Lumpkin, C. J., delivering the opinion.
In the discussion of this case, several obligations were stated, rather than seriously urged, to the regularity of the impressment proceeding by the able counsel for the plaintiffs in error. It is suggested that the Secretary of War has not expressed any opinion that it was necessary to take private property for public use, in Atlanta, or the region round about, as it was incumbent on him to do, by the fourth section of the Impressment Act; neither has any order to impress been issued. The section alluded to declares “That Avhenever the Secretary of War shall be of opinion that it is necessary to take private property for public use, by reason of the impracticability of procuring the same by purchase, so as to accumulate necessary supplies for the army, or the good *554of the service — in any locality — he may, by general order, through the proper subordinate authorities, cause such property to be taken, the compensation due the owner for the same to be determined and the value fixed, as provided for in the first and second sections of this Act.”
The suggestion is that the Secretary of War has only said that he recognized impressments as a legal mode of procuring and accumulating supplies, owing to the impossibility of obtaining the same by purchase, and'he simply appoints a person to impress. It is asked, can that opinion apply to a locality where the owner proposed to sell the property at the value thereof in market overt? We let this point pass, remarking that the agents of the Government act only by virtue of the authority delegated to them by law. Its provisions should be presumed. For the Secretary of War to recognize impressment as a legal mode of procuring supplies which could not be obtained by purchase, would be superogatory — Congress having passed the law for that express purpose. By the fourth section, it was contemplated that the Secretary of War should say by his order in what locality it was necessary for this power to be exercised.
Colonel Underwood has occupied some time in undertaking to define the boundary line between State sovereignty and the powers of the Government of the Confederate States — a subject exceedingly interesting, for its importance, at least, if not its novelty. He contends that the right of eminent domain is inherent in the States, and has not been parted with to the Confederate States. Concede it: what then ? To the Confederate States the power to take private property for public use has been conferred by necessary implication. See section IX., paragraph 16. Indeed, the words of the Constitution would seem to presuppose an exterior, if not anterior, right; and seeks only to limit its exercise: “Nor shall private property be taken for public use without just compensation.” This is nothing more nor less than the law of self-preservation, applied to nations. And if there ever was an occasion when it could be justified, it is now, in the death-struggle in which our people are engaged to save themselves and their *555posterity from subjugation by the abolition vandals of the North. Indeed, the learned counsel admits that the power to take private property for public use exists in the Confederate Constitution, and that Congress possesses this power, with the limitation prescribed — that is, by making just compensation; and says that this is only in affirmance of the great principles of the common law.
The important questions then in this case are, what is meant by just compensation? How and, when is it to be ascertained ? and how, when and in what paid ?
It is insisted that the mode prescribed by the impressment acts for making just compensation is unconstitutional, inasmuch as it allows the owner of property no voice in the matter.
Congress passed an impressment bill, the design of which was to protect the holder; and it provided that compensation should be determined in the case of producers by two or three impartial loyal citizens of the vicinage, and in the case of non-producers, by two commissioners in each State, one appointed by the President, the other by the Governor. Soon after the passage of the Act a case of impressment occurred in Virginia, of hay, and the appraisers it was alleged put on a most exorbitant price, acting on the erroneous impression that true and loyal citizens would invariably extort from the Government extravagant prices. Congress passed a supplemental bill, providing that in case the impressing officer did not approve the award of the appraisers he should so endorse on- the appraisement and leave the matter of price over to be settled by the State Commissioners without allowing a correlative right to the producer, and under this supplemental bill instructions were issued from the War Department at Eichmond, prohibiting impressing agents from approving any appraisement in excess of the schedule prices fixed by the Commissioners for the whole State, and thus, in fact, the principle of adjusting compensations by the arbitrament of loyal and impartial citizens of the vicinage, a most important feature of the original impressment bill, has been superceded and wholly abandoned.
*556We shall be pardoned, we hope, for intimating that this order, like that of Adjutant and Inspector General Cooper’s, under the first Conscript Act of April, 1862, declaring that persons incapable, by reason of bodily infirmity, for field duty, were nevertheless subject to be enrolled, was not warranted by the law, and that this order at least, like that was, should be promptly ignored by Congress.
