The plea of nil debet to an action of debt on the judgment of one of our own courts of record is had. If the defendant wished to put the judgment in issue, he should have. pleaded nul tiel record. (Wheaton v. Fellows, 23 Wend. 375.) The plaintiff is entitled to judgment on the demurrer to the first plea.
There has either been some error in copying the second plea into the demurrer hook, or else it was not drawn with very great skill. Some words are omitted which the pleader seems to have had in his mind, while others are inserted which might better have been left out.
But' there are substantial defects in the plea. It was not necessary to set out all the steps which were taken in obtaining
The plea does not directly allege that a discharge was granted by any body. But if we look at what the pleader probably intended to say, to wit, that a discharge was granted by Judge Betts, the plea will still be bad. A discharge could only be granted by the court—-not by a. judge. (§ 1, 4, 6.)
Again: The discharge as set out in the plea is restricted to debts “ proveable under the said act;” (and see § 4.) There is no averment in the plea that the debt due to the.plaintiff was proveable under the bankrupt act, and without such averment the discharge does not appear to be a bar to the action.
Finally: There is no averment that this debt was not created in consequence of the defalcation of the defendant as a public officer, or while he was acting in a fiduciary capacity. (§ 1.) The federal courts are not agreed on the question whether one who owes fiduciary debts can become a voluntary bankrupt, so as to obtain a discharge from any of his obligations; but they are agreed that fiduciary debts are not discharged by the certificate,
As it is almost a matter of course to allow such defects as have been mentioned to be cured by an amendment, it will be proper to consider the broader question made at the bar; to wit, whether the discharge, if well pleaded, would constitute a good answer to the action. And here it will only be necessary to notice two facts. The defendant is a voluntary bankrupt, or one who has been discharged on his own motion, and not at the instance of his creditors; and the debt was contracted before the bankrupt act was passed. Upon these facts two general questions' arise; first, whether the insolvent or voluntary branch of the statute is to have a retroactive effect, so as to annul existing contracts; and second, whether it was within the constitutional power of congress to pass the law.
First. A law which nullifies existing contracts, or destroys a right already vested; or which in any other way takes the property of one man without his consent, and gives it to another, is so utterly repugnant to the principles of justice, and so demoralizing in its tendency, that it would be a libel upon congress to impute the intention to pass such a law, unless we can find a justification plainly written in the statute book. It is not to be made out from equivocal expressions, nor by tracing general words into remote and unjust consequences. When there is any room for construction, the law should be taken in that sense which will best stand with honesty and fair dealing.
A distinction may be taken between that branch of the statute which is properly called a bankrupt law, and that which is in truth an insolvent law under another name. A bankrupt law proper is not made for the relief of the debtor, but rather for his punishment. It acts upon him in invitum. At an early day the bankrupt not only forfeited all his estate, but he was treated as a criminal, and might be seized and shut up in prison. And although the rigor of the law has since been very justly abated, it is still the leading feature of a proper bankrupt system that it is a remedy in the hands of the creditor for the col
But when we come to that feature in the statute which enables the debtor, without the concurrence, and against, the will of the creditor, to demand a discharge from his legal obligations, very different considerations arise. If such a law be wholly prospective in its operation, it can be subject to no great objection. The credit is then given with reference to the existing state of things. The law may be said to enter into, and form a part of the contract; and when the debtor is afterwards discharged, it is no more than the creditor could have anticipated as a possible event at the time he parted with his property. But if a law enacted after the credit was given be made to retroact so as to annul the prior obligation of the debtor, it will be nothing less than an act of arbitrary power, without the semblance of justice to support it.
If then we find in this statute expressions which look back upon the past, they should, if possible, be understood as applying only to that class of cases where the creditor, and not the debtor, is the acting party. And in other cases, general words should be understood as applying only to future obligations. In this Avay we shall promote justice, and save ourselves from the reproach of having carried the modern doctrine of repudiating debts into the national legislature.
Let us iioav see Avhat foundation there is for the argument that a voluntary bankrupt may be discharged from the debts Avhich he OAved before the statute was enacted. The first section provides, that “ all persons whatsoever, residing in any state, district or territory of the United States, owing debts
Although this statute had but a brief existence, it was professedly enacted for all time to come ; and the great, if not the only object of the legislature must have been to provide for the future. If it had been the intention of congress that present as well as future obligations should be discharged, it is bút reasonable to suppose that they would have used words so plainly manifesting that intention as not to leave it an open subject for discussion. When our own legislature, in the year 1811, were
The fourth section of the act of congress declares, that when the bankrupt has conformed to all the requisitions of the act, he shall be “ entitled to a full discharge from all his debts ;” and the same shall be deemed 41 a full and complete discharge of all debts proveable under this act.” And the fifth section provides, that44 all creditors” may come in and prove their debts, including such debts as 44 are not due and payable until a future day;” and including also 44 uncertain or contingent demands.” Now upon the principles already stated, the words 44 till debts” as here used, should be understood to mean such debts as might be coritracted after the passing of the act. The words may have a wider influence when applied to cases of involuntary bankruptcy, where the law acts on the debtor by way of giving a new remedy to the creditor. But they cannot be applied to the existing debts of the voluntary bankrupt, without violating a rule of construction which has its foundation in the immutable principles of justice.
