I concur fully in the views of my brother Manning.
Campbell J. :The principal question to be decided in this case is, whether the provisions of the charter of Detroit, authorizing the expense of grading and paving streets to be collected against the owners of land abutting on the streets are valid.
These provisions are somewhat different from any which have been passed upon in other states, so far as my observation has gone. The taxes are not distributed through any district, larger or smaller, upon any given ratio, but each lot is chargeable with the whole expense of grading and paving in front of it, and not with an aliquot portion of the grading and paving of a block or district. By § 8 of Ch. 8 of the Revised Charter (L. 1859, p. 132) the Council are authorized “to levy, assess, and collect a tax or assessment on all lots, premises, on subdivisions thereof, sufficient to defray the expenses of grading and paving, graveling, macadamizing, or planking any highway, avenue, street, lane, alley, or crosswalk in said city, in front of or adjacent to such lots, premises, or subdivisions thereof, and of putting curb - stones or “ culverts therein; which tax or assessment shall be credited to the street paving fund.” A similar provision occurs in subdivision 11 of section 21, in chapter 5 {I. 1859, p. 96) which, however, provides further for street crossings not opposite any lot, and for interior public spaces, and allows the Council to. apportion the expenses of improving these at its discretion, and without any rule, upon the adjacent block. Where such paving is at the intersection of Streets adjacent to the point of a triangular block, the Council are authorized to assess against the whole city so much as they deem just.
There is, then, no provision which divides the cost of *289an improvement as a whole upon property or persons by any rule of proportion whatever. Two lots side by side contribute alike when the surface is uniform, but not otherwise. And for those taxes which are distributable through a block, there is no rule of apportionment prescribed, the Council being left to a full discretion.
The first question that arises is, under what division of powers is this exercise of authority to be classed? It was held by the former Supreme Court, in Williams v. The Mayor, &c., of Detroit, 2 Mich. 560, that these expenditures and charges could only be justified under the taxing power, as the imposition of burdens for public purposes. Such is the course of modern decisions; and if it be not an exercise of the taxing power, it is not easy to find any basis for it to rest upon.
Assuming this, if valid at all, to be an exercise of the power of taxation, it is claimed that the law must be governed by one or both of two constitutional provisions, which are as follows:
Art. 14, see. 11. “The Legislature shall provide an uniform rule of taxation, except on property paying specific taxes, and taxes shall be levied on such property as shall be prescribed by law.”
Sec. 12. “ All assessments hereafter authorized shall be on property at its cash value.”
Street improvements have been made the subject of much judicial discussion, and we have been referred to a number of decisions which have a bearing to some extent upon the case before us. The grounds on which they have been attacked or sustained vary, and it may be useful to refer to some of the distinctions.
In New York it has long been customary to apportion the expense of such improvements upon property benefited, in proportion to the amount of benefit in each instance. These benefits are ascertained by some competent board of assessors, who are governed by no arbitra*290ry rule. After fluctuating a long time among various reasons, the Court of Appeals, in The People v. The Mayor, &c., of Brooklyn, 4 Comst. 419, settled down upon the taxing power as the one resorted to. But, inasmuch as it could not be reconciled with the idea of general taxation, because not apportioned within any specific district ascertained by law, a distinction was taken between ordinary taxation, which it was admitted must be uniform, and “ assessments” for local purposes, which it was held were, so far as the district of apportionment was concerned, subject to no rule but legislative discretion. The right to make the distinction was based upon a constitutional provision, which expressly recognized “assessments” in municipal corporations as distinct from taxes.
In Ohio the right was sustained of assessing the improvement on the property benefitted, in Scovill v. Cleveland, 1 O. S. R. 126. And in this case, as well as in Hill v. Higdon, 5 O. S. R. 243, where the whole assessment was divided ratably upon the premises within the range of the improvement by their frontage, the right to make such assessments was based expressly upon a provision in the Constitution borrowed from and identical with the one which was relied on in the case of The People v. The Mayor, &c., of Brooklyn, in New York. In Illinois the assessments have been maintained on the ground of benefits to the property.
There are some cases where the decisions have applied to building or clearing sidewalks, which have .been placed on different grounds. In Bonsall v. Lebanon, 19 Ohio, 418, the assessment by frontage' seems to have been upheld on the ground that the duty was general throughout the town, and therefore the tax uniform. As there was no grading, this would be substantially true. The case, however, is not reasoned fully. In Massachusetts an ordinance for cleaning sidewalks is plainly to be referred to the police power: — Goddard’s case, 16 Pick., 504. And *291it appears that the charges for sidewalks do not all fall upon the property owners, but in part upon the cities, and also that, after requiring one to be built, a second cannot be required, but the public must maintain them. Lowell v. Hadley, 8 Met. 191; Lowell v. French, 6 Cush. 228. In Mayor v. Mayberry, 6 Humph, 371, the right to require sidewalks is based on the right to remove nuisances — a foundation the propriety of which is not very apparent. In Washington v. Nashville, 1 Swan, 177, the right of the public is laid down as absolute.
