*2 Decisions will be entered for respondent.
In 1982, tax preference items were generally subject to a minimum tax under
*2 OPINION
Hamblen, Chief Judge: Respondent determined the following deficiencies in the Federal income taxes of E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co. (Du Pont) and affiliated corporations; Conoco, Inc. (Conoco), and affiliated corporations; Remington Arms Co., Inc. (Remington); and New England Nuclear Corp. (NEN):
Taxpayer(s) | TYE | Deficiency |
Du Pont, et al. | Dec. 31, 1979 | $ 13,010,040 |
Conoco, et al. | Dec. 31, 1980 | 12,436,199 |
Remington | Jan. 31, 1980 | 78,698 |
NEN | Feb. 28, 1981 | 108,196 |
Total | 25,633,133 |
Unless otherwise indicated, section references are to the Internal Revenue Code in effect during the years in issue and 1982, and Rule references are to the Tax Court Rules of Practice and Procedure.
When these consolidated cases were submitted to the Court, an issue involving depletion as a tax preference item under section 57(a)(8) was unresolved. The parties agreed, however, to abide by the decision in a case then pending before the Supreme Court. In its eventual*4 resolution of that case, the Court held in favor of the Government.
These cases were submitted fully stipulated under Rule 122. The stipulation and attached exhibits are incorporated by this reference. When the petitions were filed, the principal place of business of Du Pont and Remington was in Wilmington, *3 Delaware, and the principal place of business of Conoco was in Houston, Texas. 2
For calendar year 1982, Du Pont filed*5 a consolidated Federal income tax return as the common parent of an affiliated group (the Du Pont group), which by then included NEN and all of petitioners. The "tentative" income tax liability of the Du Pont group, before tax credits and recapture of credits, was $ 256,844,566. Various types of credits available to the Du Pont group, including foreign, investment, jobs, and research credits, totaled $ 469,997,179. After a full offset of the tentative tax liability, excess credits of $ 213,152,613, mostly investment tax credits, remained. 3 Allocated portions of the excess credits were carried back to the taxable years in issue, a period during which the four taxpayers -- Du Pont and affiliated corporations, Conoco and affiliated corporations, Remington, and NEN -- did not join in consolidated returns with one another.
*6 Until 1987,
income of a person which either is not subject to current taxation by reason of temporary exclusion (such as stock options) or by reason of an acceleration of deductions (such as accelerated depreciation) or is sheltered from full taxation by reason of certain deductions (such as percentage depletion) or by reason of a special rate of tax (such as the rate of tax on corporate capital gains). * * *
The minimum tax during the period in issue was equal to 15 percent of the excess of tax preference items over the greater of $ 10,000 or the "regular tax deduction".
Tax preference items totaled $ 177,082,305 for the Du Pont group in 1982. Without regard to the minimum tax, had*7 *4 these items not been taken into account in the computation of taxable income, the regular tax liability before credits and recapture would have been $ 81,457,860 higher; i.e., the marginal tax rate of 46 percent from section 11(b)(5) multiplied by $ 177,082,305. Although the Du Pont group had sufficient credits to offset in full even this higher tentative tax liability, a consequence would have been $ 81,457,860 less in credits available for carryback or carryover. Hence, use of the preference items for regular tax purposes in 1982, which use did not reduce 1982 tax liability, nonetheless reduced taxable income and thereby "freed up" $ 81,457,860 of credits for carryback to the years in issue. Over $ 65 million of this freed-up amount represented regular investment tax credits, with the remainder about equally divided between energy credits and so-called TRASOP (Tax Reduction Act Stock Ownership Plan) credits.
The statutory provision most directly in issue is
This Court had occasion to consider
In
*5 In
The situation confronting us in the instant cases differs from Occidental Petroleum and First Chicago in two major respects. First, the excess credits freed up by the 1982 preferences of the Du Pont group have been applied, and thus have actually generated tax benefits, in other years. Second, we now have a regulation,
The regulation begins with a proposition uncontested by petitioners: a taxpayer is not subject to minimum tax in the current year for preferences that, because of available credits, do not have the effect of reducing current regular tax liability.
