People v. Lord

Learned, P. J.:

There is no doubt that, morally, the defendants committed a fraud on the plaintiffs. The' question is whether their act was such that the law will compel them to • compensate the injured party.

It is important to see exactly what the alleged act was. In the course of the argument it was said, on behalf of the defendants, that the purchase of a bid was not a fraud; that, in like manner, the destruction of a bid was not a fraud; and that in concealing the fact of such purchase and destruction the defendants made no fraudulent concealment, because the State placed no trust or confidence in them as regarded this matter.

But it must be observed that' the transaction was not the mere purchase and destruction of bids. It was an affirmative agreement among the parties present at the meeting, that no one should bid except that party who should pay to the others the highest price for the privilege. It was, therefore, a plain agreement among *394themselves against competition, admitted to have been made with fraudulent intent, and to have been designed to depress prices. The surrender and destruction of the bids which had been previously prepared, were only the means of carrying out the agreement. The gist of the agreement was that, in consideration of money paid by the defendants, the other parties would not bid for the contract, and the object was to compel the State, if possible, to pay more for the work than it would have cost at fair prices or open competition.

It is not questioned that such an agreement is void. (1 Story’s Eq., § 293; Jones v. Caswell, 3 Johns. Cas., 29; Atcheson v. Mallon, 43 N. Y., 147.) The reasons given are that such an agreement is uneonscientious and against public policy, and has a tendency injuriously to affect the character and value of sales at public auction, and to mislead private confidence; that it operates as a fraud- on the sale; that it is contrary to morality and sound policy ; that it deprives the person selling of the opportunity of obtaining a full equivalent for the property. It is, therefore, evident that the reason why such an agreement is held to be void, is not any wrong which the parties thereto have done to each, other, or any want of consideration for the agreement or the like; but the reason is that the agreement operates as a fraud upon another person / that is, the person whose property is put up at auction. In declaring the invalidity of such agreements the courts have, therefore, necessarily declared that ‘such agreements tended to defraud the person who sells property at auction. That is to sajq that if such an agreement be carried out, and that if the person selling the property, thereby obtain a less price than he would otherwise have received, and less than a reasonable price, he has been actually defrauded by means of the agreement, and has not merely suffered a loss for which no one was to blame. And because such agreements tend to produce this fraudulent result, they are held to be void.

Upon the same general principle, the employment of by-bidders, or puffers, by the seller at an auction sale, is a fraud. (Bexwell v. Christie, Cowp., 396.) The principle is applied to the letting of contracts as well as to the sale of merchandise. Thus, where, in the case of a letting of work on the canal, certain persons agreed for *395the consideration of $400, paid by a higher bidder, to withdraw their bid, the court held this agreement to be illegal, and refused to enforce a division of the $400 among the parties. And the court said the transaction was “contrary to public policy and illegal, * * * and tended to destroy that honest competition which public bidding is designed to secure.” ( Woodworth v. Bennett., 43 N. Y., 273.) Again, where the postmaster-general had given notice for proposals for conveying the mail, and the plaintiffs intended to make proposals and to try to obtain the contract, and the defendants agreed to pay them $1,000 if they would not make such proposals, the agreement was held to be illegal. (Gulick v. Ward, 5 Halst., 87.)

The question then, which presents itself here is this: When an agreement is so injurious to the public and so- likely to defraud some third party, that the courts refuse to enforce it, and when such a fraudulent agreement has actually caused, as it was intended to do, a loss and injury to some third party, who is entirely innocent; shall he be without redress ? If the courts will not compel a division of the gains made under such an agreement, because they were obtained by fraud, ought the courts to refuse to restore these gains to the person from whom they were fraudulently obtained ?

To answer these questions we may first notice some cases analogous, but not identical in principle. If by-bidders are employed at an auction, the purchaser is not bound to complete his purchase. (Howard v. Castle, 6 Durn. & East, 642 ; see also Crowder v. Austin, 2 Car. & P., 208 ; Wheeler v. Callier, 2 Mood & M., 123.) In Veazie v. Williams (8 How. [U. S.], 134), the. defendant Williams sold some real estate at auction ; without his knowledge the auctioneer made fictitious bids; Yeazie, the plaintiff, thereupon purchased the property at $40,000; he received a deed, paid a part in cash and gave notes for the balance; $14,000 remained unpaid at the time of the commencement of the action. The sale was in 1836 ; the alleged fraud was discovered in 1840, and the action was commenced in 1841. The court held that the transaction was a fraud on the purchaser, and required the seller to refund to him all over $20,000, that being the highest real bid.