If the right to make improvements and charge them to property owners is to be based upon the idea of private benefits created, I am entirely clear that no such power is maintainable. No principle is better settled than that private property cannot be taken By the government for private use, and it is equally clear on principle, that taxation in general can only be justifiable for public purposes, affecting large or small localities. The improvement of private property is no part of the objects of government. Unless a work is needed by the public, the public have no right to make it, and if needed, no individual should be compelled to pay except as a proportionate share of a public burden. The very distinction between taxation and the taking of private property is laid down in express terms by the court of New York, in People v. Mayor of Brooklyn, to be, that in the former the individual contributes only his share to a public burden, while in the latter he contributes beyond his share, and is entitled therefore to a compensation for the excess. This distinction is quoted with approbation by the Ohio courts from the language used in New York. I am unable to see how, under such a distinction, that can be regarded as a legitimate exercise of the taxing power which requires more than a proportionate share to be contributed. It does not follow, because the power is not that of taking property for public use, *292that it is the taxing power. It may be neither, and illegal and arbitrary for the very reason that it is neither.
In Louisiana, in the case of Municipality No. 2 v. White, 9 La. Ann. R., 446, under a constitution which contains the same terms with the two sections of our own already cited, it was held that the doctrine of benefits was inadmissable, and that these improvements must be made by a general ad valorem tax within some fixed district. In Sutton’s Heirs v. City of Louisville, 5 Dana, 28, it was held that benefits could not be regarded And in City of Lexington v. McQuillan’s Heirs, 9 Dana, 513, it was held that, within the paving districts created by the statute, the expenses of paving and grading must be ratably distributed upon some uniform system of distribution, and, accordingly, an assessment which charged against one lot the expense of paving and grading in front of it, was held void, because the work should have been apportioned as an entirety. In Weeks v. City of Milwaukee, lately decided by the Supreme Court of Wisconsin, a special assessment was held valid only because the constitution of that state had adopted the precise language used in the New York Constitution, distinguishing between assessments and general taxation; the court declaring expressly that, if that phrase had not been found, they would have had no difficulty in declaring the act void.
When we consider the fluctuations in New York, and also the fact that the benefit system is there an ancient one, reaching' back to the early days of the colony, we may very fairly doubt whether it would have been recognized or created in modern times had it not been found already in existence. No court has yet succeeded in laying down any reasons which vindicate it as in any sense within the taxing power. And in that state it originated under the ordinary application of the right of eminent domain— in which, however, on principle it has but little better foundation.
*293In the case of Williams v. Mayor, &c., of Detroit, 2 Mich. 560, our own Supreme Court, while not deciding the point, intimated very strongly that benefits were not properly to ,be regarded in these cases (p. 572). And the tax in that case was sustained on the express ground that it was apportioned through a district. It was held that the present Constitution did not govern, because the law was prior to it, and therefore the question involved here did not arise.
In examining our ’present Constitution, it will be found that while we have adopted the section of the New York Constitution in which the courts of New York, Ohio and Wisconsin, have found their only authority for discretionary assessments as different from taxes, we have, in adopting it, striken out the very language on which all of those courts rely- for the distinction: — Seo. 13 of art. 15, Const. of 1850. This being so, the argument, so far as it rests upon that foundation, is of no force here, and must be maintained upon other reasons if at all. But without this clause, it is not sustained upon most of the authorities cited.
Assuming, however, that benefits may be properly regarded, the law before us contains no provision for ascertaining them. The Legislature certainly cannot determine that any lot is benefitted by the precise value of an improvement in front of it, and that no other lot is benefitted at all. In New York, in the case cited, the benefits were ascertained as a matter requiring the use of judgment and discretion by a competent board or- officer, very much as property is assessed in other cases. — - So it was also in Scoville v. Cleveland. Under our statute, the matter is entirely arbitrary, and there is no uniformity whatever. The city may grade and pave in front of a single lot at a time, and the cost against one fifty-foot lot may be double that against the next one, if the ground is uneven. The law does not define what is meant *294by “adjacent” property, or how far it shall be allowed to be reached. The law does not provide how large a lot or block shall be, nor determine any limit of extent as coming within a taxing lien. A lot fifty feet wide by one hundred deep may stand beside a tract three miles deep, as this very case exemplifies, and the law does not provide any means of distinguishing between them. A lien for fifty dollars may in one case be confined to a lot of small value, and in the other encumber the title of a large estate. And if a parcel of land extend on a paved street with a depth of but a few feet, the law points out no way of holding the rest of the block, which must necessarily be benefited in some degree at least by the improvement. This law cannot, upon the most liberal construction, be held to rest upon the basis of compelling the parties or premises benefited to bear the burden.
