Townsend v. Bush

Smith, J.

I concur in the opinion expressed by my brother Trumbull ; and would add, that the objection made by counsel that the testimony offered was irrelevant rested on the ground that the facts stated, and attempted to be proved, would not, if proved, constitute usury, because the usurious agreement was made between Leffingwell and E. and A. Townsend, who are not parties to this action, and neither the plaintiffs nor defendant had any knowledge of it. The present case, so far as it respects this question, comes within the principle of the case of Fields and French v. Gorham, 4 Day’s Ca. 251. In that case, the court decided, that the defendant might avail himself of a corrupt agreement, of which he had no knowledge at the time of making it. I then thought it necessary to presume an agency, by which the parties to the corrupt agreement might be supposed to act for the parties on the record. But on attending farther to the expressions of the statute, I find them to apply rather to the contract than the parties ; and the only fact made necessary to avoid the contract is, that it be made for the payment of any principal, or money lent upon or for usury, whereupon *270or whereby there shall be reserved or taken more than at the rate of six dollars in hundred(a). In this case, there is no doubt of the fact that the acceptance and indorsement were made to secure the payment of money lent on usury ; and that more than at the rate of six per cent. was taken or reserved by a corrupt agreement.

Swift, J.

The question whether a party to a negotiable instrument, who is divested of his interest, is a competent witness to shew it void in its creation, now comes for the first time before this Court for decision. We are unshackelled by any precedent, and are at liberty to decide it on principle.

In the case of Walton v. Shelley the rule was laid down, that no party who had signed an instrument should ever be permitted to give testimony to invalidate it. Though the court and counsel speak of it as a well known rule, yet it can be found in no prior case.

Lord Mansfield, who had borrowed many valuable principles from the civil law and incorporated them with the common law, attempts to support his decision by what he says is a maxim of the civil law, nemo allegans suam turpitudinem est audiendus ; but there is no such rule to be found in the civil law as applicable to witnesses, and it is the daily practice in common law courts to admit witnesses to testify to facts which shew they have been parties to trespasses, frauds and crimes.

The rule, as laid down in the case of Walton v. Shelley, comprehends instruments not negotiable as well as those which are, and does not require the action to be brought on the instrument; but if the consideration be antecedent notes given up, yet if the witness indorsed such notes, he is incompetent. If this principle should be carried to its full extent. It would furnish an effectual shield for usury, gambling, fraud, and illegal contracts. Let all who are concerned in the transaction, or who have knowledge of it, become parties to the writings made use of, and there will be neither danger nor possibility of detection. So manifest was the mischief of this rule on so broad a basis, that the court of King’s Bench, in the case of Bent v. Baker, in order to avoid it, were obliged to restrict it to negotiable securities, and in the *271case of Jordaine v. Lashbrooke wholly to explode it. So that the case of Walton v. Shelley has been overruled, and is not now law that country.

But as this rule, as far as it relates to negotiable instruments, has been adopted by highly respectable judicial tribunals in our sister states, it may be proper to examine it.

In the case of Walton v. Shelley, Lord Mansfield says, that whenever a man signs these instruments he is always understood to say that to his knowledge there is no legal objection. In the case of Coleman v. Wise and others in the state. New-York, the same principle is recognized. But there is not a precedent, or dictum, to warrant this position. When a man subscribes or indorses an instrument, he contracts certain legal liabilities, and be sets his name to it for no other purpose. He enters into no engagement that he will never testify that the instrument was obtained by fraud or duress ; or was given for a gambling or usurious consideration ; or that he will never make such plea. Every party to an instrument has a right by his plea to shew it was originally void. How then can it be pretended, that by signing it be is understood to say that to his knowledge there is no legal objection to it ? If he contracts such obligation, the true principle would be not to permit him to make a plea or defence repugnant to it. To allow him to plead a fact which shews the instrument void in its creation, and then to refuse him the privilege of proving it, at least by one species of testimony, is a palpable absurdity. The iniquity really consists in the defence itself, and not in the mode of proof ; for certainly it would be as unjust for the defendant to make out his defence by a witness not a party to the instrument as by one that is a party.