The regulation further provides, and petitioners here disagree, that any credits freed up by nonbeneficial preferences must be reduced before carryback or carryover to other taxable years.
In effect, the regulation computes and suspends the minimum tax amount that, absent
Although petitioners recognize that actual tax benefits derived from the 1982 preferences may properly entail an accompanying tax cost in the benefit years, their approach to implementing
More specifically, for each of the four corporations or affiliated groups with a determined*14 deficiency, petitioners would apply
The following table sets forth the computational details of petitioners' methodology: 6
Du Pont, et | ||||
al. | Conoco, et al. | Remington | NEN | |
Allocation of 1982 | ||||
preferences | $ 89,688,646 | $ 86,102,728 | $ 541,872 | $ 749,059 |
Plus: Preferences | ||||
arising in bene- | ||||
fit year | 9,047,472 | 86,204,455 | 18,847 | 80,750 |
Total pref- | ||||
erences applica- | ||||
ble to benefit | 98,736,118 | 172,307,183 | 560,719 | 829,809 |
year | ||||
Regular tax in | ||||
benefit year (be- | ||||
fore credit | ||||
carryback) | 274,420,715 | 181,077,896 | 2,367,401 | 4,684,213 |
Plus: TRASOP | ||||
Credit | 15,192,745 | 18,034,391 | --- | --- |
Less: Credit | ||||
carryback from | ||||
1982 | 113,146,438 | 97,151,475 | 837,139 | 2,017,561 |
Regular tax | ||||
deduction in | ||||
benefit year | 176,467,022 | 101,960,812 | 1,530,262 | 2,666,652 |
Minimum tax base | ||||
(excess of pref- | ||||
erences over | ||||
regular tax de- | ||||
duction) | --- | 70,346,371 | --- | --- |
Minimum tax at | ||||
15% | --- | 10,551,956 | --- | --- |
*8 The parties are thus approximately $ 15 million apart on the question of petitioners' tax liability for the years in issue. Respondent's approach, in
The Supreme Court has described the judicial deference to Treasury regulations as follows:
Congress has delegated to the Secretary*16 of the Treasury, not to this Court, the task "of administering the tax laws of the Nation."
A regulation generally is *17 valid if reasonable and if consistent with the plain language, origin, and purpose of the statute.
While we acknowledge the normal importance of the statutory language,
Nevertheless, and notwithstanding these previously articulated shortcomings,
The courts have recognized the importance of a preference reduction in
For more direct indications of the origin and purpose of a statute, we look to the legislative history. We discover here that the congressional committee reports relating to
Tax benefit rule. -- There are certain cases under present law in which a person derives no tax benefit from a tax preference. For example, if an individual has no adjusted gross income because of deductions for accelerated depreciation on real property (an item of tax preference under the minimum tax) and also has itemized deductions (which under these circumstances he is unable to use), the tax benefit from the accelerated depreciation deductions may be reduced or eliminated because of the unused itemized deductions. However, the individual may still be subject to the minimum tax on the accelerated depreciation. Similar problems can occur in the case of deductions for percentage depletion, the capital gains deduction, rapid amortization and intangible drilling expenses. To some extent, the Internal Revenue Service has been able to deal with this issue through regulations. To deal with this problem specifically, the amendment instructs the Secretary of the Treasury to prescribe regulations under which items of tax preference (of both individuals and corporations) are to be properly adjusted when the taxpayer*22 does not derive any tax *11 benefit from the preference. For this purpose, a tax benefit includes tax deferral even if only for one year. The committee, by adding this provision, does not intend to make any judgment about the authority of the Treasury to issue these regulations under existing law. [S. Rept. 94-938, at 113-114 (1976), 1976-3 C.B. (Vol. 3) 49, 151-152. 8]
The subsequent conference report also sheds no light on the matter. In a background discussion, the report describes the House bill as directing the Secretary "to issue regulations under which neither individuals nor corporations would be subject to the minimum tax on a tax preference if they received no tax benefit from the preference." S. Conf. Rept. 94-1236, at 425 (1976), 1976-3 C.B. (Vol. 3) 807, 829.*23 The conference agreement, according to the report, simply "includes the tax benefit rule from the House bill."
