Adams & Westlake Co. v. Deyette

Kellam, J.

(dissenting). I feel compelled to dissent from the conclusions of the court upon the main propositions discussed in the foregoing opinion. It is always a matter of interest to the general student of the law to know the views of eminent text writers upon any legal question, but it must always be a matter of more particular interest to a court to know what its own legislature has made and established as the law of that jurisdiction; and so, when I find that the statute law of this state expressly allows a corporation to purchase shares of its own stock (Comp. Laws, Sec. 2917), I conclude that the wisdom or unwisdom of such policy is not a question for discussion or settlement by the courts of this state. At all events, it is gratifying to know that, however bad the law may be, or however vicious its policy, it is not original with a Dakota legislature. It is the law of many of the states. It was broadly declared as general rule of law in the Field Commission Code; and in Bank v. Bruce, 17 N. Y. 507, Judge Selden said, ‘ ‘I am not aware of any common-law principle which forbids it.” Be that as it may, our statute says that it may be done, and it does not seem to me allowable for this court to say that what the statute authorizes is contrary to the policy of the law.

I think, too, that the argument of the opinion is predicated almost entirely upon assumed premises, to wit, that the corporation was insolvent, or in contemplation of insolvency, when it borrowed the money with which to buy this stock. The only finding is that it was insolvent when it confessed these judgments nearly four months afterwards. For aught that appears in the record, its then insolvency may have resulted from causes entirely occurring after the money was so borrowed, and that at the time of the loan both borrower and lender may not only have thought, but known, that it was in a solvent and prosperous condition, and even that it then had ‘surplus profits” equal to the amount used in the purchase of this stock. I do not suppose the fact that the corporation *130borrowed money would prove that it did not at the time of such borrowing have surplus profits, for such profits would not necessarily be in money on hand. A condition or relation shown to exist will be presumed to continue, but the presumption does not also reach backward. I think, therefore, that there is no warrant in the findings for treating the corporation as insolvent when the loan was made, but that the same is purely an assumption.

If this case is rightly decided upon the facts found, it is because a note given by a perfectly solvent corporation, for money borrowed to purchase shares of its stock, the purpose being known to the lender, is invalid and unenforceable unless the subsequent purchase of such stock is made by the corporation under the conditions named in the statute, or else that such note, good when made, becomes invalid by the subsequent insolvency of the corporation. The last proposition seems utterly indefensible. It cannot be that a note, valid when made, becomes invalid by a change in the financial condition of its maker. If it is the intention of the court to rest its decision upon the first proposition, I am unable to understand how it can so confidently reach the conclusion it announces, without at least some consideration of the question whether Deyette’s knowledge of the purpose for which the money was borrowed would invalidate his note. There is certainly a very respectable, not to say formidable, line of authorities firmly holding that money loaned to a corporation for a confessedly ultra vires purpose is recoverable, although the lender knew that the money was to be so used. Some of these cases are collected in 27 Am. & Eng. Enc. Law, under head of “Ultra Vires.” Ex parte Credit Foncier, 7 Ch. App. 161, would seem from the general statement of facts, to be much like the case now in hand. Company A loaned money to Company B. ‘Company B. had authority to borrow money, but not to buy up their own shares. Both companies were subsequently wound up. It was jheld that Copipany B was not affected by notice of any illegal!? *131ty in the purpose to which the money borrowed was to be applied, and that it was consequently entitled to prove against the estate oí Company A under the winding up.” As this question is not discussed in the majority opinion, I only refer to it here so that I may not be understood as assenting to the view which the court seems to have adopted without discussion.