It is a general rule that a statute shall not be so construed as to give it a restrospect beyond the time of its commencement. (2 Inst. 492; 1 Black. Comm. 45, 6; Bac. Ab. Statute (C).) This is not only the doctrine of the common law, but it is a principle of general jurisprudence. (Dwar. On Stat. 680; Dash v. Van Kleeck, 7 John. 477, per Kent, Ch. J.) And general words in a statute shall be so restricted as not to do a wrong to any one. The statute of Glocester, ch. 1, provided that the disseisee should recover damages in a writ of entry founded on
These authorities are precisely in point, and I think them sufficient to establish the position that the general words in this statute should not be so construed as to nullify contracts which had been made before the law was passed. But there are one or two other clauses which are supposed to have a bearing upon the question. Merchants, bankers, &c. who do not keep proper books of account after the passing of the act, and persons who subsequent to that time apply trust funds to their own use, cam not be discharged. (§ 4.) And the second section declares void all future payments &c. made by the debtor in contemplation of bankruptcy, and for the purpose of giving a preference among creditors; and also declares void all conveyances &c. made by the debtor in contemplation of bankruptcy, to any person not being a bona fide creditor, or a purchaser for a valuable consideration, without notice. I am unable to see that these provisions give much color for the argument that the statute must have a retroactive effect. They merely put men upon their good behavior, by telling them that if they commit certain frauds, they shall never have a discharge under the bankrupt act, and then go on to make void certain other acts tending to the injury of creditors. But another part of the second section is said to have a strong bearing in favor of the defendant. The clause is as follows: If it shall appear to the court “ that the bankrupt, his application being voluntary, has, subsequent to the first day of January last, or at any other time, in contemplation of the passage of a bankrupt law,” given a preference to one creditor over another, he shall not be discharged, “ unless the same be assented to by a majority in interest of those of his creditors who have not been so preferred.” It is undoubtedly true that this clause looks backward; but it only acts upon the debtor, and denies a discharge in all future time to one, who, in the
We have not been referred to any other provision as favoring the conclusion for which the defendant contends; and if we do not look beyond the law itself in search of the intention of its framers, I think we are bound to say that this debt has not been discharged. The history of the times has been drawn into the discussion for the purpose of proving that congress must have intended to blot out present, as well as future contracts. I know that the country abounded in debtors at the time this law was made, and that congress was strongly pressed to legislate for the past, as well as the future. But it does not follow that the law makers yielded to this influence, and consented to do a wrong to creditors. And before we are at liberty to say that congress intended to take the property of one man and give it to another, we must see that intention so plainly manifested that he who runs may read.
I am ready to admit that the question is not free from difficulty, and knowing that the commonly received opinion has been that present as well as future debts may be discharged, I cannot but entertain some doubt of the soundness of my own conclusion. But on the authority of the cases which have been mentioned, and others which might be cited to the same effect, I am of opinion that the law should not be so construed as to nullify pre-existing contracts.
tSecond. If I am mistaken in the conclusion that the act was not intended to operate upon debts which were contracted before the law was passed, it then becomes important to inquire whether congress had the constitutional power to pass that branch of the statute which provides that all persons, without regard to their
It is proper to remark at the outset, that the federal government is one of defined and limited authority. It can only exercise the powers which have been expressly delegated to it, with such as are necessary for carrying those powers fairly into effect. This great principle has not only been generally admitted, but it is now a part of the fundamental law. (l0th Amendment.) We must then look into the constitution to see whether the power to pass this law has been granted to congress. If it has not been granted, it does not exist. I am thus particular in stating the principle, for the reason that although every one is ready to admit it in words, its practical importance has not always been felt.
The only authority to legislate upon this subject is contained in the following words:—“Congress shall have power to establish uniform laws on the subject of bankruptcies throughout the United States.” The argument in support of the law is, and must be, that bankrupt and insolvent—bankruptcy and insolvency—are synonymous terms, and that when the convention spoke of “bankruptcies,” they intended to cover the whole field of insolvency, or inability to pay debts. To my mind nothing can be more clear than that this position cannot be maintained by any fair course of reasoning.