Now, on behalf of the defendants here, it may be truly said that in those and similar cases, there was the affirmative act of pro*396curing fictitious bids, and that the purchasers were deceived by these bids. But, when we examine the nature of the alleged deception we shall see that, in substance, it is the same which was practiced in the present case. Fictitious bids are not misstatements as to the condition or quality of the thing sold. The buyer may exercise his judginent, and may examine, so far as possible, the property for which he is bidding; and when he knows its condition and quality, and voluntarily offers so much for it, on what ground can he claim to have been defrauded by the mistaken idea that some other person offered a certain other sum ? The ground, as stated by Lord Mansfield in the case above cited, is this: “ The basis of all dealings ought to be good faith. So more especially in those transactions, where the public are brought together in a confidence that the articles set up for sale will be .disposed of to the highest bidder.” Although then, the purchaser be thoroughly acquainted with the property to be sold, so as to be capable of judging correctly as to its value, still he is defrauded by the employment of by-bidders; and this, because an auction sale demands good faith on both sides; no by-bidding on the part of the seller, no agreement against competition on the part of the buyer. And just as the employment of by-bidders is a fraud on the buyers, so an agreement against competition is a fraud on the seller. Each is a violation of the true and fair intent of such sales. Each shows its fraudulent character by the secrecy with which it is carried out.

And since the courts have held that an agreement against competition, intended to depress prices, is a fraud, or tends to produce a fraud on the seller, it would seem to follow that they have held, that, as to him, such an agreement is a wrongful act. To illustrate: a mere neglect to bid at a sale might diminish the price which the seller would obtain, but it would be no fraud or wrong. But an agreement not to compete, intended to depress prices, is characterized as a fraud upon the seller, and must, therefore, have been considered a wrong toward him.

And we may see how strongly the courts insist on perfect fairness at such sales, from the case of Cocks v. Izard (7 Wall., 559). There, at a judicial sale, a person caused it to be understood that he was bidding for the owner. Other persons voluntarily refrained *397from bidding, and the property was struck off to him. The sale was set aside, for “ the law will not tolerate any influence likely to prevent competition at a judicial sale.” In that case there was no agreement not to compete. The same doctrine is recognized in Fuller v. Abrahams (6 Mood, 316); Johnson v. La Motte (6 Rich. Eq., 347); Plaster v. Burger (5 Ind., 232).

Now, on behalf of the defendants, it is said that the present case differs from the cases above cited, and others like them, in these particulars: that those were cases of judicial sales; and, also, that, in the present case, the contracting board acted voluntarily in accepting the bid; and that they had the right, if they chose, to reject all bids.

The principle of law which forbids the employment of by-bidders applies to private as well as to judicial sales, as will appear by the cases already cited.

Whether the principle which declares agreements against competition, made to depress prices, to be void, is equally extensive, we need not now say. For, although the letting of these contracts was not done under any judicial proceeding, still it was not the case of a private person, who was abont to build, and who had, by his own choice, advertised for proposals. The letting was done under the requirements of the law. The fair and true intent of the law ought to be enforced by the courts, as much as in a sale under their own authority. The contract was, by the Constitution, to be made with the lowest bidder (art. 7, § 3, amended 1854), and statutes had been passed to carry out this provision. And the illegality of agreements against competition, as between the parties in the ease of such lettings, is declared in Gulick v. Ward and Woodworth v. Bennett (ut supra). Thus, such lettings, made under the authority of the law, have been recognized to be subject to the same rule, in this respect, as judicial sales.

Again, the plain object of the Constitution and the statutes is to obtain for the State, in respect to these contracts, the benefit of fair and open competition. The intent of the defendants was to thwai’t that object, and such was the result. Their combination had that end, and no other, except their own gain.

But it is said that the board might reject all bids if they did not consider them advantageous. Of what use would that be ? The *398board must advertise again. If parties might lawfully make an agreement against competition once, they might do so again; so that a second advertisement for the letting of these contracts would have had the same result with the first. It would be useless to reject these bids and to have new biddings, when the same combinations against competition could be repeated over and over again, with the sanction of law. In a judicial sale the officer must sell; he must sell at auction ; he must sell to the highest bidder. So with the contracting board. They must have the work done ; they must advertise for biddings; they must let by contract to the lowest bidder. There is, therefore, little analogy between them and a private individual. lie may build or not, as he chooses ; may let his work by contract or not, as lie chooses; may select the highest or the lowest bidder, as he chooses. It is not, therefore, necessary to the decision of the present case to inquire how far these princi pies apply to merely private contracts.