The principle of uniformity, which our Constitution requires, is really no new requirement, but in some way enters into every proper tax, and is recognized in all the decisions upon assessments as well as taxes, as essential to the validity of all these charges. And where it is sought to require each party benefited to contribute according to the amount of his benefit, the ratio is intelligible and just, if he should be compelled to pay on the basis of private benefits at all.
And there is no restriction iipon the Legislature in defining the size of districts. Our road districts are instances of this. And if a charge is made on a uniform rule within any prescribed district, there can be no very good reason for objecting to it because the district is large or small, if the rest of the city is made to bear its own local burdens on a substantially similar basis. But single lots, if all are made chargeable without any reference to size or extent, are not .districts, nor is there any room for apportionment or uniformity. The very term taxation, whether used in a con-constitution or elsewhere, signifies a proportioned charge, *295upon some uniform standard, either of value or something else, which will afford a means of comparison.
I can see no reason why the clause of our Constitution requiring taxes to be by uniform rules does not apply to this case. Neither do I myself perceive why the rule of valuation should not be held to be intended to apply, as it certainly does apply literally, to the same thing. If there were any reason why a valuation tax for local purposes would not operate as justly 'as any other, there might be reason for endeavoring to find another construction. But the whole controversy upon this subject has shown that the valuation rule has advantages in most eases over any other and in assessing benefits it is undoubtedly followed to a considerable extent. The only decision which we find any where, upon a constitution requiring taxes to be upon a valuation, applies the requirement to these assessments:— Municipality No. 2 v. White, 9 La. Ann. R., above cited. It affords a nearer approach to uniformity than any other, and it is this very quality that has caused its adoption for general taxation, and the power of exemption affords very full room for correcting its defects, where certain classes of property or improvements should be spared, in whole or in part.
So far as the Constitution is supposed to confer or au thorize the conferring of powers of local legislation and management upon cities and counties, those powers must be construed and measured in view of the whole instrument.— There are many clauses which limit and control this authority. It cannot be supposed that the Legislature is permitted to create in otu’ midst a number of irresponsible and unchecked municipalities, whose citizens are to be withdrawn from the protection of the general laws of the land. Whatever powers can be granted to cities, they certainly can not exceed those to be exercised by the Legislature that creates them.
I agree entirely with the views expressed by my *296brother Christiancy in the reasoning by which he has demonstrated the illegal character of this spurious system of charges on property and its owners. And irrespective of the views I have expressed, as my individual opinion, upon benefits as a foundation for assessments, and upon the express clauses of the Constitution referred to, I concur with him that the taxing power, in whatever shape it is exercised, must be exercised with some regard to a distribution of burdens, and not arbitrarily. For the reasons I have given, and also for those which he has elaborated, I concur with him in regarding the provisions of the charter in question as invalid.
Christiancy J.:The eighth section of chapter eight of the revised charter of the city of Detroit (L. of 185V, p. 132) purports to give the Common Council power to “levy, assess, and collect a tax or assessment on all lots, premises, or subdivisions thereof, sufficient to defray the expenses of grading and paving any street, lane, alley, &c., in front of, or adjacent to, such lots, premises, or subdivisions thereof, and of putting curb-stones and culverts therein;” the term “ adjacent” being here obviously used in reference to alleys and not to streets.
By the fourteenth section of the ninth chapter, such tax or assessment is made a lien upon the premises till paid, and the collector is also authorized to ' collect the same of the person taxed, by distress and sale of his goods and chattels.
By reference to the eleventh subdivision of the twenty-first section of chapter five (L. of 185V, p. 96), in connection with the eighth section of chapter eight, above referred to, it is evident that there is to be no apportionment of the expenses among the owners of the various lots along the street to be paved, but the whole expense of the grading and paving in front of any particular lot, *297to the centre of the street (whatever may be its amount, and without any reference to the amount paid by any other lot), is imposed, in gross, upon the lot.