As late members of the British empire, the states and the people were well acquainted with the laws and legal institutions
Prior to the adoption of the constitution; hó such thing as a bankrupt law, eo nomine, had been enacted in this country. But in England there was a complete system of bankrupt laws, which had been in use for more than two centimes. There had also for a long period been another and an entirely distinct set of laws in that country, which related to insolvent debtors. These two sets of laws were not only distinct in their enactment, but they applied to different classes of persons, and were
The first inquiry will be Avhether congress can pass a bankrupt IaAV which shall extend to persons Avho are not engaged in any branch of trade. I think they cannot. The question is not Avhat might be accomplished by the “ omnipotence of parliament;” but what A\ras the use and meaning of theAvord bankruptcy at the time the constitution was adopted. And should Ave find that the laws and the lexicographers are at variance upon the point, Ave must, I think, take the word in its legal sense. I need not cite books to proArc that technical words must be understood according to their technical meaning. But Ave shall find nothing like a conflict of opinion between the laws and the philologists upon this question.
It has already been mentioned that the operation of the English bankrupt lows was always confined to merchants and traders, or persons Avho gained a livelihood by buying and selling. Bankers Avere included because they Avere traders in money and exchanges. The remaining, and by far the most numerous classes in the community, were never subject to the
Thus we find that the philologists and lawyers are agreed upon this point; and there is certainly no reason why they should differ, for the English word bankrupt had its origin in the incidents of trade and commerce, and has come down to us in that connection, and through the medium of the laws. It is quite clear, therefore, that whatever secondary or figurative meaning the word may have acquired, its primary, and its only legal signification, is that which confines it to traders.
Now what" can be opposed to these authorities ? Doctor Johnson defines bankruptcy thus—“ 1. The state of a man broken, or bankrupt. 2. The act of declaring one’s self bankrupt.” The adjective bankrupt he defines thus-—“ in debt beyond the power of payment;” and the verb—“to break; to disable one from satisfying his creditors.” Although he has omitted to specify a particular class of persons, he has not said that the word is applicable alike to all classes; and his want of entire accuracy cannot prove much, for he has come nearer to the point than laymen usually do when they venture upon the definition of legal terms. There are some other lexicographers of far less celebrity, who, in compiling books for the use of schools, or for
As a state of insolvency usually precedes and is attendant upon bankruptcy, it is not surprising that the two words should sometimes be confounded; and hence it is that in common parlance the word bankrupt has occasionally been applied to an insolvent farmer, physician, lawyer, mechanic, or other-person who had not been engaged in trade. But the distinction' between the two words is so strongly rooted in our language, that even among the unlearned- the word bankrupt was very rarely applied to any other class than merchants and traders, until congress attempted to ten debtors of all descriptions into bankrupts.
Insolvency is said to be the generic term, comprehending bankruptcy as a species. (2 Bell’s Com. 162; Web. Dict., Insolvent.) If this be true, it will not uphold this law, for congress has unfortunately attempted to enlarge a power which goes only to the species, so as to- include the whole genus. But the case is still worse, for although insolvency is undoubtedly the larger term, there is no necessary connection between the two things. A man may be insolvent without ever becoming a bankrupt, or. having the capacity to become such; and a bankrupt may prove to be entirely solvent. Mere insolvency never makes one a bankrupt without the concurrence of some act tending to the injury of his creditors; and when there has been such an act, the man may be declared a bankrupt, however able he may be to pay his debts.
I know that a figurative use has sometimes been made of the word bankrupt. Johnson and Richardson have collected examples from Shakspeare and other poets and writers, where a man has been said to be bankrupt in wit, intellect, or character. But I presume no one will affirm that the convention had in
I must not omit to mention the fact, because it has been supposed to be a matter of some consequence, that the statute, 34 and 35 H. 8, ch. 4, which is the first of the English bankrupt laws, was not in terms confined to merchants and traders. But it is evident from the whole scope of the act, when taken in connection with the state of trade and commerce at that period, that none but merchants were intended to be included in its provisions ; and Coke speaks of this statute as though it was only applicable to merchants. (4 Inst. 277.) Within thirty years afterwards, and when new branches of trade had been opened, the law was extended by the statute 13 Eliz. ch. 7, so as to include not only merchants, but all persons “ seeking his or her trade or living by buying and selling.” Other statutes followed, (see 1 James 1, ch. 15, and 21 James 1, ch. 19,) in which the persons who might be proceeded against as bankrupts, were still more carefully specified. There is not, I believe, so much as the shadow of an authority in the books for saying, that in point of practice the English bankrupt system was ever extended, at any period, to all classes of persons.
