attempting to derive the
present value of BDC's operating profits for the life of the
covenant as an outer limit to the value of the covenant. See
Buckley v. Commissioner, supra. If so, however, he has failed to
persuade us of an appropriate discount rate, and we decline to
invent one out of whole cloth.
On the other hand, we agree with respondent that (1) the
allocation of $1 million by the purchase agreement to the
covenant was not the result of arm's-length bargaining, and (2)
- 23 -
BDC, Mr. Langdon, and Bravo, in agreeing to this allocation, did
not have competing tax interests. Mr. Langdon, through Pohle
Partners, was well aware of the potential tax advantages to both
buyer and seller of allocating the entire $1 million to the
covenant.9
We also agree that it was unreasonable to have allocated
nothing to goodwill and going-concern value, including the value
of the distributorships. In its appraisal of BDC's business,
Pohle Partners concluded that the intangible assets (its customer
lists, franchise rights, goodwill, etc.), together with the
consulting agreement and covenant, were worth a combined $1.2
million. The record reflects that the intangible assets had
substantial value.
Neither party presented evidence as to the value of the
intangibles. The fact that the goodwill, or the value of the
company, as a going concern, was not mentioned in the contract of
9
Pohle Partners provided to Mr. Langdon a 1988 article
entitled "Acquisition in Today's Beer World". In that article,
after mentioning the TRA 1986 changes discussed supra note 8, the
Pohles discuss the use of allocations to covenants not to compete
to alleviate potentially, in part, the effect of those tax law
changes, where the wholesale beer business of a closely held,
regular C corporation is being sold. The article notes that
these covenants will typically be with the individual
shareholders who own the corporation selling the business, and
further states: "In an asset sale, there is not a tax affect
within the [selling] corporation because the contracts are with
the individuals * * * Again, the purchaser is satisfied because
of the deductability [over the life of the covenant of the
payments made]".
- 24 -
purchase is not controlling. Copperhead Coal Co. v.
Commissioner, 272 F.2d 45, 48 (6th Cir. 1959), affg. T.C. Memo.
1958-9; Concord Control, Inc. v. Commissioner, 78 T.C. 742, 745
(1982).
Goodwill exists where there is an "expectancy of both
continuing excess earning capacity and also of
competitive advantage or continued patronage." Wilmot
Fleming Engineering Co. v. Commissioner, 65 T.C. 847,
861 (1967). More succinctly, it has been described as
the probability that 'old customers will resort to the
old place.' Metallics Recycling Co. v. Commissioner,
79 T.C. 730 (1982); Brooks v. Commissioner, 36 T.C.
1128, 1133 (1961); see also Miller v. Commissioner, 56
T.C. 636, 649 (1971). The indicia of goodwill are
numerous and include practically every imaginable trait
that has a positive bearing on earnings.
Solitron Devices, Inc. v. Commissioner, 80 T.C. 1, 18 (1983),
affd. without published opinion 744 F.2d 95 (11th Cir. 1984).
There frequently is an overlap between the goodwill and going-
concern value of a business. Id. at 20. Going-concern value has
been defined as "the additional element of value which attaches
to property by reason of its existence as an integral part of a
going concern", and that such value is manifested by the ability
of the acquired business to continue generating sales without
interruption during and after acquisition. Id. at 19-20; Concord
Control, Inc. v. Commissioner, supra at 746; VGS Corp. v.
Commissioner, 68 T.C. 563, 592 (1977).
In the instant cases, Bravo acquired an established and
profitable wholesale beer and beverage distribution business with
a workforce in place. The buyer had no startup expenses. In
- 25 -
addition to acquiring all the real estate and tangible personal
property that BDC used in that business, Bravo acquired BDC's
customer lists and exclusive brand and distribution rights in the
market area the business served. We find that substantial
goodwill and going-concern value was transferred by BDC.
Petitioners cite cases upholding large allocations to
covenants. These cases all predate the TRA 1986, and thus,
unlike here, involved parties with competing tax interests. See
Intl. Multifoods Corp. v. Commissioner, 108 T.C. 25, 46 (1997)
(cases upholding the contracting parties' allocation of a
specific amount to a covenant not to compete are premised upon
the assumption that the competing tax interests of the parties
will ensure that the allocation is the result of arm's-length
bargaining; where that assumption is unwarranted, there is no
reason to be bound to the allocation in the contract); Buffalo
Tool & Die Manufacturing Co. v. Commissioner, 74 T.C. at 446-448;
see also H. Rept. 101-881, at 351 (1990). The cases on which
petitioners rely are innapposite.
We reject respondent's proposed valuation of $121,000 as
unrealistically low and built upon faulty assumptions.