Let it be borne in mind that the case before us, is not claimed to be one of immediate and pressing necessity and which admits of no delay. For such emergencies the principles here considered do not apply. It is to accummulate supplies in certain localities, looking to the future wants of the army. In all such cases it has been held, upon high authority, that private property can only be taken constitutionally in one of three ways, to-wit:
1. By the agreement of the parties, that is, by stipulation between the agents of the Government and the owner.
2. By commissioners mutually selected by the parties; and
3. By the intervention of a jury. In our humble opinion, policy, if not the Constitution, requires that our legislation upon this subject should conform to the spirit of this fundamental principle. It is the surest, if not the only way of securing in every case, that just compensation guaranteed by the Constitution. Congress is but the creature of the Constitution. It is obvious, therefore, that Congress can pass no law depriving the owner of his property, even for public use, unless adequate compensation is secured by the law.
In the case of Vanhorne’s Lessee vs Dorrance, 2 Dallas, 304, which is a leading authority upon this subject, Mr. Justice Patterson, in delivering the opinion of the Court, takes occasion to refer to the Isle of Man, the jurisdiction of which subordinate royalty was vested in private persons, which being found inconvenient for the purposes of public justice and for the revenue, on account of the commodious asylum which it afforded to debtors, outlaws and smugglers, was purchased, not seized, by the Crown. He then proceeds to comment thus upon the transaction:
“ The case of the Isle of Man was a fair and honorable *557stipulation. It partook of the spirit and essence of a contract. It was free and mutual. It was treating with the proprietors on equal terms. ' But if the business cannot be effected in this way, then the value of the land intended to be taken should be ascertained by commissioners, or persons mutually elected by the parties, or by the intervention of the judiciary, of which a jury is a component part. In the first case we approximate nearly to a contract, because the will of the party whose property is to be affected, is in some degree exercised — he has a choice, his own act co-operates with that of the Legislature. In the other case there is the intervention of a court of law, or in other words, a jury is to pass between the public and the individual, who after hearing the allegations and proofs of the parties, will, by their verdict, fix the value of the property or the sum to be paid. The interposition of a jury is in such case a constitutional guard upon property, and a necessary check to legislative authority. It is a barrier between the Legislature and the individual which ought not to be removed. As long as it is preserved, the rights of private property will be in no danger of being violated, except in cases of absolute necessity or great public utility.”
Again : “ It is contended that the Legislature must judge of the necessity of interposing their despotic authority; it is a right of necessity, upon which no other power in Government can decide; that no civil institutions are perfect, and cases will occur in which private property must yield to urgent calls of public utility or general danger. Be it so. But then it must be upon complete indemnification to the owner. But who shall judge of this indemnity ? Is it necessary that the value of the property must be judged by the board of property without the consent of the party or the interference of a jury? Alas, how necessity begets necessity. They rise upon each other and become endless. The proprietor stands afar off, a solitary and unprotected member of the community, and is stripped of his property without his consent, without a hearing, without notice, the value of the property judged, (pre-judged}) without his participation or *558the intervention of a jury. If this be the legislation of a republican government in which the preservation of property is made sacred by the Constitution, I ask wherein it differs from the mandate of an Asiatic prince. Omnipotence in legislation is despotism. According to this doctrine we are all mere tenants-at-will, holding our property at the mere pleasure of the Legislature. Precarious tenure! And yet we boast of property and its security, of laws, of Courts, of constitutions, and call ourselves free!
I should state that it is said in a note appended by the Reporter to the end of this case that a writ of error was brought on the judgment of the Circuit Court, which was said to be then pending in the Supreme Court; what became of it I know not, as I can find no further notice of it in the reported decisions of the Supreme Court. Be that*as it may, we cannot believe for a moment that the great constitutional doctrines enunciated by the Judge have ever been impaired by the adjudications of that or any other Court.