Under these provisions, and without the assent of complainant, the Council levied what the charter assumes to call “ a tax or assessment, on the lands of the complainant,” for the grading and paving of Fort street, which passes through the complainant’s farm, to the full amount of the expense of such grading and paving; and have issued their warrant to the collector for the collection of the amount (between four and five thousand dollars) from the goods and chattels of the complainant. The 'complainant has not goods and chattels sufficient to pay the amount.
Have the Legislature, in authorizing this mode of raising the funds for this improvement, exceeded their constitutional power ? This is the only question in the cause; for, if the act is, in this respect, unconstitutional, the case, I think, sufficiently shows a constitutional right of the complainant about to be violated in the proceeding complained of, not merely by the seizure and sale of his goods and chattels, but by casting a cloud upon the title of his real estate.
I shall not here enter upon the discussion of the general nature of state constitutions and legislative power: but, for my own views of these general, principles, I shall here only refer to my opinion given in'the case of /Sears v. Cotterell, 5 Mich. 256. To the views there expressed I still adhere.
I am not, therefore, to inquire whether the power in question has been grauted, but whether it has been prohibited, by [the Constitution ; and, unless I shall be able clearly to see that some certain provision of the Constitution has been violated, I shall be compelled to uphold the constitutionality of the law, whatever I may think of its expediency.
If, as is claimed by the complainant, this be such “tax *298or assessment” as is contemplated by the eleventh and twelfth sections of the fourteenth article of the Constitution, it is clearly void, as it is neither assessed by any uniform rale, nor on property at its cash value. These sections are as follows:
“Sec. 11. The Legislature shall provide an uniform rule of taxation, except on property paying specific taxes; and taxes shall be levied on such property as shall be prescribed by law.
“Sec. 12. All assessments hereafter authorized shall be on property at its cash value.”
I do not think these provisions were intended to apply to' taxes or assessments for such local improvements in cities and villages. It is certain that these, provisions have relation to taxation for raising the general revenue for state, county, and township (and probably city) purposes, whether they have any greater extent or not. The “assessments” mentioned in the twelfth section can not be construed in the sense of a special tax, or sum of money raised for local purposes, as contra - distinguished from general taxes, but in the sense of ascertaining the value of property, as a prerequisite to the imposition of a tax. If this be not so, then there is nothing in the Constitution which requires the assessment of general taxes to be “on property at its cash value.”
The distinction between general taxes and special burdens or assessments, imposed for local purposes, has always been well understood in this state, and was generally recognized in all those states whose institutions and judicial decisions had most influence here at the time of the adoption of the ^Constitution; and such local assessments were not then, and never have been, understood here as referred to by the general provisions of statutes in reference to “taxes.” This is sufficiently evident from the authorities cited by the defendant’s counsel. Besides, if these local assessments are within these sections, then no pro*299porty paying “specific taxes,” such as that held by railroad companies in the city of Detroit, would be liable to any assessments for streets or sidewalks; this would be contrary to the universal understanding. See also Canal Trustees v. Chicago, 12 Ill. 405; Ottowa v. Trustees, &c., 20 Ill. 423 ; Nassau street, 11 Johns. 77.
But the next section (13) of the same article of the Constitution, requires the Legislature to “ provide for an equalization, by a state board, once in five years, of assessments on on all taxable property, except that paying specific taxes.” Surely this provision, directly connected with those in the 11th and 12th sections, can have no reference to local assessments for paving, but only to such assessments as furnish the basis of the ordinary annual taxes. The Constitution of Louisiana, under which the case of Municipality No. 2 v. White was decided, has no such provision in reference to equalization, and, though similar to, is not identical with ours in reference to taxation and assessment.
There being- nojother limitation in the Constitution upon the taxing power of the Legislature than those already noticed, it follows that if the mode of raising the expenses of grading and paving, provided by this charter, can, in any just sense, be considered a tax or an assessment, or if, independent of the Constitution, it could be considered as an exercise of the power of taxation, it is free from all constitutional objection.
If an exercise of the power of taxation, then, though it does take private property for a public use, it is not without compensation; as the owner is always supposed to receive compensation in the benefits conferred by government in the proper application of the tax. And if the provision of the Constitution, against taking private property for public use without compensation, is to be construed to apply to any case in which the property is not taken in kind, to be itself used by the public, then the presumption of compensation, in the mode just men*300tioned, must be a conclusive one in all cases where the property is taken in payment of a tax; or no valid tax could ever be imposed or collected; since human wisdom has never devised, and never can devise, any system of' taxation which will not produce great inequalities, both in the apportionment of the tax and in the benefit to arise from its expenditure. And however equally imposed, and though with express reference to benefit, there will yet be individual cases where the person taxed will, in fact, be injured, rather than benefited, by the expenditure.
