SWN Production Company, LLC and Equinor USA Onshore Properties, Inc. v. Charles Kellam, Phyllis Kellam, and all other persons and entities similarly situated

FILED June 14, 2022 released at 3:00 p.m. EDYTHE NASH GAISER, CLERK SUPREME COURT OF APPEALS OF WEST VIRGINIA No. 21-0729 – SWN Production Company, LLC and Equinor USA Onshore Properties Inc. v. Charles Kellam, Phyllis Kellam, and all other persons and entities similarly situated Chief Justice Hutchison, concurring: I wholeheartedly concur with the majority opinion’s assessment that Estate of Tawney v. Columbia Natural Resources, L.L.C., 219 W. Va. 266, 633 S.E.2d 22 (2006) (“Tawney”), and Wellman v. Energy Resources, Inc., 210 W. Va. 200, 557 S.E.2d 254 (2001) (“Wellman”), remain good law in West Virginia. I also agree that the remaining three questions posed by the district court – essentially asking what language or details are required by Tawney and Wellman to be included in a lease – are usually case-by-case questions. Leases are contracts, written repositories of the parties’ intentions. When oil- 1 and-gas leases are not properly drafted or are later interpreted by a party in a slipshod manner, the questions posed by the district court become issues to be resolved by a court or factfinder. I write separately to emphasize the central, general rule underlying Tawney and Wellman that was only tangentially touched upon by the majority opinion. The rule underlying Tawney and Wellman is simple: contracts are formed by a meeting of the minds. You cannot have a meeting of the minds if a contract uses terms that are vague, ambiguous, “An oil and gas lease (or other mineral lease) is both a conveyance and a 1 contract.” Syl. pt. 1, in part, McCullough Oil, Inc. v. Rezek, 176 W. Va. 638, 346 S.E.2d 788 (1986). 1 and neither understood nor accepted by both parties. This rule is immutable and is, with few exceptions, the basis for every legally enforceable agreement. To understand the general rule at the heart of Wellman and Tawney in the context of an oil and gas lease, the reader must understand other, more specific, long- standing interwoven guidelines tied to the interpretation of oil and gas leases. These guidelines are, by default, implied into every oil and gas lease. For over a century, the first guideline has been that lessee/oil-and-gas companies cannot lease oil and gas rights and then sit on those rights, to the detriment of the owner/lessor of the rights. Thus, the 2 fundamental goal implied into every single oil and gas lease is that the lessee has a duty to extract the minerals and get them to market for sale. 3 Included in that goal is an 2 See St. Luke’s United Methodist Church v. CNG Dev. Co., 222 W. Va. 185, 191-92, 663 S.E.2d 639, 645-46 (2008) (“This Court has recognized the unfairness of allowing a lessee to effectively tie up land when others stood ready to develop the same.”); Syl. pt. 1, in part, McCullough Oil, Inc. v. Rezek, 176 W. Va. 638, 346 S.E.2d 788 (1986) (An oil and gas lease “is designed to accomplish the main purpose of the owner of the land and of the lessee (or its assignee) as operator of the oil and gas interests: securing production of oil or gas or both in paying quantities, quickly and for as long as production in paying quantities is obtainable.”); United Fuel Gas Co. v. Smith, 93 W. Va. 646, 117 S.E. 900, 904 (1923) (“[T]here is always implied in every oil and gas lease a covenant to drill the number of wells reasonably necessary to develop the property and prevent drainage by operation on adjoining lands.”); Lowther Oil Co. v. Miller-Sibley Oil Co., 53 W. Va. 501, 44 S.E. 433, 435 (1903) (“[A] lease calls for the right, not to oil in place, but to extract it.”); Parish Fork Oil Co. v. Bridgewater Gas Co., 51 W.Va. 583, 42 S.E. 655 (1902) (recognizing as universal the principle of law “which discourages tying up and rendering unproductive the vast fields of mineral wealth, construes every contract and lease as to both lessor and lessee so as to best promote production, development and progress, and frowns upon every attempt to evade it as being in contravention of both good morals and public policy.”). See generally, Keith B. Hall, Implied Covenants and the Drafting of Oil 3 and Gas Leases, 7 LSU J. Energy L. & Resources 401, 418 (2019) (“The implied covenant 2 understanding that the lessee bears all of the risks and costs of drilling, producing, and getting the oil and gas to market. Hence, the lessee bears the risk of drilling a dry well. The lessee also bears the risk that the physical properties of any oil or natural gas discovered may be of a lesser quality or pressure than is desired. Another corollary, default guideline implied into every oil and gas lease is just as clear: the lessor/owner of oil and gas