The plaintiff contends that a demand was unnecessary in the suit against the maker of the note; or if ne-nessary, that the defect has been cured by the verdict.
The question whether the maker of a promissory note, or acceptor of a bill of exchange, being the original debtors, are unconditionally liable, notwithstanding á *236place of payment has been designated, or whether a demand is to be regarded as a condition precedent, appears to have been extensively agitated,- and have produced great contrariety' of decision in the English Courts.
In the various discussions and decisions in those Courts, material distinctions have been maintained on these and analogous questions, between the liability of original debtors, and such as are collaterally, or secondarily responsible. Distinctions have also been urged, and in some instances allowed, between the situation in this respect, of such as arc bound by designations contained in the body of the note or bill, and such as purport to be thus bound only by the terms of acceptances on
The drawee of a bill has an unquestionable right to accept or refuse his acceptance; consequently he has the same authority that the maker of a note has to superadd qualifications or conditions to.his promise, and the holder may receive or reject such acceptance. It is the acceptance only which creates the presumption of fuuds in the hands of the acceptor. A strict analogy is admitted to exist with regard to the order of responsibility between a negotiable promissory note, after endorsement, and an accepted bill of exchange ; the maker of the one, and the acceptor of the other, (in ordinary cases,) are to be considered the real and primary debtors, generally and universally liable for their own proper debts. In either case, where no other place of payment is appointed, the law designates the residence or place of business of any such debtors, as the proper place of making payment, or any necessary demand; and notwithstanding the promise may be to pay on demand generally, it is held by all authority, and universally conceded, that such original debtor may be sued and held to bail at any place, without any previous demand or notice from the holder of the instrument, though it has been-transferred to the hands of a stranger. In such case, moreover, I apprehend the debtor could not excuse himself from even cost or interest, by pleading and proving his readiness and .willingness to pay at the proper time and place. If this be the law, I can not imagine that injustice or inconvenience would more frequently arise to prim ally debtors, ' where a particular place of payment is designated, under the rule that they shall be generally and universally liable, *237with this qualification only, that, if sued previous to a regular presentment made, they may by way of defence shew, if the fact be so, that they were ready and willing to pay at the time and place appointed,.and thereby avoid costs and damages, and receive a discount sufficient to remunerate them for any loss sustained in the difference of exchange or otherwise, by reason of the failure to make due presentment. Nor can I discover any sufficient authority or reason, for the distinction which some have insisted on, between the liability of acceptors of bills and makers of notes; or as to .the effect of stipulations respecting the place of payment, whether it be inserted in the body of the instruments, or only in the acceptance of bills.
In a recent case before the English House of Lords, which is supposed to be analogous to the present, the question as to the necessity of a demand on the principal debtor, being deliberately considered, a decision was rendered establishing the affirmative of the proposition. This was a case of an accepted bill of exchange, containing a designation of a place of payment in the acceptance only. The acceptor was sued without any averment in the declaration of a previous demand being made at the place appointed for payment; a demurrer being filed to the declaration, the Court of B. R. overruled the same, holding the demand unnecessary. On a writ of error in 1820, the House of Lords, having before them the opinions, seriatim, of the twelve Judges, reversed , the judgement, holding that actual presentment, and an averment to that effect, were essential to the plaintiff’s title to recover. a
Hence, if we are to yield with servile obedience to recent decisions in England, it will be found that, after a long and obstinate contest between the Courts of Kings Bench and Common Pleas, the principles contended for •by the latter, and as above stated, have prevailed by the weight of the House of Lords. Yet I think it will appear, on a careful examination of all the English decisions, that a majority of the professional Judges have held the contrary doctrine. By the decision of the House of Lords alluded to. the opinion of a large majority of the twelve Judges was overruled, and which had been requested and given, it would appear, on the most deliberate consideration in that particular case. The Lords *238were so influenced, I conclude, by the opinions and arguments of Lord Chancellor Eldon and Lord Redesdale, when, as I conceive the weight of the names as well as strength of argument was decidedly in the opposite scale. Without entering into a particular examination of the numerous adjudications involving the principle, and which could only be a repetition of what has been said by the Judges in the case alluded to, and in one in the Supreme Court of New-York, in 1819, I venture to assume the position that a majority of the English Judges oí professional eminence, have held the opinion, that in a proceeding against the principal debtor, (notwithstanding a place of payment is designated in either the body of the instrument, or the acceptance of a bill,) an averment of presentation is unnecessary ; that if such debtor has funds provided for the payment at the appointed place, he can, if sued, by bringing the money into Court and pleading his readiness and willingness to have paid at the proper time and place, and proving the same, make successful defence against the damages and costs of suit j and also avail himself in like manner, of indemnity for any injury sustained by reason of the difference of exchange, &c. at the place designated, and that at which he may be required to pay. In support of this latter doctrine, (among others,) may I think, he found the names of EUenborough, Kenyon, Grose, Mansfield, and of the twelve Judges in the recent case mentioned, Best, Richardson, Garrow, Holroyd, Bayley, Graham, Richards and Chief Justice Abbott, eight in number. Some of these Judges ■ extend the principle much further, and maintain that acceptors of bills and makers of notes, even where a place of payment is expressed,are generally and universally liable, without any restrictions or qualifications ; that place of payment is in no respect material, except with reference to drawers and endorsers, who are only collaterally responsible ; whose liability is contingent, depending on the use of due diligence by the holder to get payment from the principal debtor. It may be true that some of those Judges have since yielded part of the doctrine.