It is proper to mention here, that our first bankrupt law, which was passed in the year 1800, was, in all its leading features, based upon the English bankrupt system. This law was passed while most of the men who had taken part in framing and ratifying the constitution were still living. As a practical construction of the bankrupt power, no one can deny that it is a precedent of great importance. At that period no one seems to have supposed that the power of congress extended over the whole subject of insolvency; and probably few persons would ever have thought of such a thing, if we had not witnessed the sad consequences of idleness, extravagant living and gambling speculations! But none of these things can alter the constitution.
I have met with no authority for saying that- a bankrupt law may be extended to all .classes of debtors, save what may be found in one of the numerous elementary books of Hr. Justice
It has been said, that upon this construction there Avill be great difficulty in specifying the classes of persons Avho may properly be subjected to the operation of a bankrupt law; and this has been deemed an argument of some importance in sup port of the law under consideration. But there is very little of truth in Avhat is alleged as the groundwork of this reasoning ; and if the supposed difficulty really existed, the argument based upon it Avould be good for nothing. The improvements Avhich have from time to time been made in the English bankrupt laws, based upon long experience of their practical operation, must furnish the means of specifying Avith sufficient accuracy Avho may, and who may not come within the operation of the system. And I may add, that this specification was actually made in our own bankrupt law of 1800 ; and so also it Avas by the laAV of -1841, when we come to that branch of it Avhich may properly be termed a bankrupt law. But however great the supposed difficulty may be, it clearly cannot have the effect of enlarging the poAver.
The next feature which I shall notice in a proper bankrupt system is, that there must be something more than the mere non-payment of debts—some act must be done by the trader, Avhich the law has declared to be'an act of bankruptcy—before he can be brought under the operation of the system. So are the English bankrupt laws; so was the law of 1800; and so
In a proper bankrupt system, the law, like all other laws for the collection of debts, is made for the special benefit of the creditor, and can only be set in motion at his instance. So are the English bankrupt laws; .so was our own law of 1800; and so is the bankrupt branch of the law of 1841. “ One distinction has ever existed, that is, an insolvent act has ever operated at the instance of the debtor imprisoned; but bankrupt laws at the instance of the creditors.” (1 Dane Ab. 317.) No such thing was ever known prior to 1841, as that a man should declare himself a bankrupt, and demand a discharge in defiance of his creditors. It may be remarked here, that for a long time these laws afforded no relief of any kind to the bankrupt. Neither the 34th and 35th H. 8. ch. 4, nor the 13 Eliz. ch. 7, provided for the bankrupt’s discharge. The creditors seized on all his estate for the payment of their debts, and if they were not fully satisfied the bankrupt remained liable for the balance. It was not until the reign of Anne, that the bankrupt, on conforming to all that was required of him, obtained a discharge from so much of his debts as had not been-satisfied under the commission. It still remained for the creditors to adopt this remedy or not, at their pleasure. If they elected to sue out a commission, they got the effects of the bankrupt, and he was discharged. But it was never in his power to move in the matter, and say to his creditors, “ I will have a discharge whether you agree to it or not.”
There was at the same time another, and an entirely distinct system of laws in operation in England for the relief of insolvent debtors. The first of these laws was passed as early as the 22 and 23 Charles II. ch. 20, and at the time of our revolution there were not less than thirty British statutes on the subject. These laws relieved the debtor from imprisonment on surrendering his property; but left his future acquisitions still liable for the payment of debts. They answered very nearly to the cessio bonorum of the Roman law, which did not discharge the debt, but only released the debtor from confinement. We see, then, that there were two distinct and independent systems in operation touching the relation of debtor and creditor; and it will be found on examination that these two systems related to different classes of debtors, were based on different principles, and administered by different tribunals. Several of the colonies had also enacted insolvent laws, with some modifications of the British statutes, while the other colonies had taken the British insolvent system as they found it.
A brief notice of the law under consideration will render the application of what has been said plain and obvious. What has congress done 1 It has given us a law in two distinct branches, one of which contains several of the leading features of a bankrupt law proper. It is confined to debtors who are engaged in some branch of trade, and who have done certain specified acts which are made acts of bankruptcy. Against such a debtor the creditor may institute proceedings, and may thereby overreach unjust preferences, set aside fraudulent conveyances, and seize
far the most numerous class of debtors, are to come under the operation of the law or not, according to their own pleasure, without any power of coercion in the creditor. It would sound strangely in the ears of an English lawyer, or of any of those distinguished jurists of our own country who were on the stage at the time the constitution was adopted, to tell them of a bankrupt law extending to all classes of persons, and which was made for the exclusive benefit of the debtor. And it will sound strangely enough to us so soon as we have fully recovered from the spasm which produced this enactment.