rights is entitled to royalties, that is, a share of the profit gained from the oil and gas the lessee delivers to market. In West Virginia, those royalties are, by default, (1) based on the gross proceeds received by the lessee at the first point of sale to an unaffiliated third-party purchaser in an arm’s length transaction, and (2) free from any deductions for the expenses incurred by the lessee getting the oil and gas to market. Wellman involved another basic doctrine of contract law: the parties to an oil and gas lease can agree to disclaim any of the default, implied guidelines I just described, and contract for a different result. Our opinion plainly stated the default guideline, which is that that every oil and gas lease is built on a presumption that the lessee will bear both the responsibility and the cost of getting the minerals to an impartial marketplace. We to market requires a lessee to diligently seek purchasers at a reasonable price for any oil or gas that is found in paying quantities.”); Nancy Saint-Paul, 2 Summers Oil and Gas § 18:11 (3d ed. 2021) (“In order to carry out the purposes for which an oil and gas lease is made, that is, the . . . production and sale [of oil and gas] so as to yield a profit to the lessee and a return to the lessor in the form of rents and royalties, it is necessary that the oil or gas produced from the land be marketed.”). 3 ruled in Wellman that a lease can alter that presumption and provide that the lessor will bear a share of the costs of getting the oil and gas to market, but only if those costs were (1) actually incurred by the lessee, and (2) reasonable. Syl. pts. 4 and 5, Wellman, 210 W. Va. at 202, 557 S.E.2d at 256. In Tawney, we reiterated and expounded on Wellman. We determined that, to vitiate the presumption that the lessee bears the costs of getting the minerals to market, and to shift some share of the costs onto the lessor, the lease between the parties needs to identify with particularity the specific deductions for post-production marketing costs that the lessee intends to take from the lessor’s royalties, and it must indicate the method of calculating those deductions. See Syl. pt. 10, Tawney, 219 W. Va. at 268, 633 S.E.2d at 24. As the majority opinion makes clear, when a lessee seeks to deduct post-production expenses from the gross proceeds received in the sale of oil or gas to calculate a lessor’s royalty, Tawney continues to require that the lease expressly provide that the lessor shall bear some part the costs incurred between the wellhead and the point of sale (that is, the first sale to an unaffiliated third-party purchaser in an arm’s length transaction); identify with particularity the specific deductions the lessee intends to take from the lessor’s royalty; and indicate the method of calculating the amount to be deducted from the royalty for such post-production costs. Id. Stated simply, Wellman created accountability in oil and gas leases, by clearly stating that oil and gas lessees cannot make deductions to royalties for any post- production costs of marketing unless those costs are (1) clearly shifted onto the lessor in 4 the lease; (2) actually incurred, and (3) reasonable. Syl. pts. 4 and 5, Wellman, 210 W. Va. at 202, 557 S.E.2d at 256. Tawney created transparency, by requiring oil and gas companies to explain with particularity in the lease the deductions they intend to take from the lessor’s royalties, and to state with reasonable precision how those deductions will be calculated. Syl. pt. 10, Tawney, 219 W. Va. at 268, 633 S.E.2d at 24. Together, the cases are the foundation of what legal scholars call the “marketable-product rule,” because they explain the default position, in every lease, that oil and gas companies bear the cost of preparing and shipping the product they’ve taken out of the lessor’s ground to market. Only if the parties plainly and unambiguously agree to something different will the lessee/company be permitted to shift some of those “post-production” costs onto the lessor. After this Court issued Tawney and Wellman, and several other state courts adopted the marketable-product rule as well, a few legal commentators offered criticism. One said that the cases were schemes “to provide the lessor with a larger piece of the gas- production pie.” Another said the cases were written in a way that “results in an even 4 bigger windfall for lessors.” One oil and gas lawyer called the marketable-product rule 5 nothing more than “a massive shifting of post-production costs from lessors to lessees,” and “a judicially directed wealth transfer from lessees to lessors that contradicts the 4 David E. Pierce, Royalty Jurisprudence: A Tale of Two States, 49 Washburn L.J. 347, 369 (2010). Brian S. Wheeler, Deducting Post-Production Costs When Calculating 5 Royalty: What Does the Lease Provide?, 8 Appalachian J.L. 1, 27 (2008). 