But if the mode of raising the money in the case before us is not an' exercise of the power of taxation, then it may become a very grave question whether it does not fall within the prohibition of the ninth and fifteenth sections of article fifteen of the Constitution, against taking private property for public use for improvements in cities and villages without compensation.
The early cases in New York, which have been followed in many other states, and which held that assessments for streets and other local purposes were not a tax, because they were a benefit rather than a burden, can have little weight in determining whether the provisions of the charter here in question are an exercise of the taxing power. The power to exact money or property from individuals, for a public improvement, must rest upon the public necessity and the public convenience, not upon the private benefit to the individual. The latter is but an incident which grows out of the exercise of the power, and may and does furnish a very proper, and, in my opinion, the most equitable, rule for apportioning the public burden among individuals. But the statute before us does not profess to adopt the principle of private benefits in any respect whatever, though it may not be wholly inconsistent with it; since, probably, as a general rule, the land in front of which the improvements are made will be more benefited than those more remote; yet this is not so necessarily the result that the court can *301take judicial notice that it must he a benefit in all cases. And it is easy to conceive cases in which it would be an injury instead of a benefit. And if the private benefit had been made the basis of apportionment, the question whether benefit or not, and the amount of such benefit, would be questions of fact, to be ascertained in each individual case by some board or tribunal appropriately constituted for that purpose.
The Legislature is not competent to ascertain and adjudicate upon facts in individual cases, so as to bind private rights. This is not one of the functions of legislative power. See Parmlee v. Thompson, 7 Hill, 80, and note.
It is very certain that this is not a specific tax within the meaning of that term in the Constitution. And, with the single exception of specific taxes, the terms tax and assessment, both, I think, when applied to property, and especially to lands, always include the idea of some ratio or rule of apportionment; so that, of the whole sum to be raised, the part paid by one piece of property shall bear-some known relation to, or be affected by, that paid by another. Thus: If one hundred dollars are to be raised from tracts A, B, and C, the amount paid by A will reduce, by so much, that to be paid by B and C, and so of the others.
In the ease of specific taxes, as w.ell as duties and imposts, though the amount paid by one is not affected by that paid by another, yet there is a known and fixed relation of one to the other, a uniform rate by which it is imposed upon the whole species or class of property or persons to which the specific tax applies; and this is so of duties and imposts, whether specific or ad valorem. To compel individuals to contribute money or property to the use of the public without reference to any common ratio, and without requiring the sum paid by one piece or kind of property, or by one person, to bear any relation whatever to that paid by another, is, it seems to me, to levy a forced contribution, not a tax, duty or impost, within *302the sense of these terms as applied to the exercise of powers by any enlightened or responsible government.
In the case before us there is no ratio, relation or common rule, or standard of apportionment, whatever. Nor can there be, unless we can judicially assume that there is absolute uniformity of soil and surface throughout the district to be improved, and even then the expense must often vary from other causes. The amount paid by one is neither increased nor diminished by that paid by another, nor is there any uniform rate, as in the case of specific taxes, duties and imposts. This is called the assessment of a tax; but there is nothing for assessors to do. What is actually done, and all that can be done, is to estimate the expenses of the improvement to be made in front of a particular lot, to impose that amount upon the lot and the owner, and to issue a warrant for its collection. This is the whole process of what Í3 called “ levying and assessing a tax -or assessment.” I can not, I confess, see anything in this process in the nature of an assessment, or the assessment of a tax; and, if not so in fact, the names by which the statxite may have designated the process can not make it so.