In determining the rights of the parties respectively upon the facts found in this case, the first question would seem to be, did the transaction of January 20th create a legal and enforceable claim in favor of Deyette against the hardware company for the repayment of the money so loaned. Respondent claims and this court holds, that it did not, because the money was advanced knowing it was to be used for an illegal purpose, to wit, the purchase by the company of the Trask stock. The purchase of the stock, however, was not necessarily illegal. It would be legal if the stockholders all consented in writing. Comp. Laws, Sec. 2917. It is. found that such consent was not obtained. It is not found that Deyette knew or had notice that it was not obtained. Was it required of him, in order to make his loan valid, to know or see to it that the purchase of the stock was made under such conditions as would make it a permissible and legal transaction? The money was loaned to accomplish a purpose that might be legal or it might be illegal, depending -upon conditions not connected with the loaning of the money, but with the purchase of the stock. There are many cases holding that contracts made to actively aid in the violation of the law are unenforceable, and that money advanced and used for such a purpose cannot be recovered. The cases go upon the ground of guilty knowledge upon the part of the lender, making him in pari delicto with the immediate perpetrator of the wrong. But here there was no guilty knowledge on the part of Deyette, unless the law imputes it from the facts proved. It was not found that he loaned the pionpy for $ie purpose pf, py knowing th^t it ^as to be *132used for, buying bis stock under unlawful conditions. All that the proved facts show upon this point is that he loaned the money to the company for the purpose of, and to be used in, buying this stock, and that he did not know that the consent of the stockholders had been or would be obtained, so as to make the purchase permissible, and such use of the money loaned lawful. Respondent contends and our former opinion favors the thought, that as, under ordinary conditions and generally, the purchase of the stock would be in violation of the law, it was incumbent on Deyette to know that the conditions existed which would make the purchase allowable under the law. I think this is going too far. It is, in effect, presuming guilt from facts which are entirely consistent with innocence. The law punishes the lender by denying to him the right to enforce repayment, because he has knowingly participated in and willingly aided the violation of the law. If, as is found in this case, this money was borrowed for the purpose of buying this stock, the borrowing preceded the actual purchase, and, if any presumption is charged against or credited to Deyette, it ought to be that the company would proceed in a lawful manner in effecting the purchase. Suppose the traffic in intoxicating liquors is generally prohibited by law, and is only legal when the party so trafficking has first obtained a license therefor. A. applies to a bank for a loan of money to enable him to put in a stock of liquor for sale, and the bank makes the loan knowing the money is to be used for that purpose, is it therefore to be charged with the presumption that A. intended to engage in an illicit trade, instead of that he would do what was necessary to make his business legal? It is against the policy of the state as announced in its constitution (Art. 17, Sec. 7) for a corporation ‘ ‘to take or hold any real estate, except such as may be necessary and proper for its legitimate business.”

A bank or other party loans money to a corporation, knowing that it is to be used in the purchase of real estate. .Must the lpan contract be presumed to be inyalid until the *133lender establishes affirmatively that the real estate so purchased was actually ‘■‘necessary and proper” for the legitimate business of the corporation? There may be authorities so holding, but I have found none. The rule is that, the corporation proving authority to borrow money, it will be presumed that it did it legitimately, and in the exercise of its corporate powers. 4 Am. & Eng. Enc. Law, 222. It would seem a freak in logic to say that after a thing is done it will be presumed that it was done regularly, but that before it is done it must be presumed that it will be done irregularly. The loan contract was valid or invalid when made. If invalid, it was because of some knowledge, actual or imputed, upon the part of the lender, that he was aiding and participating in a violation of the law. Such knowledge is the very essence of his wrong, and ought in some way to be reasonably proved, rather than presumed, and that, too, against the established presumption that men will not ordinarily do unlawful things. The presumption applies as well in civil as in criminal matters. It will never be presumed that the law has been or will be violated, but the contrary will be presumed. 19 Am. & Eng. Enc. Law, 42. If this is a safe presumption for courts to rest their judgments upon, it ought to be safe for individuals to act upon. Suppose in a proper judicial proceeding complaint were made that this company was about to purchase shares of its own stock. Would not the court of whom relief was asked say at once it may legally do so under certain conditions, and it cannot be presumed against it that it will do it illegally? If a court will presume in its favor that it will act within the law, is there any good reason why a stranger dealing with it may not indulge the same presumption?