In the light of the above vital truths, we would ask, was just compensation allowed in this case? We would premise that the mode of arranging a schedule of prices, by the commissioners, for the whole State, every sixty days, may give just compensation; but if so, it is accidental. The prices will generally be too much or too little for some articles in the various districts of a large State. It has no reference to demand and supply at the time and place the article is seized, than which nothing is more fluctuating at this eventful period. The commissioners meet to-day and fix the price of good sugar in Atlanta at seventy-five cents per pound, and this is the standard of valuation for the next two months. Long prior to the expiration of that time, owing to the quantity in market and the prospects of future supply, prices have undergone a great change — either advancing or declining. How often has this fact been witnessed during the progress of the war ? On the fifty-ninth day from the time when the commissioners last met, sugar is seized at the then schedule price. The day following the commissioners convene and agree on another schedule; sugar is seized under the new schedule, and the *559very same property in quality, perhaps owned by the same individual, is valued quite differently from that taken the day before; and yet this must be taken as just compensation in both cases. This is self-evidently absurd. It cannot be so. There can be no diversity of opinion upon this subject.
It is the duty of the Government to provide some fair and proper mode to ascertain the value of property taken, and to pay for it without delay. The citizen may be compelled to submit to this encroachment upon his private rights, when the public good requires it. But whenever he is forced to make the surrender, he is entitled to the value of the property taken, and at the time it is taken — the amount to be assessed by a proper tribunal and paid in money. It is a debt against the public, who takes the property, and must be paid like all other debts. The rule we hold to be this: the fair cash value of the property taken for public use, if the owner were willing to sell and the Government desired to buy, at that time and place and in that form, would be the measure of just compensation. And let not Congress legislate upon the idea that the people' are too corrupt to be trusted. For if so, they are unworthy of the boon for which we are fighting, and our martyred heroes have sacrificed their lives in vain.
But to come more particularly to the facts of the case at bar. No schedule of price was ever fixed by the commissioners for the lot of sugar impressed by Major Gumming. It is admitted on the record that the commissioners fixed seventy-five cents per pound as the price of good sugar, and that is the only class of sugar to which any price was fixed. The sugar in controversy was not of that class, but was choice sugar, and of a higher grade, and consequently this sugar did not come within the schedule of prices fixed by the commissioners. The law requires that a schedule of prices shall be fixed by the board of commissioners, so as to afford just compensation to the owner. We repeat, no price was fixed for choice sugar, and therefore it was the right of the owner to insist on some fair mode of obtaining his constitutional compensation.
Good sugar is a class of sugar well understood by mer*560chants, and is a grade below choice sugar. The commissioners were not governed by the value of the sugar at the time it was taken, for they had fixed the price of good sugar forty days previously. The proof is, that this sugar was worth $1 10 at the time it was taken. The Circuit Court says, there is no proof that the commissioners did not take the ■ market price as the standard of value for this grade of sugar. But we think the Judge is mistaken. There is no dispute as to the quality of the sugar. The proof, and the only proof, is, that it was choice sugar of the value of $1 10 per pound, whereas the price fixed by the commissioners, and tendered by the Government agent, was seventy-five cents per pound. The commissioners could not then have taken the market price as the standard of value, especially when the Commissary, himself, has admitted on the record that this particular sugar, in comparison with good sugar at seventy-five cents, was worth eighty-five cents per pound.
We are of the opinion, then, that admitting the law to be constitutional, it appears from the record' that no schedule of prices, including this particular grade of sugar, ever was fixed by the board of commissioners, either at the time it was taken or before; that its true value never has been ascertained by any legal or constitutional tribunal; and that the same was seized by the agent of the Government against the consent of the holders, without making or tendering therefor, just compensation. And as the parties have agreed that the Circuit Judge, or this Court-in the last resort, shall prescribe some fair mode of adjusting the difficulty, we advise that the question of just compensation be refeiTed to a special jury at the next term of the Superior Court of Fulton county, unless the parties shall before that time agree upon the price to be paid for the sugar.
Let the judgment be reversed with instructions.