This statute not only brings in the English insolvent laws under a new name, but it gives them a scope and influence which they never had before. Instead of stopping where the insolvent laws did, with the release of the debtor from imprisonment, this law goes further, and annuls the obligation of the contract. And what is still worse, upon the construction for which the defendant contends, it has a retrospective operation, and nullifies contracts which had been made before the law was passed. This, too, is done without the consent of creditors, either as individuals, or as a class governed by majorities. The respect which I feel for those who enacted the law has not overcome the convictions of my own judgment, that this was not a constitutional exercise of power. Indeed, I think the opinion
Let us see where a bankrupt system might end if the principles asserted in this law were fully carried out. If the power of coercion may' be denied- to the creditor as to any particular class of debtors, then it may be denied in all cases. This would give us a system made for the exclusive benefit of the debtor, which would contradict all that has ever been enacted or written on the subject of a bankrupt law. Again: If persons not connected with trade may become voluntary bankrupts, then it is entirely clear that congress can extend the system in its compulsory form, so as to authorize the creditor to sue out a commission against airy debtor, whatever may be his pursuit or occupation. Such a law would be without any warrant in the history of the past, and could not fail to shock the whole community. Our farmers, planters and mechanics, to say nothing of many other classes which are not engaged in trade, are not always very exact in paying their debts at the day, although they may be solvent; and if a commission could be sued out against such persons, it could hardly fail to prove ruinous to them, and that too without benefiting the creditor. The effects of the debtor would not be likely to constitute more than what Lord Eldon called “ stock in trade for the commissioners, the assignees, and the solicitor.” (6 Ves. 1.) I do not believe that any member of the federal convention, or any lawyer or statesman who acted upon the adoption of the constitution, ever dreamed that the bankrupt system could be rightfully extended to persons who were not connected with trade and commerce. The Federalist has but a single paragraph upon the subject, which is contained in the 42d number, written by Mr. Madison. It is as follows: “ the power of establishing uniform laws of bankruptcy, is so intimately connected with the regulation of
But the principle asserted by this act of congress reaches a still wider field than we have yet surveyed. If the law comes within the power, it must be because congress is not tied down to any particular system of laws touching the relation of debtor and creditor; but has power over the whole subject of insolvency, talcing the word in its largest sense. This covers the entire relation of debtor and creditor, so far as relates to their rights and remedies in case the debt is not paid. Congress has but to exert its authority, and the whole civil jurisdiction of the state courts, from the highest to the lowest, will be blotted out. And still more. If the power does not refer to any system of laws, but is to be understood as speaking of insolvency in the abstract, then congress need not require the debtor to go through the forms of asking a discharge ; but may at once absolve him from his obligation, and tell the creditor he is a creditor no longer. There need be no surrender of the debtor’s estate. He
If we intend to meet this question fairly, without warping the fundamental law to the exigency of the times, I cannot entertain a doubt that the fiamers of the constitution, when they used the word “ bankruptcies,” plainly referred to one, and only one of the two great legal systems touching the relation of debtor and creditor which had long been in operation. The conven
Bankruptcy is a legal term; Ave are discussing its meaning as used in a legal instrument; find Ave must go to the laAvs to ascertain its legal import. And to Avhat laAvs shall we go but to those of England under Avhich we had lived doAvn to the revolution 1 Will it be said that either the convention,- the states, or the people had in mind any other laAvs ? I presume not. But suppose Ave leave England, and cast our eyes over the rest of Europe. I have yet to learn that any government on the continent had a bankrupt law, eo nomine, or any thing Avhich ansAvered either in form or substance to the English bankrupt system, or to the one Avhich we have so recently had and repudiated. Most of the European states had the cessio bonorvm of the civil laAV, Avhich only relieved the debtor from imprisonment on surrendering his effects, and left his future acquisitions subject to be seized by the creditor. We must then return to England before Ave can find a bankrupt system Avhich will blot out the debt; and when Ave go there Ave can find no pattern for the insolvent or voluntary branch of our bankrupt laAV. Scotland has a bankrupt laAV Avhich differs in several particulars from the English system. But it Avill not answer the defendant’s purpose. It was not until Avithin a recent period that it
Some considerations have been pressed into the argument which can have little or no just bearing upon the question. We are told that some of the states, prior to the revolution, had made enactments containing many of the features of a bankrupt system. That may be true. But they had never called them bankrupt laws. They had always been termed insolvent laws, or laws for the relief of insolvent debtors ; and if the convention intended to refer to those laws, they would have spoken of insolvency, instead of bankruptcy. The argument that the state laws contained some of the features of a bankrupt system, so far as it proves any thing; weighs against those who use it. As the states had never called them bankrupt laws, no one can say that such is their proper name, without comparing them with some bankrupt system; and this carries us back again to the laws of England. Before dismissing this head of the argument I must not omit to notice that, prior to the adoption of tiie federal constitution, there were very few if any state laws which discharged the debt; and whether we look at those laws before or after that period, I have never met with more than one which discharged the debt without the consent of the creditors as a class. With that exception, the consent of a large majority in value of the creditors has, I believe, always been required before the debtor could get any thing more than a release from imprisonment. The exception to which I allude is our own insolvent law of 1811. That law, as has already been noticed, was first condemned by the people, then repealed by the legislature, and finally declared unconstitutional by the supreme court of the United States. The law of congress which we are considering has already shared the same fate in two of the particulars which have been mentioned; and I trust that in due time the parallel will be completed.