The findings in this case are entirely consistent with absolute moral and legal innocence on the part of Deyette; entirely consistent with an honest belief on his part, when he loaned the money, that the consent of the stockholders had been or would be obtained. And a simple finding that it was not ob-*134tamed is quite insufficient, in my judgment, to charge him with a knowledge that the law was to be violated in the purchase of the stock. In his argument respondent assumes that Deyette was in the employ of the company, and must have had knowledge of what was and was not done, and therefore should be held to know that the Trask stock was bought without the consent of the stockholders being first obtained. There is nothing in the record showing that he had any relations with the company except that of creditor on account of this loan, except that included in the judgment confessed was $134 for work and labor. In what capacity this was performed is not shown or suggested. He might have been a clerk in the store, with some knowledge of its business and financial condition, or he might have been a drayman or laborer outside, with no knowledge of its affairs. We cannot presume either. We must get the facts from the record, and not from the briefs of counsel. I am unable to discover anything in the findings that militates against the validity of Deyette’s claim. Placing this- conclusion upon the ground that no guilty knowledge is found upon his part, furnishes an additional reason why it is unnecessary for me to discuss the mooted question of whether knowledge alone, if he had had it, that the stock was to be bought in violation of law, would, without participation by him in the unlawful transaction, other than loaning the money, be sufficient to render his loan contract invalid and unenforceable; and as, in the view I take of this case, this question is not involved, I reserve the expression of any opinion for future examination when presented. It follows that in my opinion the Deyette judgment in respect to its consideration was good and valid. This was the very question upon which the case turned in the trial court. It held the judgment invalid because the consideration was invalid. This is evident, not only from its conclusion of law upon this point, but from the fact that it held the judgment good as to the claim for services.

In our former opinion, now adhered to by a majority of the court, we went further, and said that the judgment ought not *135to be enforced, because it was an effort on tbe part of an insolvent corporation to prefer Deyette as a creditor, and tbat an insolvent corporation could not do this. The same cause and the same reason would condemn the entire judgment, as well for services as for money loaned; but upon further reflection and a more thorough examination of the question I am unable to concur in the opinion that a corporation, by becoming insolvent merely, ipso facto loses its right to pay or secure one creditor in preference to another. We have declared the right of an individual debtor to make such preferences. Manufacturing Co. v. Max (S. D.) 58 N. W. 14. We said the right of a debtor to prefer one creditor over another was guarantied to him by the express words of the statute. Sec. 4654. A corporation or a partnership becomes a debtor under the same circumstances as an individual. If the so-called ‘ ‘trust-fund doctrine” will prevent a corporation debtor from so preferring one creditor to another, I am unable to see why it should not have the same effect, and for the same reason, in case of a partnership. A corporation becomes insolvent just when the partnership or the individual becomes so — when it is unable to pay its debts from its own means as they become due. Comp. Laws, § 4661. It is well, then, unless required by prevailing authority, to adopt the rule that a private corporation, unable to meet its debts as they mature, has no right to pay one creditor until or more than it pays all others? It is often said in the books that the assets of an insolvent corporation are a trust fund for the payment of its debts, but this is also true of a partnership, and really of an individual; and for the same reason. Pomeroy says this doctrine of trust is just as applicable to a partnership and its assets as to a corporation and its assets, and that in either case the relation can only be so named by way of “analogy or metaphor. •’ He further says: “It is plain that no constructive trust can arise in favor of the creditors unless the partners or directors, through fraud or a breach of fiduciary duty, wrongfully appropriate the property and acquire- the *136legal title to it in their own names, and thus place it beyond the reach of creditors through ordinary legal means. ” 2 Pom. Eq. Jur. § 1046. If the rule of disability applies to an insolvent corporation on the ground of its trust relations to its assets, it would seem that it should also apply to an insolvent partnership; but in Manufacturing Có. v. Max, supra, we sustained the right of Max & Baisch, an insolvent partnership, to make such preferences. I cannot see why, in the case either of a corporation or a partnership, the mere fact of insolvency, without more, should of itself change the character of what was the absolute property of the corporation or partnership into trust funds. Insolvency creates a condition which justifies . a court with equity powers in laying hold of assets, and then so treating and disposing of them. While the assets remain undisturbed in the hands of the corporation or partnership, solvent or insolvent, it owns and may dispose of them as an individual owner may, in any manner not fraudulent as to its creditors, including stockholders in case of a corporation. Nearly all commercial credit is given to the individual, the partnership, or the corporation on the strength of its known assets, and in reliance upon a prudent management and an honest appropriation of them to the payment of its debts. In this sense the property of every debtor is a trust fund, with himself as trustee, for the payment of his debts. It is no more so simply because the debtor is a’corporation, so long as it continues its active functions as such, and retains absolute control of its property.. At no time does the trust attach to the property because it belongs to a corporation; but when the corporation becomes insolvent and unable to continue its active life it is so far civilly dead that its assets become subject to the administration of the courts. From that time on the assets coming into the hands of the court are treated as a trust fund for the benefit of creditors and stockholders, for they then constitute an estate to be administered. In Graham v. Railroad Co., 102 U. S. 148, the learned Judge Bradley said: ‘When a corpor*137ation becomes insolvent, it is so far civilly dead that its property may be administered as a trust for the benefit of its creditors and stockholders. A court of equity, at the instance of proper parties, will then make these funds trust funds, which are, in other circumstances as much the absolute property of the corporation as any man’s property is his. ”