Petitioners, who did not offer an expert, have calculated, based
upon different discount rates and assumptions, that the covenant
is worth $2,247,992. This is totally unrealistic, inasmuch as it
exceeds the entire purchase price of the business. We therefore
- 26 -
will use our best judgment, based upon the record, sketchy as it
may be.
An allocation to a covenant not to compete lacks
economic reality where there is no showing that the
seller would experience a loss comparable to the amount
supposedly paid for the covenant such that it would
bargain for substitute compensation in that amount or
that the buyer would lose such an amount were the
seller to compete against it. [Buckley v.
Commissioner, T.C. Memo. 1994-470 (citing Forward
Communications Corp. v. United States, 221 Ct. Cl. 582,
608 F.2d 485, 493-494 (1979).]
Income projected to be earned over the next 5 years, without
discounts or increases (or taking into account optional or one-
time items), is $1,075,000 ($215,000 x 5). This is perhaps the
maximum amount Bravo could lose, if Mr. Langdon competed and
drove it completely out of business. Mr. Langdon's potential
loss of income, of course, is considerably more: $1,075,000 plus
his $90,000 salary per annum for 5 years, minus the $200,000
consulting contract, or $1,325,000, if he took all the corporate
earnings as dividends.
Both scenarios are highly unlikely. We believe that, if he
competed, Mr. Langdon would not take away more than one-third of
BDC's business, because he would be unable to sell his former
products, and BDC would retain some customers through their brand
loyalty. We are also mindful that, while Bravo might not survive
without the covenant not to compete, neither would it survive
without employees, distributors, or customers. Therefore, we
find that the covenant not to compete has a fair market value of
- 27 -
$334,000, and that the remaining $666,000 of the $1 million in
issue represents the other intangibles.
Constructive Dividend
A constructive dividend occurs where a corporation has
conferred an economic benefit on the shareholder in order to
distribute available earnings and profits without expectation of
repayment. See Truesdell v. Commissioner, 89 T.C. 1280, 1295
(1987). We hold that the additional $666,000 properly allocable
to intangibles was nondeductible capital gain income to BDC that
was then distributed to Mr. Langdon as ordinary dividend
income.10
Issue 2. Constructive Dividend Received by Mr. Langdon From BDC
for Expenses Paid To Obtain the Consulting Agreement and the
Covenant Not To Compete
BDC incurred and deducted $107,815 for expenses of the sale
of its assets. In the notices of deficiency, respondent
determined that $60,581.39 of the selling expenses was allocable
to Mr. Langdon's consulting agreement and covenant and, thus,
taxable to him as a constructive dividend, not deductible by BDC.
On brief, respondent acknowledges that BDC is entitled to deduct
those selling expenses that are not allocable to Mr. Langdon's
consulting agreement and covenant, and agrees that only the pro
rata portion of the expenses allocable to the consulting
10
Neither party argued that BDC did not have sufficient
earnings and profits for dividend treatment.
- 28 -
agreement and covenant should be treated as a constructive
dividend to Mr. Langdon.
In determining whether an expenditure by a corporation
represents a constructive dividend to the shareholder, it is also
necessary to decide whether the expenditure primarily benefited
the shareholder personally rather than furthered the interest of
the corporation. Hagaman v. Commissioner, 958 F.2d 684, 690-691
(6th Cir. 1992), affg. on this issue T.C. Memo. 1987-549; Ireland
v. United States, 621 F.2d 731, 735 (5th Cir. 1980); see also
Loftin & Woodard, Inc. v. United States, 577 F.2d 1206, 1214 (5th
Cir. 1978); Hood v. Commissioner, 115 T.C. 172, 179-180 (2000)
Where the expenses are those of the shareholder, the showing
a corporation must make to deduct those expenses is a strong one.
To avoid constructive dividend treatment, the taxpayer must show
that the corporation primarily benefited from the payment of the
shareholder's expenses. Hood v. Commissioner, supra at 181.
In the instant cases, BDC did not require Mr. Langdon to pay
his pro rata share of the transaction's selling expenses. Mr.
Langdon received $200,000 for his consulting agreement and
$334,000 for the covenant, or a total of $534,000 of the
$2,017,461 total purchase price. Petitioners have not addressed
this issue, either at trial or on brief; we thus deem the issue
waived. We hold that BDC's payment of the selling expenses
allocable to Mr. Langdon's consulting agreement and covenant
- 29 -
primarily benefited him and not BDC. Accordingly, the pro rata
share of the selling expenses attributable to Mr. Langdon and
paid by BDC is a constructive dividend taxable to him and
nondeductible by BDC.
To reflect respondent's concessions and the foregoing,
Decisions will be entered
under Rule 155.