5 bargained-for exchange struck by the parties.” Essentially, these commentators cast this 6 Court’s efforts as some modern-day, wealth-redistribution scheme to rewrite oil and gas leases to take money from the lessee and give it to the lessor. These critiques are biased nonsense. First, the marketable-product rule is not a “modern-day” concept, rather, it dates back over eight decades. Scholarly texts outlined the boundaries of the rule as early as 1940, when Professor Maurice Merrill (a well-known leader in the development oil-and-gas law) said: If it is the lessee’s obligation to market the product, it seems necessarily to follow that his is the task also to prepare it for market, it if is unmerchantable in its natural form. No part of the costs of marketing or of preparation for sale is chargeable to the lessor. Maurice H. Merrill, The Law Relating to Covenants Implied in Oil and Gas Leases § 85, at 214-15 (2d ed. 1940). Another titan of oil and gas law, Professor Eugene Kuntz, advocated for the marketable-product rule as early as 1962: [T]here is a distinction between acts which constitute production and acts which constitute processing or refining of the substance extracted by production. Unquestionably, under most leases, the lessee must bear all costs of production . . . It is submitted that the acts which constitute production have not ceased until a marketable product has been obtained. Eugene Kuntz, A Treatise on the Law of Oil and Gas § 40.5 (1962). See also, Owen L. Anderson, Royalty Valuation: Should Royalty Obligations Be Determined Intrinsically, 6 John W. Broomes, Waste Not, Want Not: The Marketable Product Rule Violates Public Policy Against Waste of Natural Gas Resources, 63 U. Kan. L. Rev. 149, at 149 and 174 (2014). 6 Theoretically, or Realistically? Part 2, 37 Nat. Resources J. 611 (1997) (“[A]bsent an express lease provision to the contrary, lessees should not have to pay royalty on any value added to production by reason of incurred ‘post-production’ activities. However, ‘production’ should not be regarded as having been completed until a first-marketable product has been obtained.”). Second, most critics of the marketable-product rule inherently, but wrongly, assume that the production of oil and gas is a shared adventure by a lessor and a lessee. But the facts usually show that lessor/land-and-mineral owners and lessee/oil-and-gas companies are not partners on anything close to resembling an equal footing. The imbalance in the relationship between lessor and lessee is most obvious in the take-home profits. That is, in most leases, the lessor only receives a small percentage of the final profit in the form of rents and royalties (usually 1/8) while the lessee oil-and-gas company retains much more (usually 7/8 of the gross profit). But the differences between the parties to a lease go far deeper. In this case the parties are arguing over whether the lessor should pay a share of the “charges” incurred by the lessee for compressing, dehydrating, and transporting oil, gas, or coalbed methane. The lease gives the lessee exclusive control over whether, when, and how to incur those charges, and the lessor has no input. The lessor does not choose the method used for compression, dehydration, or transportation. The lessor does not choose whether, when, or how much to spend when a new building, warehouse, office, or compression station is constructed. These physical structures can be depreciated or written off of the lessee- 7 owner’s taxes, but the lessor does not share the benefit of those tax write-offs. Moreover, at some point, those physical assets may be divested or leased-out by the lessee/oil-and- gas company for a profit which is not shared with the lessor. The lessee may buy equipment like a pickup truck to improve operations; the purchase of the truck is a post-production “charge” that the lessee might insist be shared by the lessor/land-or-mineral owner, and its use to travel to a lunch destination or an industry convention an operational “charge,” but the sale of the truck would just be a “profit” or return of capital to the lessee alone. Put simply, the lessors of minerals are not equal partners with the lessees. Further, as I noted earlier, critics of the marketable-product rule proffer that it creates a “windfall” for mineral-rights owners. These owners sign a lease expecting a royalty calculated as a percentage of the market price received by the lessee. The Merriam- Webster Dictionary defines a “windfall” as “an unexpected, unearned, or sudden gain or advantage.” I am bewildered when critics construe paying a mineral-rights owner their rightful rent or royalty as an unexpected, unearned gain. Restaurants and other businesses often pay their landlords rent based on a percentage of the business’s gross sales; no one ever complains when a landlord gains higher rents after the restaurant or business hired more people, bought more equipment or stock, did more business, and earned more profits. 