This trust doctrine, as applied to the assets of corporations, solvent and insolvent, was fully discussed by Judge Brewer in Hollins v. Iron Co., 154 U. S. 371, 14 Sup. Ct. 127, and the construction of the court is thus stated in the head note: “The expression often used, that the property of a corporation constitutes a ‘trust fund’ for its creditors, only means that when the corporation is insolvent, and a court of equity has possession of its assets for administration, such assets must be appropriated to the payment of its debts before any distribution to the stockholders, but, as between a corporation itself and its creditors, the former does not hold its property in trust, or subject to lien in favor of the creditors, in any other sense than does an individual debtor.” In Van Alstyne v. Cook, 25 N. Y. 489, the court, in speaking of the assets of an insolvent, limited partnership, said: “They are trust funds when the courts of equity are. properly appealed to in behalf of the partners, or any partner or creditor, to protect and distribute the same upon equitable principles, and on such application assert the control over them. They are not trust funds in the hands of the partners any more than ordinary partnership property. ” The supreme court of Illinois declares the same doctrine in Roseboom v. Whittaker, 132 Ill. 81, 23 N. E. 339: “The mere insolvency of a corporation cannot have the effect of depriving creditors of their legal remedies, but they are at liberty, notwithstanding the insolvency, to sue the corporation in an action at law, and by means of such proceeding establish a specific lien upon the property seized by attachment or execution. Such lien, when perfected, will doubtless entitle the creditor acquiring it to a preference over ocher unsecured creditors. *138After the aid of a court of equity has been invoked, and that court has taken the assets of the insolvent into its hands, its jurisdiction becomes necessarily exclusive; and it will proceed, in administering the insolvent estate, upon the maxim that equality is equity.” See, also, the later case of Peterson v. Tailoring Co., 150 Ill. 290, 37 N. E. 242. In Town v. Bank, 2 Doug. (Mich.) 530, it was held that a corporation has the same right to prefer one creditor over another that an individual has. This was followed in Kendall v. Bishop, 76 Mich. 634, 43 N. W. 645, and again in the recent case of Bank of Montreal v. E. J. Potts S. & L. Co., 90 Mich. 345, 51 N. W. 512, where it was held that ‘ ‘a corporation may, in the absence of legislative restriction, deal with its property precisely as an individual may, and may prefer one creditor over another; and hence its assets do not become a trust fund for pro rata distribution among all of its creditors, until steps are taken under the ‘winding-up act.’ ” This “trust-fund” doctrine is luminously discussed by Judge Mitchell in Hospes v. Car Co., 48 Minn. 174, 50 N. W. 1117, who demonstrates that, unless prohibited by statute, an insolvent' corporation has the same right as an individual to prefer creditors, and that there is no solid foundation for the doctrine that the insolvency of a corporation has the effect of converting its assets into a “trust fund,” in any proper sense of that term. In Ang. & A. Corp. 802, it is laid down as an unqualified proposition of law that “the mere insolvency of a corporation neither impairs its powers to manage its affairs nor converts its property into a trust fund for the benefit of its creditors. ” Almost precisely the same thing was said in Catlin v. Bank, 6 Conn. 233, and reiterated by the same court in Pondville Co. v. Clark, 25 Conn. 97. In the former case the court discussed the question at great length. In the course of its opinion, it says: “The cases of an individual and of a corporation in the matter under discussion, it appears to me, are not merely analogous, but identical, and I discover no reason for the slightest difference between them. * * * The insol*139vent banking corporation is just as muck a trustee of the creditors, and no more, as the insolvent individual is the trustee of his creditors.”