Nor do we see any inconsistency between the regulation and legislative history from 1989. The
The conferees do not intend any change in the scope of the authority provided in
Contending that the regulation is too far removed from the statutory language and congressional intent, petitioners cite
In determining whether a particular regulation carries out the congressional mandate in a proper manner, we look to see whether the regulation harmonizes with the plain language of the statute, its origin, and its purpose. A regulation may have particular force if it is a substantially contemporaneous construction of the statute by those presumed to have been aware of congressional intent. If the regulation dates from a later period, the manner in which it evolved merits inquiry. Other relevant considerations are the length of time the regulation has been in effect, the reliance placed on it, the consistency of the Commissioner's*25 interpretation, and the degree of scrutiny Congress has devoted to the regulation during subsequent re-enactments of the statute. [
According to petitioners,
We observe generally that several of the factors mentioned in
Concerning*26 the purported bad faith, the record falls well short of confirming the allegation. In any event, we fail to see how the delay in issuing regulations benefited the Government in what petitioners presume was a "protecting the revenue" mindset. In
Nonetheless, there is no question that the Commissioner, from a litigating standpoint, has taken a restrictive view of the taxpayer-favorable thrust of
We do not believe, however, that the Commissioner's litigating stance has any direct bearing on the validity of the regulation or on our standard of review. As discussed below, neither the result nor the rationale in
Petitioners rely heavily upon this Court's opinion in First Chicago as justification for their*28 recommended adjustment method. As petitioners read the opinion, we there "held that those preference items [that freed up credits] should be 'properly adjusted' under
In First Chicago, however, we did not have before us a taxpayer that had yet gained a tax benefit from the use of freed-up credits. Moreover, the taxable years in issue were only those in which the subject preferences arose. Therefore, we were not called upon to decide exactly what would happen if and when the taxpayer realized a tax benefit. The issue in the instant cases differs from that in First Chicago, just as the issue in First Chicago was "quite different" from that in *14
Admittedly, in First Chicago we assumed that if and when the taxpayer realized a tax benefit, there would*29 be a contemporaneous and at least partially offsetting tax detriment. We did not, however, specifically endorse either alternative offered by the parties here, and we do not view our analysis in First Chicago as dependent upon petitioners' approach. Both petitioners' method and the regulation exact a tax cost in the year of the tax benefit, and we see this general principle as sufficient to support the result we reached in First Chicago. Furthermore, although the Court of Appeals may have assumed something similar to petitioners' approach in addressing the Commissioner's appellate arguments, the court's affirmance of our decision was not dependent upon such an assumption. See
As a somewhat more focused argument, petitioners point to an excerpt from a committee print, which relates to the origin of
There are certain cases in which a person derives no tax benefit from an item of tax preference because, for example, the item is disallowed as a deduction under*30 other provisions of the Code or because the taxpayer has sufficient deductions relating to nonpreference items to eliminate his taxable income. 1 To some extent, the Internal Revenue Service has been able to deal with this issue through regulations. To deal with this problem specifically, the [Tax Reform] Act [of 1976] instructs the Secretary of the Treasury to prescribe regulations under which items of tax preference (of both individuals and corporations) are to be properly adjusted when the taxpayer does not derive any tax benefit from the preference. * * *
Staff of Joint Comm. on Taxation, General Explanation of the Tax Reform Act of 1976, at 106-107 (J. Comm. Print 1976), 1976-3 C.B. (Vol. 2) 1, 118-119*31 (hereinafter referred *15 to as the General Explanation). Petitioners contend that the examples in the footnote illustrate the suspension and reactivation of preference items, which is the essence of their recommended approach.