This mode of imposing the burden would certainly seem to rest entirely upon the idea of a duty on the part of the owner to grade and pave the street in front of his lot; a duty which, it would seem, was supposed to grow out of' the ownership; and in this respect it would seem to resemble a police regulation. And yet this idea of duty is not carried out; as the owner is not allowed to make the improvement for himself. But this supposed duty is made the basis of another duty, that of paying the city for making the improvement for him, which they will not permit him to make for himself, and of course without any default on his part in the performance of his duty. This case, then, differs essentially, if not entirely, from the cases in the state Of New York, and many other states which have followed. *303her example, where street assessments are, by statute, required to be made in proportion to the benefits to be derived from the improvement. In all those cases there will be found to have been a board of assessors, or some other officer or board, whose official duty it was to ascertain the relative amount of those benefits to each lot or tract along which the improvement extended, or within some other area or district; and the tax was imposed according to those benefits, thus ascertained. The whole sum to be raised, within the area or district to be taxed, constituted a common burden within such area or district. There was thus a clear principle for the apportionment of a public or common burden. The amount paid by one was affected by the amount paid by another. This, then, was essentially in the nature of a tax, and may well be held to be an exercise of the power of taxation, as shown by the very able opinion of Judge Ruggles, in People v. Mayor of Brooklyn, 4 Comst. 419. This case has been almost universally followed in every state where a similar mode of street assessments has been adopted. Every case of a street assessment cited by the counsel of the defendants, involves a similar principle. I do not here speak of sidewalks, but of streets. Even the case of Hill v. Higdon, 5 O. S. R. 243, where the tax was assessed at a uniform rate per foot front, was under a law requiring the assessment to be in proportion to the benefit; and the irresistible inference is, that in that particular ease the assessors had ascertained that the benefit would be in proportion to the extent of frontage. But if the act had required the assessment to be in proportion to the frontage, this would have been an intelligible basis of apportionment. And a similar remark may perhaps be made upon the case of Williams v. Mayor of Detroit, 2 Mich. 560, where the charter authorized the Council to raise the funds substantially in the mode prescribed by the present charter, “or otherwise as they may direct y” and the assessment was made in proportion to the frontage: —See pp. 568 and 571. But *304in the case before ns the sum demanded is no proportion of a common burden. There is no common burden to be apportioned.
With the exception of the case of Weeks v. City of Milwaukee, which rests upon a peculiar feature of their Constitution not found in ours, and where the absence of a rule of apportionment seems to have been overlooked, I have met with but one reported case in which it has been directly-held that the duty and the whole expense of making a street improvement in front of the owner’s property could be imposed upon the owner without reference to any ratio or rule of apportionment; and that is State v. Dean, 3 Zab. 335 ; and a similar principle may perhaps be involved in State v. Mayor of Jersey City, 4 Zab. 662, though in the latter case the statute (which I have not been able to find) seems to have required the assessment to be made upon the property benefited — the case does not say in proportion to the benefit. In State v. Dean, the doctrine was carried to such an extent, as in my view, to detract much from the authority of the case, since — if I rightly understand the case — it holds that, where the owner lays out and dedicates a street to the public, the public have a right before, and as a condition precedent to, acceptance, to compel the owner to defray the expense of putting it 'in order fit for use as a street. The principle upon which this can be done I have not been able to discover.
The distinction between the power of taxation and that of taking private property by right of eminent domain has, perhaps, no where been laid down with more clearness and precision than by Judge Buggies, in the case of The People v. Mayor of Brooklyn, above cited. “ Taxation,” he says, “ exacts money or services from individuals, as and for their respective shares of contribution to any public burthen.
“ Private property, taken for public use, by right of eminent domain, is taken, not as the owner’s share of contribution to a public burthen, but as so much beyond his share.
*305“Special compensation is, therefore, to be made in the latter case, because the government is a debtor for the property so taken ; but not in the former, because the payment of taxes is a duty, and creates no oblig'ation to repay, otherwise than in the proper application of the tax.
“ Taxation operates upon a community, or upon a class of persons in a community, and by some rule of apportionment.
“The exercise of the right of eminent domain operates upon an individual, and without reference to the amount or value exacted from any other individual or class of individuals.”
In the general correctness of these distinctions I fully concur. Tested by these rules, the imposition of the burden in the case before us is not an exercise of the power of taxation, and the taking of property which the charter authorizes, unless it can be justified under a police power, is, within the rules here laid down, an attempt to exercise the right of eminent domain without regard to the constitutional restrictions upon that right.
It creates no public or common burden, but imposes a private individual burden for a public purpose.
It does not operate upon a community or class of persons or property by any rule of apportionment. There is no apportionment, and nothing to he apportioned. The amount required for the improvement in front of a lot is imposed as an entirety upon such lot, without any reference to the sum imposed upon any other lot. It operates upon an individual, and upon each distinct tract, without reference to the amount or value exacted from any other individual or tract, or class of individuals. If the act had been confined to the arbitrary exaction of a specified sum from a single individual by name, it would have involved the same principle of imposing the burden. If the Legislature have arbitrarily exacted one hundred dollars from A, will it render the act any the less objectionable because, without any *306reference to the sum exacted from A, they have with equal or still greater caprice required one hundred and fifty from B?