The same doctrine as to when the assets of an insolvent corporation become trust funds was declared by the supreme court of Missouri in La Grange Butter Tub Co. v. National Bank of Commerce, 26 S. W. 710. The court said: “In case of an insolvent corporation, a court of equity will make distribution of the corporation assets pro rata among the corporation creditors, and to that end will regard the corporation property as a trust fund. It is in this sense, and upon this principle, that the assets are trust funds. They are trust funds when a court of equity is appealed to in behalf of any member of the corporation or creditor to protect and distribute the assets upon equitable principles.” And again in Alberger v. Bank, 123 Mo. 313, 27 S. W. 657, Judge Barclay, in speaking of the notion that insolvency transforms the assets of a corporation into a trust fund said: “This theory seems to have a singular fascination to some learned jurists, but, in our opinion, it is wholly untenable as applied to the facts of such a case as that before us, under the law of Missouri;” and, after a very thorough and instructive discussion of the question he concludes that “the creditor of á corporation has the same right to secure, by superior diligence or persistency, and to retain, a preference for his claim against a private corporation, that he would have were his debtor an individual engaged in the same line of business, provided, always, that the transaction is honest — that is to say, not a mere cover to a purpose to hinder, delay or defraud other creditors of the failing debtor.” Such is also the declared law in New Jersey. In Wilkinson v. Bauerle, 41 N. J. Eq. 640, 7 Atl. 514, the court said: “If there be no legislative prohibition against the transfer of corporate property or its use in preferring creditors after insolvency, no reasons can be given why such transaction should be invalidated, which would not also invalidate the like transactions of *140individuals. Both reason and authority establish the proposition that a corporation may sell and transfer its property, and may prefer its creditors, although it is insolvent, unless such conduct is prohibited by law. ” The supreme court of Arkansas in the recent case of Worthen v. Griffith, 59 Ark. 562, 28 S. W. 286, holds the same way, and that ‘ ‘it is only when a court of equity, at the instance of a proper party, and in a proper proceeding, has taken possession of the assets of an insolvent corporation, that its assets may, in this state, be properly said to be a trust fund for its creditors.” The same question as to the right of an insolvent corporation to make preferences was before the court in Gould v. Railway Co., 52 Fed. 680. Judge Caldwell said that it was the settled law in Arkansas — from which state the case came — that it might lawfully do so, and added this significant statement: ‘The established rule in that state is in harmony with the general, though not quite uniform, current of authorities in this country on the question. After referring to a large number of supporting authorities he adds: “The cases which hold the contrary doctrine are bottomed on the erroneous theory that the insolvency of a corporation in effect dissolves it, and makes the directors mere trustees to distribute its assets ratably among its creditors. It is undoubtedly true that the property of a corporation is, in one sense, a trust fund for the payment of its debts; but this rule means no more than that the property of a corporation cannot be distributed among its stockholders, or applied to any purpose foreign to the legitimate business of the corporation, until its debts are paid. The rule, so far as it relates to the payment of debts, is satisfied whenever the property of a corporation is applied to the payment of its dona fide debts. The rule, as has been often pointed out, does not prevent a corporation, whether solvent or insolvent, from making preferences among its creditors, and exercising in good faith absolute dominion over its property in the conduct of its legitimate corporate business, so long as its right to do so is not restrained by statute or by judicial pro*141ceedings.” In his opinion Judge Caldwell refers to the following authorities, none of which I have cited, as sustaining his conclusion: 2 Mor. Priv. Corp. 802; Allis v. Jones, 45 Fed. 148; Covert v. Rogers, 38 Mich. 363; Coats v. Donnell, 94 N. Y. 168; Dana v. Bank, 5 Watts & S. 223; Warner v. Mower, 11 Vt. 390; Whitwell v. Warner, 20 Vt. 426; Stratton v. Allen, 16 N. J. Eq. 229; Wilkinson v. Bauerle, 41 N. J. Eq. 635, 7 Atl. 514; Duncomb v. Railroad Co., 84 N. Y. 190, 88 N. Y. 1; Harts v. Brown, 77 Ill. 226; Reichwald v. Hotel Co. 106 Ill. 439; Buell v. Buckingham, 16 Iowa 214 (opinion by Judge Dillon); Garrett v. Plow Co., 70 Iowa 697, 29 N. W. 395; Smith v. Skeary, 47 Conn. 47; Bank v. Whittle, 78 Va. 737; Ashhurst’s Appeal, 60 Pa. St. 314; Sargent v. Webster, 13 Metc. (Mass.) 497; Hallam v. Hotel Co., 56 Iowa 178, 9 N. W. 111.