The laws which have from time to time been made by congress for the relief of the debtors of the United States, whether called bankrupt or insolvent laws, prove nothing on this ques
The statute, 32 Geo. II, ch. 28, commonly called the lords’ act, enables the judgment creditor to compel the debtor to assign his property after he has remained three, months in prison. But whether the debtor moves voluntarily or by coercion, he obtains nothing but a release from imprisonment, aiid his future effects remain- liable for any balance which may still be due to the-creditor. (§ 16, 17.) The fact that this insolvent law has authorized the creditor, under particular circumstances, to become the moving party, is very far from - proving that the insolvent'and bankrupt systems are identical'. .Nor does it prove that the debtor may be the moving party under a bankrupt law;. or if "he may, that all power of coercion can be denied to the creditor.. .
The late'English bankrupt act, 6 Geo. IV, ch. 16, allows a trader to filé and publish a declaration “ that he is insolvent and unable to meet his engagements and this is declared to be “ an act of bankruptcy,” upon which a commission may issue, which will be valid although the declaration was concerted between the bankrupt and a creditor. (§ 6,7.) It would be sufficient to say, that this statute, passed in 1825, can prove nothing on the subject of .the powers-which had been delegated to congress in 1787. But if such a provision had existed before pur revolution, it would prove nothing in favor'of the defendant. The statute only adds another to the various acts of the trader which.- are to be deemed acts .of bankruptcy, upon which the , creditors may take out a commission, if they think proper.
' The act of bankruptcy was always the act of the debtor. But beyond that, he- never had before, nor has he now, the power to put the machinery in motion, and demand a discharge. It still remains for the creditors to sue out a commission or not at . their pleasure, and if they do not move, the debtor is just as powerless now as he was before.
It is upon such shreds and patches as those which have just been mentioned that -an attempt is made to confound the bank
We know from the papers of Mr. Madison that when this subject was brought before the convention, the English bankrupt laws were expressly mentioned, and Connecticut voted against the clause, because the delegates from that state were unwilling to grant so large a power in relation to bankruptcies as had been exercised in England. (3 Mad. Pap. 1481.) But we do not need this evidence to satisfy any reasonable man that the members of the convention had in their minds the English bankrupt system. It was a system which had been in operation in their own country for more than two centuries ; and however men may reason upon the words of the grant, I can never bring my mind to the conclusion that the convention did not refer to that system in its great outlines, or that they intended to vest in congress a larger power upon this subject than had ever been exercised by the British parliament.