We note first that the footnote is not worded precisely enough to be illustrative, necessarily, of petitioners' method. In any event, the Internal Revenue Code expressly authorizes a type of suspension and reactivation for sections 465, 704(d), and 163(d), and petitioners have not argued that the same or similar deferral provisions are implicated here. See sec. 465(a) ("Any loss * * * not allowed under this section for the taxable year shall be treated as a deduction * * * in the first succeeding taxable year."); sec. 704(d) ("Any excess of such loss over such basis shall be allowed as a deduction at the end of the partnership year in which such excess is repaid to the partnership."); sec. 163(d)(2) ("The amount of disallowed investment interest for any taxable year shall be treated as investment interest paid or accrued in the succeeding taxable year."). In contrast to these provisions, petitioners would carry back suspended preferences only for *32 minimum tax purposes, leaving regular taxable income in the carryback year unaffected.
We did state in First Chicago, as petitioners remind us: "There is no meaningful difference in respect of the minimum tax on preferences between suspension of the effect of the preference items here [i.e., accelerated depreciation, percentage depletion, capital gains] from suspension of the items referred to as '[examples]'" in the General Explanation.
Another of petitioners' objections to
Petitioners assert that the regular tax deduction is important because it ensures that the minimum tax is imposed only when tax liability otherwise is "shockingly low", a phrase taken from
We are simply not persuaded, however, that the importance of the regular tax deduction in the minimum tax framework must extend to the year in which the taxpayer realizes the tax benefits of freed-up credits. Stated another way, although we do not question the importance of the regular tax deduction for the general purposes of
Under petitioners' reasoning, a taxpayer who benefits from freed-up credits would get the one established tax break of
As an affirmative argument in support of the regulation, respondent asserts that it is modeled after
(1) In general. -- If for any taxable year a corporation --
(A) has a net operating loss any portion of which (under section 172) remains as a net operating loss carryover to a succeeding taxable year, and
(B) has items of tax preference in excess of $ 10,000,
*36 then an amount equal to the lesser of the tax imposed by subsection (a) or 15 percent of the amount of the net operating loss carryover described in subparagraph (A) shall be treated as tax liability not imposed for the taxable year, but as imposed for the succeeding taxable year or years pursuant to paragraph (2).(2) Year of liability. -- In any taxable year in which any portion of the net operating loss carryover attributable to the excess described in paragraph (1)(B) reduces taxable income, the amount of tax liability described in paragraph (1) shall be treated as tax liability imposed in such taxable year in an amount equal to 15 percent of such reduction.
(3) Priority of application -- For purposes of paragraph (2), if any portion of the net operating loss carryover described in paragraph (1)(A) is not attributable to the excess described in paragraph (1)(B), such portion shall be considered as being applied in reducing taxable income before such other portion.
Under
Petitioners do not dispute that
While superficially appealing, petitioners' argument has a major weakness in its foundation, *39 namely, the assumption that Congress, when enacting
Nonetheless, although Congress left the door open for application of the suspended-tax approach of
In this regard, a major problem with the regulation, according to petitioners, is that it rewrites the intricate statutory regime involving credits and regular tax. Specifically, based on the incentive nature of many credits, petitioners contend that the regulation retroactively disrupts tax planning. Petitioners also emphasize that Congress has frequently amended the statutory credit provisions, sometimes with an eye toward mathematical precision, supposedly reflecting a "refined and specific" congressional intent in the credit area. As one purported example of disrupted planning and undermined congressional intent, petitioners refer to the possible effect of the regulation on the statutory special treatment for TRASOP credits. See supra note 5.
It is indeed true that the statutory credit provisions are complex, that they have been often amended, and that the regulation can affect them. We do not see these considerations, however, as fatal flaws in the regulation. First, the regulation only interacts with the statutory credit provisions when
Petitioners also challenge the motivation behind the credit-reduction mechanism of the regulation. They allege that the regulation*42 is an attempt to correct what the Treasury supposedly perceived as a congressional oversight: the failure to *20 provide a
*43 We observe, first, that the question of whether the regulation goes too far for post-1986 years is one we need not definitively resolve in the context of these pre-1986 taxable years. Even assuming that petitioners have hit upon a primary motivation behind the credit-reduction mechanism, however, we are aware of no specific congressional intent that might preclude the Treasury from using its delegated authority in a manner analogous to that used by Congress itself in the transition rule for
We hold that
Finally, in upholding the validity of the regulation, we do not mean to suggest that petitioners' alternative approach is necessarily an unreasonable means of implementing
To reflect the foregoing,
Decisions will be entered for respondent.