The supreme court of Alabama is equally pronounced against this ‘trusfcfund” doctrine, and in a very able and elaborate opinion, filed as recently as April of the present year, it expressly repudiates such doctrine, and overrules a number of cases in which its existence had been recognized by that court. •The learned judge who writes the opinion says: ‘‘There is nothing clearer in principle than the proposition that the property of a corporation, solvent or insolvent, bears identically the same relations to the creditors of such corporation as the property of an individual or copartnership, solvent or insolvent, sustains to the creditors of the individual or partnership, and is or is not to be impressed with a trust character upon the circumstances and under the same conditions in the first case as in the latter two.” Jewelry Co. v. Volfer, (Ala.) 17 South. 525. In the still more recent case of Thomson-Houston Electric Light Co. v. Henderson, Electric & Gaslight Co., 21 S. E. 951, the North Carolina supreme court deliberately rejected the “trust-fund” theory, and declared generally that the relation between a corporation creditor and the corporation, whether solvent or insolvent, is simply that of creditor and debtor, and that the *142creditor had no equitable claim upon the corporation assets, either because it was a corporation or because it was insolvent. The supreme court of Indiana has lately made the same expression in emphatic terms in First Nat. Bank of Crawfordsville v. Dovetail, B. & G. Co., 40 N. E. 810, and in the same further held (bearing upon the first question discussed in this opinion) that “the fact that one lending money to a corporation knew that it was to be used by the directors for a purpose involving a breach of trust does not impair the validity of the judgment against the corporation in his favor for the amount loaned, entered by the corporation’s consent, with the purpose of creating a preference.” In Burrill, Assignm. (5th Ed.) Sec. 64, it is said: “It has been objected * * * that on the happening of its insolvency the corporation and its agents became trustees for the creditors, who where entitled to a ratable payment out of the trust fund in proportion to the amount of their debts. This position, however, has not been sustained, and apart from statutory provisions, no distinction exists between an individual and a corporation in regard to the exercise of the power of conferring preferences. ”