I shall say no more upon this branch of the case. Let it now be granted that congress may disregard all the leading features of the English bankrupt system, and make a law extending to all classes of debtors, placing the whole power in their hands, and denying all means of coercion to the creditor. And let it also be granted, that, As to future contracts, the law may provide for the discharge of the debt without the con
As men are always supposed to contract with reference to the law of the land, there is some propriety in saying that the law enters into and forms a part of the contract. When, therefore, there is a bankrupt system in operation at the time the credit is given, the debtor does not agree to pay in all events ; hut only that he will pay unless the debt shall be discharged in the mode already prescribed by law. It is upon this principle that the state insolvent laws have, to some extent, been taken out'of the prohibition against passing laws “ impairing the obligation of contracts.” But we are not now dealing with a prospective law; but with one which comes after the credit was given, and blots out the debt. Although some may think it a light thing for the legislature thus to nullify contracts, the announcement of such a doctrine cannot fail to shock the moral sense of every right minded man in the community. Discharging the debt which B. owes to A., is precisely the same thing in principle as taking the goods or the house of A. and transferring them to B. In either case A. is deprived of his property against his will, and without any fault on his part. Such a law strikes at the foundation of the social compact. Governments are instituted
It is said that, as this law provides for a distribution of the debtor’s property, the creditor gets all that he has a right to demand. That argument was met and overthrown by Chief Justice Marshall, in passing upon the validity of our state insolvent law. He says: “ It has been contended that as a contract can only bind a man to pay to the full extent of his property, it is an implied condition that he may be discharged on surrendering the whole of it. But it is not true that the parties have in view only the property in possession at the time the contract is formed, or that its obligation does not extend to future acquisitions. Industry, talents and integrity constitute a fmid which is as confidently trusted as property itself. Future acquisitions are therefore liable for contracts, and to release them from this liability impairs their obligation.” (Sturges v. Crowninshield, 4 Wheat. 122, 198.) The inability of the debtor to pay, whether it arises from his fault or his misfortune, cannot annul his obligation. A contract is in its very nature indissoluble without the consent of both parties. Nothing but performance, death, or mutual agreement can put an end to it. Indeed, death does not dissolve it. The obligation survives the,debtor as a charge upon his estate, and the heir or distributee takes the property cum onere.
The states are forbidden to pass any law “ impairing the obligation of contracts.” But this was not done for the purpose of securing a monopoly of that species of fraud to congress. As the power to annul contracts had not been delegated to the federal government, there could be no necessity for extending the prohibition to congress. But for more abundant caution the states have since made several amendments to the federal constitution, which now constitute the paramount law; and the fifth of those amendments extends the prohibition in still broader terms to the action of the federal government. The words
The right to annul contracts has certainly not been given to congress ip terms, and if it can be'found in the constitution it must be because it is included iti the bankrupt power. ' The argument from " that clause commences by changing the word “ bankruptcies” into insolvency, and then proceeds thus: Congress may legislate on the subject of insolvency; this-includes the whole subject,oí insolvency, and the power of congress over it is .just as ample as that which 'might be exercised by the British parliament: parliament can annul contracts, and therefore congress may do it. This is the substance ahd whole force of the argument so far as it' has ever come to my ears. Í have already entered my protest against changing the words of the grant, and shall therefore say nothing more upon that point.
I deny at the outset that the powers of the government in this country, where we have written constitutions," can be justly measured by what has been termed the omnipotence of parliament. That body has no written law to define the limits of its authority. It makes its own constitution. Magna charta exerts only a moral influence: it interposes no other barrier. Public opinion constitutes the only conservative principle of the government. Short of working miracles, parliament may do what it pleases; for there is no standard by which to try the validity of its acts. I know it has been said that acts of parliament which are “ against common right and reason,” are void. (8 Co. 118.) But Blackstone has shown us that such is not the law of England. (1 Comm. 91.) When, therefore, we speak of the power of parliament over a given subject, there is no question of construction in the case. But when we come to governments deriving their authority from written constitutions, the case is far otherwise, If the power to do the. particular thing has not been granted in express terms, but is to be inferred from general words, a question of construction immediately springs up. What is the just and reasonable interpretation of the grant'? Does it, when fairly expounded, include the matter in hand 1 If it does not, the thing cannot be done, although it may come within the letter of the grant. Parliament may blot out debts; but it does not, like congress, act under a power to legislate on the subject of insolvency, but under a power to do whatever it pleases, not only in relation to insolvency, but every thing else. We see, therefore, that there is an litter fallacy in the argument which gives this power to congress because the British parliament has it. The same course of reasoning would prove that congress might attaint the creditor of high treason, for that may be done by parliament.