The grading and paving of the street is for the public use and benefit; the owner is entitled to no peculiar use of the street not common to the public, and though he may derive a greater benefit generally (which may be considered in apportioning a tax), yet it is the public use only which can justify the imposition of the burden, even as a tax. This law takes the property of the lot owner for this public use, not directly, it is true, but to be converted into money and applied to this public use. If taken under the taxing-power, he is presumed to receive compensation in the expenditure of the tax; but if not so taken, there is no such presumption.
The Constitution, under the head of Colorations, article 15, section 9, provides, “The property of no person shall be taken by any corporation for public use, without compensation being first made or secured, in such mañuelas may be prescribed by law.” Section 15 of the same article, “^Private property shall not be taken for public improvements in cities and villages without the consent of the owner, unless compensation therefor shall first be determined by a jury of freeholders, and actually paid or secured in the manner jtrovided by law.”
It is true these provisions do not refer to a taking of property in payment of a tax, or a burden imposed under the taxing power, nor in payment of a debt or other duty to the public. It is doubtless true also, that these prohibitions are primarily aimed against a direct taking-of property, to be used in kind by the public; though the language itself makes no such distinction, and the reason why it is properly so construed is, because all the recognized legal modes of indirect taking include the idea of compensation. This is the only reason for the construction. The maxim, therefore, applies to these prohibi*307tions, in its full force, that, what cannot he done directly shall not be done indirectly. And, where indirect means are employed to accomplish what is forbidden to be done directly, the law rejects these indirect means, as of no validity, and treats the case as if the same end were obtained by direct means. If this were not so, the whole effect of the prohibition might, in all cases, be evaded with impunity by the simple device of making the process consist of two steps instead of one. And while the Legislature could not authorize the taking- of A’s land for a public park, they might, under the specious name of a tax or assessment, raise by the sale of A’s land the whole sum necessary to pay B for his land, to be taken for that purpose; and from the sale of B’s land fronting on the park, the whole expense of improving it and erecting a city hall upon it. And though they can not take and use your property directly, they may sell it, and use the money to purchase other property, of the same or any other description.
It is true that liability to abuse is not always, of itself, strong evidence of the non-existence of.a power, since all legislative and all human power is liable to abuse. But the fact, that a proposed rule of construction would remove all constitutional restraint, is very strong evidence that the rule must be erroneous.
If it be claimed that the constitutional prohibitions in question do not apply to this mode of taking private property, because the constitutional mode of ascertaining the compensation is not applicable to such a case, the reply is, that this very fact may be very strong evidence that the taking is in violation of these prohibitions; since the property is taken in a mode not authorized by them, and it is forbidden to be taken in any other mode.
The Supreme Court of Ohio, in Scovill v. Cleveland, 1 O. S. R. 126, admit that where the proceeding, under the name of a tax or assessment, is merely colorable, *308and is really and substantially an exercise of the right of eminent domain, it should be treated as the latter, and held void. The same idea is taken for granted by the court, in People v. The Mayor of Brooklyn, above cited. The constitutions of Ohio and New York are substantially the same as ours, so far as respects "this question.
But it may be said that, under a valid law, providing for the assessment of a tax upon any ordinary rule of apportionment, cases may occur where the rule of apportionment could not practically operate, and where the burden imposed upon one individual or tract would have no relation to that paid by another — that, under the acknowledged power of the Legislature to establish, or to authorize the Council to establish, assessment districts for local purposes, it may happen that the whole property in the district may consist of a single tract, and belong to the same person. This may be true, as a legal possibility, though it may be doubted whether it would be likely to occur in fact.
But as no such point is involved here, I do not propose to give a definite opinion upon a hypothetical case. The case supposed may, however, show the propriety of fixing some legislative minimum for assessment districts.— But should the Council, acting in good faith with reference to the public necessities, under a law authorizing a tax by some rule of apportionment, fix such district of reasonable extent, the power of taxation, I apprehend, would not be defeated by the accident of ownership." If the law fixes the rule of apportionment for all the property within the district, it could not probably make any difference who or how many might happen to own it; otherwise a valid rule might be defeated by the act of an individual. But the question is very u different when the law provides no rule of apportionment, and applies no principle of taxation, within any district, as in the case before us.
*309An accidental result may happen under any system or rule of law; but it does not follow that the Legislature may adopt the accident for the rule, because they had power to adopt the rule from which the accident resulted. Such a mode of reasoning would nullify every provision in the Constitution.
It only remains to inquire whether this mode of raising the expense of a public improvement can properly be held to fall within the class of police powers — a class of powers not generally supposed to come within constitutional provisions against taking private property for public use.