In the case of Churchill v. Suter, 4 Mass. Rep. 156. Chief Justice Parsons says, “ If the parties to the usury or the gambling, having received the fruits of their illegal contract, and having given a circulation to the note, can be admitted by their testimony to destroy it, beside the injury to a fair purchaser, the negotiation of paper will be greatly checked, to the no small injury of the public.” This supposes that the indorser combines with the maker of the note to have it transferred to an innocent indorsee, and then by his testimony to avoid it for usury. All will acknowledge such conduct to be highly criminal. But suppose there was originally no *272intent to defraud an innocent indorsee, and while the note is held by an indorsee having knowledge of the usury, for a usurious consideration, the indorser, by an act of bankruptcy, becomes discharged of his interest, it will be agreed then to be perfectly right for him to teslify to the usury to avoid the note. Again, suppose a usurer has taken a most unreasonable advantage of the distress and misfortunes of another, and has compelled him to obtain security by the indorsement of a friend whom he cannot indemnify ; he then puts the note in suit, and there is an indorser who has become disinterested who is knowing to the oppression and usury ; it would clearly be his duty to come forward and testify to the usury for the purpose of destroying the note. Yet by the rule contended for, the indorser in both these cases would not be permitted to testify. Here then, for the purpose of protecting the possible case of the innocent indorsee, ample protection is furnished to the certain case of the usurer and oppressor.

Again, it is said, that persons may be witnesses against their accomplices, because their testimony tends to prevent fraud and injustice, but in this case it tends to encourage it, by enabling parties to enjoy the fruits of it, and throw the consequence on an innocent indorsee.” When accomplices are admitted to testify, the enquiry is not made whether it, will or will not tend to encourage fraud ; for if it should, it was never heard that this would be an objection to their testimony. The object is to punish crimes ; and, as in many cases this cannot be done without the testimony of accomplices, the law admits them.

But to illustrate the subject ; suppose a combination to defraud an innocent indorsee by a usurious note ; the real usurer, to accomplish this plan, does not set his name to the note, and is rendered by releases disinterested ; he would then be a competent witness to prove the usury ; yet his testimony would tend to encourage fraud and injustice as much as if his name had been set to the note. This clearly shews that no such rule as that above mentioned exists.

It is further said, No man shall be admitted to allege his own turpitude, when that allegation will tend to encourage fraud, or illegality. Nor shall the defendant in his defence allege his own wrong.” This is no more than laying down the well-known maxim that no man shall take advantage of his own wrong ; but this has always been applied to the *273parties, and is now for the first time attempted to be applied to witnesses. Though this rule be generally true, yet a statute can controul its operation. Suppose a fraudulent combination to cheat an innocent indorsee by a usurious note, and a party to the fraud and the note is sued thereon ; he may plead the usury to avoid it. Suppose the plantiff replies the fraudulent combination, and that an indorsee is the only person who has knowledge of the fact. Unquestionably, the replication would be bad, and the note void. Here, then, the party is permitted to take advantage of all the turpitude, fraud, and wrong, which the above rule intended to exclude. Suppose an issue should be joined on the fraudulent combination ; a party to the fraud, if not a party to the, note, might, on the principles contended for on the other side, be admitted as a witness ; he would then testify to his own fraud and turpitude. The truth is, the real question in all these cases is, whether the note was given for usury ; and this the party by force of statute may always plead, however base and shameful the transaction may be ; and may prove it by competent witnesses, however deeply they may have been concerned in it. It is in vain to, talk about the turpitude of witnesses and the wrong of the defendant, Ita lex scripta est.

But public policy is the strong argument against the admission of parties to an instrument to invalidate it by their testimony. It is said, the makers and indorsers of negotiable notes may combine to defraud innocent indorsees, which would check and embarrass their negotiation, and prevent their circulation. It is true, such fraudulent combinations can be made, and the indorser of the note may testify to the usury on a suit against the maker, and the note may be avoided in the hands of an innocent holder. It is also true, that a similar fraud may be practised without the aid of an indorser or party to the note for a witness. Suppose two men wicked enough to contrive such a plan, they may make use of some friend expressly for the purpose of being a witness to the usury ; they may indorse the note to some person ignorant of it, and divide the spoils ; and on a suit by the indorsee, such friend may be called as a witness, and prove the usury. Here is precisely the same inconvenience and fraud as in the other case, and the same injury to the circulation of negotiable notes ; yet it cannot be denied *274that in this case the note must be set aside ; for there is no legal objection to the witness, he has no interest, his name is not on the paper. When men are unprincipled enough to practise frauds of this description, I think it is much more probable that it will be done by the intervention of some friend whose name is not on the note than by an indorser. Of course, this rule would furnish very inadequate relief, if such a fraudulent scheme should seriously be adopted.