But the objection that the contracting board acted voluntarily in accepting the bid will be answered by a reference to the cases already cited, of by-bidding. In those cases, too, the purchaser acts voluntarily. He need not buy if he thinks the property has been carried beyond its value. His bid is a voluntary expression of his own offer. Yet he is not bound thereby if by-bidders have been employed. So the contracting board acted' voluntarily in accepting the bid. But the means employed by the defendants to obtain the acceptance were contrary to the object of requiring public competition.

There are some cases which touch this question more directly. In Dudley v. Little (2 Ham. [Ohio], 504), a tax sale and deed were set aside, because there had been a combination among, several persons that one of them should bid in the land to prevent competition.

In Phippen v. Stickney (3 Metc., 381), in a carefully considered opinion, the court held that an agreement not to compete would be fraudulent, if the intent were to prevent competition and depress the price.

The case of Breslin v. Brown (34 Ohio State, 565), was one where a contract for public improvement was to be let to the lowest bidder. The plaintiff h'ad put in a bid, and he and the *399defendant then agreed to become partners in the matter. The defendant also put in a bid, which proved to be the lowest. The court said that “ any agreement entered into for the purpose of preventing competition is not only void, but it renders any sale void at the option of the seller. * * * Fair competition among bidders, to the end that sellers may be protected against fraudulent combination, is all the law seeks to secure.” And in that case the court held that there was no intent to prevent competition, and that no injury to the seller resulted. But the doctrine was asserted that a combination to prevent competition, made with fraudulent intent and to depress the price, renders the sale void. These decisions, therefore, all support plaintiffs’ views; since it is admitted m the present case that the object of the defendants was to defraud the plaintiffs and to increase the price, and that such was the result.

Again, it is said on behalf of the defendants that there was no misrepresentation. But in a sale at auction, unfair dealing and bad faith may come from other sources than actual misrepresentation. In the many cases where agreements against competition have been held to be illegal and null, such illegality and nullity are not placed on the ground of a false representation to the seller. By-bidding prevents fair competition indirectly. An agreement not to bid made to depress prices prevents it directly. “Perfect freedom from' all influence likely to prevent competition in the sale should be in all such cases strictly exacted.” (Slater v. Maxwell, 6 Wallace, 268.)

We have been referred by the defendants’ counsel to the case of Jones v. North (19 Equity Cases [Law Rep.], 426). In that case a corporation invited tenders for a supply of stone. The plaintiff agreed to purchase a certain quantity of stone from the defendant and from two other several owners of quarries.

In consideration thereof the defendant agreed not to send in any tender or to furnish any stone to the corporation. The owners of the other quarries were to put in tenders above the plaintiff’s. The plaintiff sent, in a tender, and the defendant, in violation of his agreement, also sent in a tender, which was accepted by the corporation. This action was brought to restrain him.from furnishing any such stone to the corporation. A demurrer to the bill was overruled.

*400But in that ease several things must be noticed. So far as appears, the corporation was not required by law to purchase by contract with the lowest bidder. It was, therefore, in the position of a private individual. Secondly. The corporation had not, in fact, been injured. The defendant had broken tire agreement and bad made a tender. This was presumably lower than the plaintiff’s and was accepted. And the court says that if by this action the defendant should be prevented from fulfilling his contract, the corporation could recover damages against him by an action at law. The corporation had secured, and could not be deprived of the benefit resulting from a breach of the agreement between the parties. Third. The court says nothing about the agreement against competition, but only states that it was lawful for the owners to sell their commodities to each other, although with knowledge that the purchaser was about to supply the corporation. Fourth. There is no allegation that the object of the agreement was to defraud the corporation. Finally, if the case holds that an agreement not to compete, made with intent to depress prices, is valid between the parties, it is contrary to the law of our State. (Atcheson v. Mallon, 43 N. Y., 147.)

If any doubt could exist whether, after actually entering into the contract with tire defendants, in ignorance of the fraud and after the contract had been carried out and settled in such ignorance, the State could now, on discovery of the fraud, have redress; that would seem to be settled by the ease of Veazie v. Williams (ut supra).

The defendants further urge that these views demand of them a higher degree of morality than is required in any other business. We think not. It is no hard rule to say that men shall not combine, with fraudulent intent, to deprive the State of the benefit of that fair competition which the Constitution and the statutes contemplate. Not to enter into such combinations is only simple honesty.

The judgment should be reversed and a new trial granted, costs to abide the event.

Present — Learned, P. J., Bookes and Boardman, JJ.

Ordered accordingly.