Without quoting from other cases, in which very wise and thoughtful judges have announced similar views, I am satisfied to say that to me they seem right in principle. If, for any reason, there should be a discrimination between different classes of debtors in respect to the right to make preferences among their creditors, as said by Judge Dillon in Buell v. Buckingham, supra, the rule should be declared by the legislature, which has the constitutional power to make and change the law, and not by the courts, which have no such power. It may be remarked, however, that as to some of the cases cited generally in support of the contrary doctrine they were controlled by local statutes which unfortunately are not mentioned, or at least not made prominent, in the opinion. For instance, both Ohio and Texas cases are cited as opposed, and Rouse v. Bank, 46 Ohio St. 493, 22 N. E. 293, and Lyons-Thomas Hard*143ware Co. v. Perry Stove Manuf’g Co., 86 Tex. 143, 24 S. W. 16, do so read, but in each state there was a statute declaring that any transfer of property as a preference by a debtor who is insolvent “or in contemplation of insolvency” shall not be valid as against an assignment then in contemplation for the benefit of creditors. What influence, if any, this declared policy of the state law had upon the treatment of the general question by the courts we do not know. I have read with interest what Mr. Thompson says upon this question in his recently published work on Corporations. He is an author of acknowledged learning and ability. Upon all matters he expresses his personal views positively and clearly, and usually courteously and dispassionately; but his treatment of this question, his characterization of the deliberately declared opinions of emir nent courts and judges as “themouthings of judges” with “low conceptions,” “destitute of a sense of justice,” and other similar flippancies, evince such a degree of morbidity upon this subject as greatly to compromise the value of his opinion. He says (Sec. 6496) the “fallacy” of the conclusion to which these thoughtless judges have ‘‘jumped” is in overlooking “the fact that the analogy between an individual and an insolvent corporation wholly fails in this: that although an insolvent individual may turn over his property to certain of his creditors whom he desires to prefer, and may, by so doing, hinder and delay the others, yet he merely delays and hinders them; he does not, by that act, destroy himself; he still lives; and he may, and often does, get on his feet again, and acquire property, and discharge his previous obligations. But when a corporation becomes insolvent, and ceases to have the means of carrying out the object of its creation, and dispossesses itself of all its property, it destroys itself, and becomes ipso facto dissolved.” In his zeal to demonstrate the “fallacy,” has not the learned author allowed himself to start from unstable premises? Is it entirely safe to build upon the fonndation that when a corporation becomes insolvent, “and dispossesses itself of all its *144property, it destroys itself, and becomes ipso facto dissolved?” In Sec. 6483 of the same book he has told us that ‘ ‘the assignment by a corporation of all its property for the benefit of its creditors does not extinguish it as a corporation, or disable it from maintaining an action, unless the subject-matter of the action passed from it by the assignment.” In this latter statement he seems well supported by authority, though Judge Story, in a dissenting opinion in Beaston v. Bank, 12 Pet. 138, intimated a contrary opinion. See Burrill, Assignm. (5th Ed.) Sec. 64; Ang. & A. Corp. Sec. 770; and cases cited by each of these authors. The law is generally recognized to be, as stated by Mr. Thompson, that neither the insolvency of nor a general assignment by a private corporation works its dissolution. An individual debtor, stripped of his means for satisfying his debts, “still lives”; but it is just as true of a corporation. Each is still a living debtor without present ability to pay his or its debts. It is probably true that an individual debtor is more likely to “get on his feet again,” but that is incidental merely, and does not prove or tend to prove any difference in their legal status. The possession of property is no more essential to the existence of a corporation than it is to the existence of a man. If a corporation becomes insolvent, there is nothing to prevent its members, until its dissolution is legally declared, from furnishing more funds, and proceeding to use its corporate powers. Mor. Priv. Corp. Sec. 1010, and citations. My conclusion is that the hardware company, although insolvent, might legally prefer Deyette as a creditor, and that his judgment, founded on a good consideration, was not invalid or unenforceable on account of such preference.

As to Lewis and his judgment, the facts established by the findings are the same, except that at the date of his judgment and before — but how long before is not found — he was a director and secretary of the company. He, too, loaned money to the company for the purpose of buying the Trask stock and it not being shown that at the time of such loaning and pur*145chase he had any connection with the company, he, as a creditor, would stand upon the same footing as Deyette, except that when his judgment was confessed he was a director and officer of the company. On the 9th day of May the company confessed these judgments — one to Deyette, already considered; one to Foster, over which there seems to be no controversy; and one to Lewis, now in hand. Lewis himself executed these confessions as secretary of the company. Executions were issued on these judgments, and levied upon the personal property of the hardware company, but when issued or *vhen levied does not appear. On the 12th, execution was also issued on respondent’s judgment. The property was sold, and the proceeds which are “not sufficient to pay the judgments against the Hicks-Trask Hardware Company prior to the judgment of plaintiff” (respondent), are held by the sheriff “to be applied on said executions according to the decree of this court.” It not appearing that executions were issued on other judgments than those named, we understand from the language of the findings that the proceeds are insufficient to pay the three judgments first named. The Foster and the Deyette judgments being good, and entitled to be paid; the contest is over the balance in the hands of the sheriff, and between Lewis and the respondent. While the findings do not expressly show- — as we wish they did — when the execution on the Lewis judgment was issued or levied, it must have been prior to the issuance of respondent’s execution, for the property appears to have been sold under the Lewis, Foster and Deyette executions. The fact that the company was insolvent, that it confessed these three judgments on the 9th, and that three days thereafter it confessed judgment to quite a number of other creditors, including respondent, and that executions were issued and levied on the first three judgments either prior to or on the 12th, the date of the subsequent judgments, and before respondent’s execution, issued immediately upon obtaining its judgment, is very convincing, though perhaps not incontestible. evidence that it *146was intended that Foster, Lewis and Deyette should be given a preference over other creditors. I have no doubt that it was so designed. So that the question now in hand is, could the company legally prefer Lewis, a director, and one of its managing officers, on account of an indebtedness not contracted on the strength of such preference, but for a general antecedent indebtedness? I think that we can hold that it could not, consistently with what I have already said in respect to the right generally of an insolvent corporation to prefer creditors. While the directors and officers of a corporation, solvent or insolvent, are not in any proper sense the trustees of the creditors, they do occupy a relation to them demanding the utmost good faith on their part in the handling of the corporation assets. To their honest and fair dealing with the property, and to their just and prudent management of the business, the creditors must look for their continued security, As in the case of others occupying a fiduciary position, they cannot innocently sacrifice the interests of those who trust them to their own personal advantage.. As managers of the corporation and its property, they owe a duty to those dealing with them, which they violate when, to the detriment of those who confide in them, they make themselves preferred beneficiaries in the disposition of assets which without such preference, would be available alike to all creditors. They hold in their hands the property of the corporation to which creditors must look for satisfaction of their claims, and come within the just principal that one who has possession and control of property for the benefit of others besides himself may not dispose of it for his own special advantage, to the injury of others, for whom it is also held.