7 Douglas Hale Gross, Calculation of rental under commercial percentage 7 lease, 58 A.L.R.3d 384, § 2 (1974) (“Percentage leases of commercial retail premises, having originally been employed many years ago, are by now widely used. Between 1910 and 1925, percentage leases were coming into increasing use, just as they are today, in situations where a landowning lessor improved his premises with a building erected to meet the specifications of potential business lessees; the lessor could borrow on the strength of potential percentage rent payments plus minimum rental obligations of the lessee. While 8 When a lessee obtains a higher market price for the oil and gas it took from the lessor by dehydrating, compressing, and transporting the mineral, the lessee pockets a higher profit. Yet, somehow, if the mineral owner receives their contractually set percentage share of those higher profits as a royalty, critics declare that to be an unfair windfall. The disingenuousness of this position is stinging. The royalties due to mineral owners/lessors stay the same under the marketable-product rule (usually 1/8); they never receive a larger piece of the gas- production pie, and there is no judicially directed wealth transfer. In the perpetually unequal oil-and-gas relationship, the owners of minerals allow lessees to extract those minerals from the ground in exchange for a share of the market price. That share stays the same whether the market price rises or drops. Of course, no owner of mineral rights signs a lease anticipating the term “market price” will be an opportunity for gamesmanship; market price means the price garnered in a sale to an unaffiliated third-party purchaser in an arm’s length transaction. “The lessee’s duty of good faith and fair dealing would require that the first market be real, existing, and substantial, and not a market created in bad faith to limit the royalty obligation” Anderson, 37 Nat. Resources J. at 686-87. What the lessee choses to do to those minerals to increase the market price is solely within the lessee’s discretion and control. Accordingly, the lessee bears the full burden of the costs incurred at first percentage leases were used primarily to lease valuable downtown retail locations, today they are used in neighborhood and shopping center store leases as well.”). 9 getting the mineral to market, unless the parties’ lease clearly and unambiguously specifies otherwise. A third problem I see with critics of Wellman, Tawney, and the marketable- product rule is their refusal to recognize that it is, for all intents and purposes, the majority rule in America. “A large group of jurisdictions – a group that accounts for far more than half of the nation’s oil and gas production – follows a marketable-condition rule that requires the lessee to bear the cost of putting oil and natural gas into a marketable condition.” John Burritt McArthur, Oil and Gas Implied Covenants for the Twenty-First Century, 237 (2014). At least five jurisdictions have adopted a variation of the marketable- product doctrine by appellate court decision: Arkansas, Colorado, Kansas, Oklahoma, 8 9 10 11 8 Hanna Oil & Gas Co. v. Taylor, 759 S.W.2d 563, 565 (Ark. 1988) (holding that the lessee was “not entitled to deduct compression costs” when the lease based royalties on “the proceeds received by Lessee”). 9 Garman v. Conoco, Inc., 886 P.2d 652, 659 (Colo. 1994) (“In our view the implied covenant to market obligates the lessee to incur those post-production costs necessary to place gas in a condition acceptable for market. Overriding royalty interest owners are not obligated to share in these costs.”). Sternberger v. Marathon Oil Co., 894 P.2d 788, 799 (Kan. 1995) (“The 10 lessee has the duty to produce a marketable product, and the lessee alone bears the expense in making the product marketable.”). Wood v. TXO Production Corp., 854 P.2d 880, 882 (Okla. 1992) (“In our 11 view, the implied duty to market means a duty to get the product to the place of sale in marketable form.”); TXO Production Corp. v. State ex rel. Commissioners of the Land Office, 903 P.2d 259, 262 (Okla. 1994) (“Clearly, under Wood, [the lessors] were not chargeable with a portion of the costs of compression because such costs are borne by the lessee under its duty to obtain a marketable product. . . . If the processes of dehydration 10 and West Virginia. Critics often complain that these decisions espouse varying 12 interpretations of the doctrine, without recognizing that the common law of each state differs, and the leases and facts of each case differ wildly as well. Additionally, at least 13 three states have adopted the rule and banned the deduction of post-production marketing costs by statute. Importantly, the marketable-product rule has been adopted by the largest 14 owner of mineral interests in the country: the United States government. Federal regulations provide that, for leases on federal land, any gas produced must be marketed “at no cost to the Federal government.” 