Footnotes
1. Cases of the following petitioners are consolidated herewith: Conoco, Inc., and Affiliated Corps., docket No. 19951-91; Remington Arms Co., Inc., docket No. 19952-91; and E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., Successor to New England Nuclear Corp., docket No. 19953-91.↩
2. The petition in docket No. 19953-91 was filed by Du Pont as successor to NEN. NEN was merged into Du Pont sometime after the year for which respondent determined the NEN deficiency.↩
3. Recapture of investment tax credits, which recapture was not subject to offset by credits, caused the actual post-credit, post-recapture tax liability of the Du Pont group for 1982 to equal $ 5,626,409.↩
4. As we use the term, preferences are "nonbeneficial" if they do not result in a reduced liability for regular tax in the year they arise.↩
5. The amount reflecting the regular tax deduction exceeds by $ 568,345 the investment tax credit recapture amount of $ 5,626,409. See supra note 3. This is because
sec. 56(c)↩ , defining the regular tax deduction, excludes from offsetting credits the TRASOP "employee plan percentage" under sec. 46(a)(2)(E), which here is $ 568,345.6. Because of minor inconsistencies in the stipulation and rounding, some of these amounts do not exactly match certain paragraphs in the stipulation.↩
7. According to petitioners,
sec. 58(h)↩ "is best read to mean that petitioners' preferences should be adjusted (by being reduced) in 1982 when they do not produce a tax benefit and adjusted (by being increased) in the carryback years when they do produce a tax benefit." Although this is a possible reading, it is certainly not apparent from the express words of the statute.8. On this subject, the report of the House Ways and Means Committee is identical in all material respects. H. Rept. 94-658, at 131-132 (1975), 1976-3 C.B. (Vol. 2) 695, 823-824.↩
1. For example, preference items giving rise to losses which are suspended under at risk provisions (sec. 465 or sec. 704(d) of the Code) are not to be considered to give rise to a tax benefit until the year in which the suspended deduction is allowed. Similarly, investment interest which is disallowed (under sec. 163(d)) is to be treated as an itemized deduction for purposes of that preference only in the year in which it is allowed (under sec. 163(d)).↩
9. We recognize that petitioners' method could, in some situations, result in imposition of a higher minimum tax in the benefit year than was initially avoided.↩
10. Congress eliminated the add-on minimum tax for individuals in 1982. Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982, Pub. L. 97-248, sec. 201, 96 Stat. 411-421. Congress repealed the remainder of the minimum tax in 1986, effective for taxable years beginning after 1986, replacing it with a comprehensive alternative minimum tax. Tax Reform Act of 1986, Pub. L. 99-514, sec. 701, 100 Stat. 2320-2345. See generally
First Chicago Corp. v. Commissioner, 88 T.C. 663">88 T.C. 663 , 668 n.5 (1987), affd.842 F.2d 180">842 F.2d 180↩ (7th Cir. 1988).11. Conoco and its affiliated corporations have a minimum tax liability for 1980, in petitioners' view, but only because of the large preference balance carried back from 1982 under petitioners' suspended-preference method.↩
12. Congress provided such a transition rule for suspended minimum tax under
sec. 56(b) by requiring pre-1987 NOL carryovers, which were usable against the new alternative minimum tax, to first be reduced by the amount of preferences that had caused the suspended minimum tax:(B) CORPORATIONS. -- If the minimum tax of a corporation was deferred under
section 56(b) of the Internal Revenue Code of 1954↩ * * * for any taxable year beginning before January 1, 1987, and the amount of such tax has not been paid for any taxable year beginning before January 1, 1987, the amount of the net operating loss carryovers of such corporation which may be carried to taxable years beginning after December 31, 1986, for purposes of the [alternative] minimum tax shall be reduced by the amount of tax preferences a tax on which was so deferred. [Tax Reform Act of 1986, Pub. L. 99-514, sec. 701(f)(2)(B), 100 Stat. 2344.]