But if principles of public policy are to govern, they ought to extend to all cases where the injury is the same ; and the rule ought to be, that no defendant should ever be admitted to plead usury, or any other fact, to avoid a negotiable instrument in the hands of an innocent holder. This would do complete and equal justice in all cases. But how unequal is this rule ? It will protect the innocent holder in one case, but not in another under the same circumstances, and within the same reason ; and where it protects the innocent holder, it furnishes the same protection to the usurer ; for the rule in Walton v. Shelley makes no difference whether the holder knew of the usury or not ; and in the case decided in Massachusetts the plantiff on the record was the actual usurer. A rule cannot be right which protects the very usurer the law intended to punish in one case, and in another subjects the innocent holder to a loss which it was the object of this rule to prevent.

But to decide on the policy of this law it is necessary to consider the object of the legislature in making it. It is manifest they intended in the most effectual manner to suppress usury. If they had admitted the principle, that usurious notes should be valid in the hands of innocent holders, they would have furnished a mode by which usury could have been practised with safety, and the law rendered nugatory. To shut the door against all such artifices, the law enacts, that usurious securities shall be absolutely void. It must have been well understood, that instances would occur where innocent indorsees might be prejudiced, and that parties to instruments, when not otherwise disqualified, might, by the general rides of evidence, be admitted to invalidate, by their testimony. It is not probable that the legislature contemplated precisely such a fraud as it is suggested may be practised: it must however have been known that notes might be set aside in the hands of innocent holders, which *275would operate hardly, if not unjustly, in particular cases ; but as a special provision in such cases would have defeated the statute, it must be understood that they intended to declare the notes void in the hands of innocent holders, considering the great object of suppressing usury of more importance than to promote the negotiation and circulation of notes by protecting innocent holders in the few cases where they might be affected. If there is any thing wrong in this business, any thing opposed to public policy, it is in the statute which makes void usurious notes in the hands of innocent holders ; but this is a wrong which no court of law can remedy. It would be strange indeed for them to say, that a statute is not founded on principles of public policy, and then, though they cannot declare it void, yet they will refuse legal evidence to carry it into effect. This is an attempt by indirect means to repeal a statute. The legislature have decided on the policy of the measure ; and it is the duty of courts to give it due operation.

But it has been said by Justice Buller : “ It would be attended with consequences the most injurious to society if these securities might be cut down by the persons passing them ; it is only for two men to conspire together to cheat all the world.” Peake’s Ca, 118. Chief Justice Parsons says : For any man by contriving with another may take up money of him at usurious interest, and give him a negotiable note for security. The promisee may sell it for a valuable consideration, and when the indorsee attempts to recover the money, the promiser and indorser may (at least by releases) be witnesses for each other, and defeat the purchaser of his remedy, and quietly enjoy the money he has paid for the note.” 4 Mass, Rep. 162.

It might be inferred from these observations, that innumerable frauds would be practised, if a party to a negotiable instrument could be a witness to impeach it, and that all confidence in negotiable paper would be destroyed ; yet the truth is, no innocent holder of a note could ever sustain a loss, unless by the bankruptcy of his indorser, or the person from whom he received it ; and he has nothing to do, to guard against a fraud, but to require the same ability in his indorser as prudent men ordinarily require when they give credit. It would also seem from the remarks above quoted, that an opinion was entertained that the parties to a usurious *276note could transfer it without liability to the vendee. Chief justice Parsons says, that they may defeat the party of his remedy, and quietly enjoy the money. It is true, in a suit by the indorsee against the maker of the note, the indorser might be a witness, as he would testify against his interest ; but in a suit by the innocent indorsee against the indorser, the testimony of the promiser would be of no avail, unless the indorsement was void on account of the usury contained in the note ; and that the indorsement was void must have been the opinion of Chief Justice Parsons, otherwise he could not have said that the promiser might be a witness for the indorser, and thereby defeat the remedy of the purchaser. But it is an unquestionable principle, that though the note is void on account of the usury so that no action can be sustained upon it, yet if the promisee indorse it to a bona fide purchaser ignorant of the usury, he is liable on his indorsement ; for this is a new contract not contaminated with usury, and it is binding on him, though the original note is void. If it should pass into the hands of an innocent purchaser without indorsement, if the seller conceal the usury, an action would lie for the fraud. The consequence then is, that men of property can never combine to practise a fraud of this description ; for one or the other would always be responsible in some shape on the sale ; and though they might defeat the purchaser of one remedy, they would be liable, in some other mode ; and consequently, could not enjoy very peaceably the fruits of their fraud, or very successfully cheat all the world. The apprehension, then, of danger from a fraudulent combination of the parties to a negotiable instrument, is founded on a mistaken view of the operation of the law respecting their liabilities.