But it is not alone from the number or weight of names that my opinion is formed. I think sufficient contrariety of opinion has existed in the English Courts to leave the question entirely open with us for free and rational consideration, and that the reason and arguments which *239llave and may be offered against the necessity of the de-xnand greatly preponderate. That’the acknowledged principle alone, that if the demand»is'to'be regarded as a condition precedent, the failure to^lnak.6 it at the proper time and place, whether from neglfgenee,. mistake, casualty or whatever misfortune, must create a forfeiture of the debt, is of itself hostile tp the common analogies of law, equity and justice, and conclusive against the doctrine. ’ Where the question can be viewed as between, persons of equal merit, one of which must lose the amount of the debt, as in the case of payee or endorsee against drawer or endorsers; and in proceedings against securities merely, no solid objection can exist against the exercise of rigid principles of decision ; but such rules should not be applied in aid of the machinations or artifice o^ principal debtors, to screen them from their own proper original debts. I would calculate that in nine-tenths of the contracts for payment of money at a particular place, the difference to the debtor as respects the place is but nominal; that in a still greater proportion, such designations of place are made for the benefit of the creditor, or the mutual convenience of both parties ; and that it'would be next to a miracle to find a creditor who would institute a suit at the risk of incurring the cost, losing' the interest, and being delayed in the collection, in preference to making the demand at.the -place appointed, unless he had ascertained that the application would be fruitless. If this calculation fie correct, the objection to requiring the averment and proof of the demand, is well founded in the argument ab inconvenienti. Because it would induce the necessity of making proof in all such cases, and procuring the evidence frequently from a considerable distance; sometimes from the place designated -for payment to distant quarters of the globe, to which debtors have fled, in order to evade the payment; and when too, from common observation and the nature of commerce, the evidence would not be essential to the justice of perhaps, one case in fifty; and in these rare cases, I think it is shewn that ample justice can be otherwise done. These views of the subject are to my mind, more convincing than the contrary arguments on which the recent English decision rests ; the most prominent of which are, that if the demand can be dispensed with, any persons, even the twelye Judges of England, and a gen-*240tip man from Calcutta, after accepting bills payable af t'le,r bankers, and depositing the funds there to meet them, should they travel to a distance, may there be arrested, and found unprepared to pay, and be subjected to various losses and great inconvenience. If under such, circumstances, the money could be immediately extorted from the worthy debtor, without inconvenience, cost to the plaintiff or loss of interest, whereby any considerable inducement would be afforded to the indulgence of such iniquity or vexation, I might concur, in order to prevent it, in the propriety of encountering all the inconvenience, expenditures and dangers to which I have alluded, as likely to arise under the doctrine to which I dissent.
In the decision referred to in the Supreme Court of New-York, in the case of Wolcott against Van Sant-voord, a whicli was an action by the payee against the acceptor of a bill of exchange, drawn payable at a particular place,the question was presented on demurrer to the declaration, for the omission of an averment, that the bill had been presented at the place for payment. The doctrine was examined at considerable iengtlj by Chief Justice Spencer, who delivered the opinion of a majority of the Court, and by Judge Van Ness, who expressed a dissenting opinion. The decision in that case was, on a full review of the authorities, that presentment was not a condition precedent to the plaintiff’s right of action; that in such case the time and place of payment is merely modal, forming no essential part of the contract; that it is incumbent on the defendant, whether the payee was at the place at the time of payment or not, to shew, in his de-fence that he was there ready and willing to pay, and that the payee did not come, &c.; that the consequence of the absence of the payee under such circumstances, unless he make a subsequent special demand, and there be then a refusal, are merely, that he must be content with receiving the sum originally payable, and be himself liable for the cost.