15 and gathering are necessary to prepare the product for market, then the costs of these processes may not be deducted under the royalty provision of the subject lease.”). One scholar suggests that while a comparable number of states have 12 adopted wildly different versions of the “at the wellhead” doctrine, those states’ decisions are often contradictory or conflict with decisions that suggest the states might actually follow some form of the marketable-product rule. See, e.g., John Burritt McArthur, Some Advice on Bice, North Dakota’s Marketable-Product Decision, 90 N. D. L. Rev. 545, 549- 563 (2014). 13 Appellate judges are not monks studying law in ivory towers and deriving perfect legal principles from the ether. The written opinions of appellate courts are a direct extension of the quality of the briefing and advocacy presented by the parties, both to the appellate courts and to the trial courts below. States adopting marketable-product rules by statute include Michigan 14 (Mich. Comp. Laws § 324.6503b(1) (1999)); Nevada (Nev. Rev. Stat. § 522.115 (2000)); and Wyoming (Wyo. Stat. Ann. § 30-5-304(iv) (1999)). 30 C.F.R. § 1206.146(a) provides that a lessee “must place gas, residue gas, 15 and gas plant products in marketable condition and market the gas, residue gas, and gas plant products for the mutual benefit of the lessee and the lessor at no cost to the Federal government.” See also 30 C.F.R. § 206.152(i) (2010) (“The lessee must place gas in marketable condition and market the gas for the mutual benefit of the lessee and the lessor at no cost to the Federal Government.”); Thomas F. Reese & Drake D. Hill, Wyoming’s 11 Moreover, the Legislative and Executive branches of West Virginia have adopted the marketable-product doctrine. Regarding the Legislature, as the majority opinion notes, in Leggett v. EQT Production Company, 239 W. Va. 264, 800 S.E.2d 850 (2017), this Court refused to extend the Wellman and Tawney marketable-product doctrine to “flat-rate” leases governed by state law. Within a year, the Legislature overruled Leggett, amended state law, and provided that royalties on flat rate leases must be paid “free from any deductions for post-production expenses, received at the first point of sale to an unaffiliated third-party purchaser in an arm’s length transaction for the oil or gas so extracted, produced or marketed.” W. Va. Code § 22-6-8 (2018). As to the Executive branch, it too hews to the marketable-product rule for leases of oil and gas on State lands. The State’s leases expressly provide that a lessee may not deduct the cost of putting oil and natural gas into a marketable condition from royalties due to the State of West Virginia: Production & Post-Production Costs. Neither Lessee, nor any Affiliate of Lessee, may reduce Lessor’s royalty for any post- production expense, including, but not limited to, pipelines, surface facilities, telemetry, gathering, dehydration, transportation, fractionation, compression manufacturing, processing, treating, or marketing of the Granted Minerals, or any severance or other taxes of any nature paid on the production thereof. Royalties under this Lease shall be based Powder River Basin: A Study in Federal Royalty Valuation, 4 Wyo. L. Rev. 629, 630 (2004) (discussing royalty calculation issues on production from leases on federal lands). 12 on the total proceeds of sale of the Granted Minerals, exclusive of any and all production and/or post-production costs. 16 Hence, it is a far stretch for any litigant to insist that this Court adopt a rule wholly at odds with the policies adopted by the Legislature and Executive. Fourth and finally, I feel compelled to discuss a case that was not addressed by the majority opinion: Young v. Equinor USA Onshore Properties, Inc., 982 F.3d 201 (4th Cir. 2020). The Young court was asked on appeal to review a complicated “work- back” method used by an oil-and-gas lessee to make deductions to a lessor’s royalty payment. The district court had found the lease language describing the deductions to be insufficient because it “‘merely state[d] that the lessee will deduct post-production costs,’ yet ‘[said] absolutely nothing as to how those costs would be calculated, other than