But what are the frauds that can be practised in such cases ? The only successful mode must be by the instrumentality of indorsers without ability to respond. Let us examine what frauds can be practised by the combination of a poor and a rich man. The poor man must always be the indorser. A man of property would never give his note to a bankrupt without, consideration, on the risk that he will sell it, divide with him the spoils, and swear him clear of the debt. A poor man would hardly loan money or other property to a rich man on a usurious security, for the privilege of selling it, under an obligation to discharge the usurer by *277his testimony, and with a liability of going to gaol himself for another man’s debt. A man of property would have little inducement, unless he received the full sum, to execute a note and run the risk that the promisee should swear him clear of it. The promisee could not be compelled to testify , as it would be against his interest ; and he might die before the trial. A man of property runs a further risk ; if he should practise such a fraud and avoid the note, yet he would be liable to an action in favour of the innocent indorsee whom he had cheated ; and it would always be in the power of his coadjutor in the fraud to betray and subject him. So remote is the prospect of deriving any advantage from a fraud of this description, that I very much question whether an attempt ever has been, or ever will be, made to practise it. The calling on an indorser or other party to testify will always be an after calculation, and will probably occur only where there has been some failure or embarrassments.

What can be the injury to the circulation of negotiable paper to admit the parties to invalidate it by their testimony ? It might prevent prudent men from taking the indorsements of bankrupts. This would not be very injurious to the commercial world. In the case of failure of the parties to the instrument after the indorsment, it might in some cases throw the loss upon a different party ; but this would, in reality, be little more than the common risk of loss by failures, which every man runs in a commercial country where extensive credit is given.

I apprehend, then, there is no solidity in the argument drawn from considerations of public policy.

But let us consider what will be the effect not to admit a party to negotiable paper to invalidate it by his testimony. It will certainly furnish very ample protection to usurers. Conceal the usury from all who are not parties, and there can be no proof in an action founded on the obligation. The only method, then, must he a public or qui tam prosecution. The parties affected by the usury will usually be the witnesses, and can get no redress. They can rarely calculate on such advantages from qui tam prosecutions as to realize any thing more than a gratification of revenge ; and if a usurer has nothing more to restrain him than such prosecutions, the statute against usury will be of little consequence.

*278In practice, it will be found, that this rule has much oftener protected the usurer than innocent indorsees. In the case of Walton v. Shelley, Sutton by whose assignees the action was brought, must have known the usury. The bond was executed in consideration of notes given up. If he had been ignorant of the usury, the bond would have been good. In the case of Churchill v. Suter, the usurer was the plaintiff. In both cases, the usurers were protected.

In the case before us, the rule in Walton v. Shelley would have screened the party charged with the usury, and would have subjected the defendants to pay ; but the rule I contend for would have visited the consequences of the usury upon the usurer. In the suit by Derby Bank against the plaintiffs in New-York, if E. and A. Townsend had not been excluded from testifying on the ground that they were parties to the bill, then the plaintiffs (admitting the usury existed as conceded by the pleadings) would have made good their defence, and the Derby Bank would have had a complete remedy against their indorser, who is stated to be the usurer. But the application of that rule has effectually protected him.

In this case, there would have been no difficulty, had it not been for the failure of E. and A. Townsend. As the plaintiffs indorsed and the defendants accepted as sureties for them, though their indorsement and acceptance were void as they were made to secure the usury to Leffingwell ; yet if they had been subjected to pay, they could clearly have recovered of E. and A. Townsend for money paid by them as sureties ; for in the implied promise to indemnify there was no usury, as they were unacquainted with the nature of the transaction between Leffingwell and them. But now, by their failure, they have lost their remedy ; the application of different rules by the courts in the state of New-York and Connecticut has subjected the plaintiffs to suffer a loss by the bankruptcy of E. and A. Townsend, which the defendant must have sustained, if the bill had not been usurious. This loss, however, is owing to the bankruptcy of E. and A. Townsend, and not to any preconcerted plan to cheat them.

As to the question respecting the usury ; it appears from the facts stated, that on a contract between Leffingwell and E. and A. Townsend, they were to draw a bill on Bush, in favour of E. and A. Townsend, to be accepted and indorsed ; and on this security the money was to be loaned at twelve *279per cent. Here the drawing, accepting and indorsing were to secure the usury to Leffingwell ; and though the acceptors and indorsers were ignorant of the usury, yet this does not prevent the transaction from being usurious ; for it was manifestly a contrivance to evade the statute, and if allowed of, usury might be practised with impunity.

The other Judges concurred.

New trial to be granted.

Tit. 170. s. 2.