The judgment in this case was confessed. Lewis himself as secretary of the company executed the confession to himself. It was not a hostile proceeding against the company in which he acted as a creditor only, but was a voluntary effort on the part of the company, executed through and by him as its secretary, to giye .himself an advantage over creditors generally, *147with no equities to justify such preference, except that he was a general creditor on account of an antecedent indebtedness. I do not think such a preference should be sustained.

In many of the states which recognize the general right of an insolvent corporation to make preferences among its creditors, such preferences in favor of its own directors on account of antecedent indebtedness, in the absence of special equities, are not sustained. See Gottlieb v. Miller, 154 Ill. 44, 39 N. E. 992, where a preference was sustained as to outside creditors, and set aside as to directors. See, also, Lippincott v. Carriage Co., 25 Fed. 577, where a large number of cases are cited to the point that directors and managing officers cannot be preferred. Montgomery v. Phillips (N. J. Err. & App.) 31 Atl. 622, followed in Mallory v. Kirkpatrick (N. J. Ch.) 33 Atl. 205; Henderson v. Trust Co. (Ind. Sup.) 40 N. E. 516; Corey v. Wadsworth (Ala.) 11 South. 350. See, also, upon this a valuable note to Lyons-Thomas Hardware Co. v. Perry Stove Manuf’g Co. (Tex. Sup.) in 22 Lawy. Rep. Ann. 802, 24 S. W. 16, in which the editor’s conclusion is thus stated: “On examination of the decisions, it is clear that the weight of authority is overwhelmingly in favor of the legality of preferences to ordinary creditors, except as restricted by statute, and overwhelmingly against the validity of such preferences when made in favor of directors.”

The trial court held the Lewis judgment invalid, both because of the invalidity of its consideration and because it was the result of an attempt to give preference to a director. For reasons stated early in this opinion, I think the first ground untenable. As to the second ground, I am of the opinion that he, being a director, and one of the managing officers of the company, ought not to get any advantage in the nature of a preference, but that the court was wrong in holding his judgment void and in denying him participation in the distribution of the proceeds of sale in the hands of the.sheriff. This seems to be the policy of our statute. If, by a general assignment, *148this preference had been attempted in favor of Lewis, the preference would have failed, but he would still have been entitled to share ratably with other creditors. Comp. Laws, § 4660. I think there is much in the majority opinion that is sentimentally good and wholesome, but that the text from which it is elaborated cannot be found anywhere in the facts returned by the trial court, or of which we have any judicial knowledge.

Finally, I cannot quite understand how the court, having deliberately declared that the assets of this corporation, being insolvent, constitute a fund for ratable distribution among its creditors without preference, can affirm this judgment, which gives to this respondent creditor practically the entire assets of the corporation, in the face of the record showing other creditors, whose judgments were confessed at the same time, and which must go unpaid. This is an equitable action in the nature of a creditors’ bill in behalf of this plaintiff only, and the remark of Judge Thayer in Walker v. Miller, 59 Fed. 871, seems pertinent: ‘ ‘If this trust-fund theory is to be adopted to prevent the corporation from granting a preference because of its insolvency, we know of no reason why it should not be invoked to keep attaching creditors at bay, and thus relegate the disposal of the fund, so far as judicial proceedings are concerned, to a court of equity.” See, also, Mallory v. Kirkpatrick, supra.