According to my conception, this opinion stands on the most solid basis. Among other arguments advanced in it, is one which has often been used in support of the principle, and to which I have before adverted, that if presentment be a condition precedent to the liability of the acceptor, it must be emphatically so, as regards the drawer; and the result would be, that a failure to present *241at the time, or at the place, would occasion a total loss of the debt; for if it cannot be recovered in an action on the bill, in consequence or an omission to ayer a presentation at the time and place, no other form.- pf action will lie where that proof cannot be made.” Chief Justice Spencer, in the same opinion, used another argument in support of it, which appears to me unanswerable; which is, that 11 the nonattendance of the holder of a bill, at the time and place of payment, can produce-no worse consequences to him than if he had attended,.afid the acceptor had also been present, and tendered the money which the holder had refused to acceptand he adds, “under such a state of facts, what is the legal consequence ? It is perfectly well settled that when a debt or duty exists, such as the payment of a sum of money, a tender of the money, though it be refused, does not extinguish the debt or duty; but it remains obligatory on the party owing the debt or duty.” - . :
The dissenting opinion of Judge Van Ness in that case, contains little more than a passive acquiescence in what he conceived to be the current of decision’in Westminster Hall, and a reference to the English adjudications on the question. He appears, however, to have assumed the fact, that the necessity of presentment 'had been more generally acquiesced in by the Judges of England than is shewn to be true from the opinion of the Judges as given in the late case before the House of Lords, to which I have already referred. He employs one argument, drawn from his own resources, to which he thinks no satisfactory answer has or can be given. It is, as I understand it, that in order to charge an endorser of a note or bill, made payable at a particular place,- a demand at such place is indispensably necessary'; that this necessity is not created or imposed on the holder-by the terms of the endorsement, but by the terms of the note or bill, and hence he concludes that a demand is no less necessary to charge the maker or acceptor than the endorser ; that giving notice to an endorser of the dishonor of negotiable paper, for the purpose of making him answerable, is a condition in law applicable to the endorser only; but that the designation of a place of payment, by the parties themselves, constitutes a condition in fact, and is applicable to all the parties to the paper, and each one may have advantage of it.
In order to test the validity of this distinction between *242the supposed conditions in fact and in law, it is necessary to inquire whether the distinction can be sustained on the principles of legal reasoning; whether there is the same policy and justice in discharging a principal debtor, on the ground of a failure by the holder of a. note to present it for payment at the time and place appointed, that th-re is for exonei-ating a security, for the reason that due diligence has not been used to get the money from the principal. This is the simple question when fairly stated, and it furnishes its own answer. Drawers of bills after acceptance, and endorsers of either notes or bills, are but collaterally responsible. The acceptor of the one, and the maker of the other, have, according to the real fací in most cases, and in legal presumption in all, received the original consideration for which the paper was given ; if the money is not collected from them, it must fall as a clear loss on some one. Any failure to demand payment at the time and place mentioned, tends to increase the responsibility of the drawer or endorser, by rendering payment by the principal less certain. Rules for the government of commerce must be strict and uniform, for the security of innocent persons. Principles governing the liability of collateral debtors, who are virtually securities, should be established and understood. If, by the neglect of the holder of a note or bill to use due diligence in collecting the money of the principal debtor, the security be discharged, and the principal prove insolvent, the loss is only transferred from one to another, who is presumed to be less meritorious, as his negligence may have contributed to produce it.
But is there the same reason for exonerating the principal for a failure to demand payment at the place mentioned, when, if he has provided the funds at the time and place, he may avail himself of it as matter of defence against damages and costs, and satisfy the debt (which is at all times his own,) with the same amount of money ? Had this distinction obtained between conditions in law and in fact, the practice of instituting suits on notes, payable on demand, without presentment, could never have prevailed. I understand the law on these and analogous points, to rest on the general principle, that absolute debtors shall not be discharged on legal quibbles, and that creditors have no inducement to sue when they can make prompt collection without.
jn a ¡ate case Qf the States’ Bank against Smith,a *243the supreme tribunal of the United .States has clearly intimated its opinion on this question. The suit was by the endorsee against the endorser of a note, drawn payable at the Bank of the United States, in the City of Washington. The objection to the;,declaration was. that it did not contain an averment that a demand of payment of the maker of the note was made where it was ihadé payable. Judge Thompson,- in delivering the opinion of the Court, said, “whether, where the suit is against the maker of a promissory note, or the acceptor of a bill of‘exchange, payable at a particular. place, it is necessary to aver a demand of payment at such place, and upon the trial to prove such demands, was a question on which conflicting opinions had been entertained;’in the Courts of Westminster Hall. And after noticing the opinion in the late case, to which I. have referred, of Rowe against Young in the House of Lords, and the contrary opinion reported in the fourth and seventeenth volumes of Johnson’s Reports, a he remarked that this question did not necessarily arise in the case then before the Court, and they did not mean to be understood as expressing any decided opinion upon it, although they were strongly inclined to think that, as against the maker or acceptor of such note or bill, no averment or proof of demand of payment at the place designated, was necessary. But when recourse is had to the endorser of a note, very different considerations arise ; he is not the original and real debtor, but only surety. That case, though materially different from the present, required a full investigation of the doctrine of liability, and after it had, as we may sup» pose, received due consideration, no doubt can exist, as to what would have been the decision of that .Court, had the question been directly involved.
Hence, I entertain the confident opinion that, where the suit is against the original and principal debtor, no averment or proof of a demand is necessary to sustain the action.
On this point, however, some of the Judges necessary to constitute the majority, are not fully satisfied, and decline giving any opinion upon it. But Judge White concurs throughout in the opinion I have expressed. On the other ground relied upon by the defendant in error,, a majority concur, and decide that the verdict cured the defect in the declaration if any existed. Therefore, the judgement below is reversed, and judgement rendered for the plaintiff in this Court.
Rowe v. Young 2 Brodrip and Bingham 165. 6 Sergeant and Lowber 53.
17 John. R. 248.
•» 11 Wheat. 172.
"17'Join,S)