to leave the amount of the deduction wholly to the lessee’s discretion.’” Id. at 207-08. On appeal, the Young court relied upon the now-defunct analysis used by this Court in Leggett to reverse the district court and approve the lease’s language. The Young court rejected any notion that a lease should have a clear, mathematical formula to calculate how deductions will be taken: Tawney doesn’t demand that an oil and gas lease set out an Einsteinian proof for calculating post-production costs. By its plain language, the case merely requires that an oil and gas lease that expressly allocates some post-production costs to the See West Virginia Department of Commerce, Mineral Development 16 Properties, executed lease agreement between the State of West Virginia and SWN Production Company, underlying portion of the Ohio River within MM60 to southern end of MM70, being approximately 320.44 acres, at https://wvmineraldevelopment.org/ mineral-development-properties (last visited June 14, 2022). 13 lessor identify which costs and how much of those costs will be deducted from the lessor’s royalties. These conditions may be satisfied by a simple formula[.] Id. at 208 (emphasis in original). I question the Young court’s statement that Tawney only requires a lease to contain a “simple formula” and not “an Einsteinian proof” describing how a lessee’s post- production costs of getting oil and gas to market will be deducted from a lessor’s royalty. This statement is correct only if the oil-and-gas lessee is actually taking simple, clear, and unambiguous deductions from the royalties. The problem that I see demonstrated by the case law is that oil-and-gas lessees insist on taking estimated costs or vague, malleable, impossible-to-measure deductions from royalties – in essence, using Einsteinian methods that are incomprehensible to all but the most clever industry accountants. Lessees are using accounting-based chicanery and devising deductions designed to completely consume the lessor’s royalty through a “death by a thousand cuts” strategy. 17 See generally, Adam H. Wilson, Without A Leggett to Stand on: Arguing for Retroactive Application of West Virginia’s Amended Flat-Rate Well Statute, 124 W. Va. L. Rev. 259, 282 (2021) (“At first blush, the net-back method may sound like an equitable way to allocate costs between lessor and lessee; however, lessees use the net-back method to fleece lessors of their valuable minerals. Gas companies . . . best effectuate this by creating wholly-owned See Amicus Curiae Brief on Behalf of West Virginia Royalty Owners’ 17 Association, West Virginia Farm Bureau, Bounty Minerals LLC, and Siltstone Resources, LLC (in Support of Respondents Charles Kellam, et al.) at 17. 14 subsidiary companies that charge the mineral owner with what would be otherwise impermissible deductions.”). Frankly, if the lease does not contain a clear explanation of any and all deductions or how those deductions are calculated, understandable by both the oil-and-gas lessee and the mineral owning lessor, then no contract has been formed and the deductions cannot be taken. The rules of contract formation are taught in the first weeks of law school. “It is elementary that mutuality of assent is an essential element of all contracts.” Bailey v. Sewell Coal Co., 190 W. Va. 138, 140, 437 S.E.2d 448, 450 (1993). For this mutuality to exist, “it is necessary that there be a proposal or offer on the part of one party and an acceptance on the part of the other.” Id. “The contractual concept of ‘meeting of the minds’ or ‘mutual assent’ relates to the parties having the same understanding of the terms of the agreement reached.” Messer v. Huntington Anesthesia Grp., Inc., 222 W. Va. 410, 418, 664 S.E.2d 751, 759 (2008). For an oil-and-gas lease to be an enforceable contract, there must be mutuality of assent. Both parties must have the same understanding of the terms of their agreement. Yet leases wrongfully continue to be drafted with ambiguous definitions of the post-production marketing expenses the oil-and-gas lessee intends to deduct from the lessor’s royalties. Moreover, lessees deduct estimates of expenses, or make other vaguely characterized deductions, from royalties without clearly explaining how those deductions are within the terms of the lease. If lessees would simply follow Wellman and Tawney, there would be far less uncertainty in lessor-lessee relations and, concomitantly, less 15 litigation. The details of deductions should be discussed and agreed-upon when the lease is negotiated and signed; when they are not, or the lessee gives the lease terms a new interpretation beyond that discussed by the parties, then litigation over the lease is sure to follow. Accordingly, I respectfully concur with the majority’s opinion. 16