We are then brought back to the inquiry whether, under the power to legislate on the subject of bankruptcies, congress can annul debts which were contracted before the law was passed. Now I take it to be a sound principle that no power conferred
Although the powers of parliament haye no constitutional limit, the English courts have .often restricted the operation of .statutes; and this has been done on a principle whiph is directly applicable to the question before us. If parliament should, in express terms, direct a thing to be done which is contrary to reason and justice, the mandate must be obeyed, “ Put,”
Let us now apply the principle asserted by this law to other subjects of legislation. Congress has power to lay and collect taxes, duties, imposts, and excise: to regulate commerce, and to declare war. Can congress lay a new duty on the goods which the merchant imported the year before; or can any one be taxed on account of the property which he once owned, but had sold
If then it be conceded, as has been ■ thus far assumed, that the authority to annul contracts may possibly be deduced from the bankrupt power, I hold that upon well established principles—such as have been and must be acknowledged in every enlightened community—the power should not be so construed as to touch this debt.. It is against reason and justice. But the authority to annul contracts, whether made prior or subsequent to the passing of the law, can only he deduced from the bankrupt power by supposing that the convention had in view the English bankrupt system. Under that, the debt is discharged. But the advocates for this law are compelled to reject that system, because it will not answer their purpose. It is confined to traders, and is a compulsory remedy in the hands of the creditor; and besides, the debtor cannot be discharged without the consent of his creditors as a class. Let us lay the English
There is still another view of this question which is very satisfactory to my mind. Congress has no judicial power over the subject of insolvency. The power is “ to establish uniform laws” on that subject. A law is a rule of action. It looks to the future. It prescribes the rule of right and of duty for the time to come. But congress has attempted the exercise of judicial powers. It has legislated backward instead of forward, and thus passed judgment upon existing obligations. It has not declared what shall be the force of contracts thereafter to be made, or when, or under what circumstances the obligation of such
I have spoken plainly of this law1, not because it gave me any pleasure to do so, but because I thought the occasion called for it. The law is based upon false and dangerous principles. Congress has undertaken to legislate for the past, as well as the future ; and instead of leaving men to bear the consequences of .their own follies and misfortunes, an attempt has been made to transfer their burdens to the shoulders? of "other men. The law benefits one class of' citizens at the expense of another, and ■it cannot be carried into execution without producing that un
I desire not to be understood as entertaining any hostility to a proper bankrupt system. On the contrary, I deem such a system highly expedient in a country like this, where there are several independent governments in operation, and where so many of the people are engagedin trade and commerce. A bankrupt law is necessary to secure to creditors their just rights, and to afford adequate relief to those, who, from the nature of their pursuits, are subject to sudden and unforeseen reverses of fortune. But those classes which are not connected with trade, neither need, nor Could they endure a national bankrupt system.
Since my opinion was prepared, Í have received two other opinions upon the same subject; one by Judge Wells of the U. S. court for the district of Missouri, who agrees with me that the voluntary branch of the law cannot be supported; (2 N. Y. Legal Observer, 185;) and the other by Mr. Justice Catron, who has arrived at a different conclusion. (1 Howard, 277, note.) Beyond the weight of authority which the name of the learned judge last mentioned justly Carries with it, I see nothing in his opinion which is calculated to shake the convictions of my judgment. After what has already been said, I shall only notice one or two things. The learned judge has 11 purposely avoided any attempt to define the mere word bankruptcyand has contented himself with affirming, that the power “ extends to all cases where the law causes to be distributed the property of the debtor among his creditors ; this is its least limit. Its greatest is the discharge of the debtor from his contracts. And all intermediate legislation, affecting substance, and form, but tending to further the great end of the subject—distribution and discharge—are in the competency and discretion of congress.” The power is to make laws “ on the subject of bankruptcies,” and no “ limit” of any kind is mentioned in the constitution. How then can any boundary be affixed to the power, except .by «regarding it as pointing to some bankrupt system ? Clearly there is none. The very fact that the learned judge has mentioned limits, proves that no lawyer can read and reason upon the power without considering it as pointing to the English bankrupt system, which provides for “ distribution and discharge.” If that be so, then what authority can there be for taking one or two things contained in that system, and rejecting all the rest? Why go beyond traders ? Why place the power in the hands
I have been particularly struck with the difficulty which the learned judge found in getting over the objection that this law violates contracts. Indeed, I do not perceive that he has got over it, unless it be by a leap. But the fault is not his : it is in the law. There is no legal highway across that gulph. He says “ the great object of giving the bankrupt power to congress was to deprive the states of the dangerous power to abolish debts.” With great submission, I think otherwise. That end was fully accomplished by another clause of the constitution, which directly prohibits the states from passing any law “ impairing the obligation of contracts.” The mere existence of the bankrupt power has not even touched the jurisdiction of the state legislatures.
But I will not piusue the subject. It is easy to affirm that this law is. warranted by the bankrupt power. But any one who attempts to assign the reasons for such an opinion, will, I think, find that he has entered upon a most difficult task.
My conclusion is, that the voluntary branch of the bankrupt law is unconstitutional, for the following reasons:
1. It is not confined to traders, but extends to all classes of debtors.
2. It places the whole power in the hands of the debtor, without giving any means of coercion to the creditor.
3. It discharges the debt without the consent of the creditor in any form, and so violates the obligation of the contract.
4. If it retroacts so as to discharge debts contracted before its passage, then it not only violates contracts, but it goes entirely beyond the scope of the bankrupt power. It is not a law, but a sentence or judgment against creditors, and congress has no judicial power over the subject.
Judgment for the plaintiff.