In Massachusetts substantially the same mode of imposing the burden for constructing sidewalks has been adopted as that provided for paving streets in the city of Detroit: — City of Boston v. Shaw, 1 Met. 137; City of Lowell v. Hadley, 8 Met. 180; Lowell v. French, 6 Cush. 223. These cases will be found to rest mainly and professedly upon the authority of Goddard's Case, 16 Pick. 504. This was an ordinance of the city of Boston requiring the owners and occupants of houses bordering on streets, to clear the snow from the sidewalks adjoining their respective houses and lands, and imposing a penalty for a neglect of this duty. This was expressly, and I think very properly, held to be a police regulation, and sustained on that ground; and the reasoning of the very able judge who gave the opinion of the court, shows that the decision was based substantially upon the principle of regulating the use of private property, or property partaking of the character both of public and private, in a manner deemed necessary to the public safety and convenience; which is, I think, the most prominent and distinctive feature of a police regulation. And the course of reasoning adopted is not applicable, in any appreciable degree, to the grading and paving of streets. The adjoining owner is recognized as having “ a peculiar interest in *310and benefit from tlie sidewalk, distinct from that Avhich he enjoys in common Avith the rest of the community [and consequently from that which he enjoys in the street]. He has this interest and benefit often in accommodating his cellar door and steps, a passage for fuel, and the passage to and from his own house to the street. To some purposes, therefore, it is denominated his sidewalk. For his own accommodation he would have an interest in cleaning the snow from his own door.”
Noav, the only feature in this case which can make it an authority for imposing- upon the owner of a lot the whole expense of constructing a sidewalk in front of it is, I think, this “peculiar interest,” or qualified property, which a man is supposed to have in the sideAvalk; and this does not extend, in any appreciable degree, to the street itself. Accordingly, while a similar mode has been quite generally adopted in imposing the burden of building sidewalks — see (in addition to the cases above cited from Massachusetts) Bonsal v. Mayor of Lebanon, 19 Ohio, 418; Mayor v. Mayberry, 6 Humph. 368; Washington v. Mayor of Nashville, 1 Swan, 177; Paxon v. Sweet, 1 Green, (N.J.) 196 — it seems much less generally applied to streets. And, in Ohio, Tennessee, and NeAV Jersey, this principle, as applied to sidewalks, is carried out in the manner usually adopted for carrying into effect police powers; by imposing upon the owner the duty of constructing the walk himself, and, upon his default in the performance of the duty, by doing the work for him, and imposing upon him the expense as a penalty for a breach of duty, which penalty is generally collected by suit.
It is true the courts do not, in all the cases just cited, expressly term this a police regulation; but the reasoning, I think, can only be justified on this ground. And in Mayor v. Mayberry, which seems to be the leading case in Tennessee, it is expressly declared not to be a tax, and the decision is professedly based upon the authority *311of Goddard’s case, above cited. The view taken in Bonsal v. Mayor of Lebanon, above cited, is substantially the same.
In some of these cases, it is true — especially Washington v. Mayor of Nashville, and Paxton v. Sweet — the general language of the court, arguendo, is broad enough to sustain the power in question in the case before us. But the language must be rmderstood secundum subjectam materiam, and can not be considered judicial authority beyond.
There would be great hazard in the attempt to bring within the field of police regulations cases not already recognized as such, and not, by any necessity, required to be so recognized. A power once admitted as a police power is hardly susceptible of accurate definition, and difficult to be restrained within any prescribed limits; and ought therefore, as far as possible, to be confined to the doing of those things which are necessary to the public welfare, and which, yet, can not be done at all, or without serious inconvenience, under specific recognized powers which are suscej>tible of restraint within known and defined limits.
But the raising of money for the grading and paving of streets, is not one of those public necessities which can not be conveniently met by the well - recognized power of taxation. The exigency falls directly within the appropriate exercise of this power. And to ignore this well-understood and defined power, and resort to a police power to accomplish the same end, would be like passing from terra firma into void space, where no sensible object exists by which to guide our course.
I am therefore unwillingly brought to the conclusion that the provisions of the charter here in question are in direct conflict with the ninth and fifteenth sections of the fifteenth article of the Constitution. I am unwillingly brought to this conclusion, because some months of delay must occur *312before the defect can be cured by legislation, and contractors may suffer, and necessary public improvements may be checked, during the interval. Besides, I think it quite probable — though we have no evidence of the fact — that owing to the peculiar circumstances óf the property affected, and as the result of accident rather than the system, the sum imposed upon the complainant’s property may not greatly, if at all, exceed the amount which might have been assessed under a legitimate system of taxation, which the Legislature had the power to adopt. But these considerations can have no weight in determining the question of power.