More v. Bennett

Waterman, J.

It is impossible to reconcile the numerous cases upon the subject of contracts and combinations in restraint of trade. Beginning with the cause reported in Tear Book 2d, Henry V, in which the irascible Judge Hall, three quarters of a century before the discovery of America, upon an attempt to enforce an obligation entered into in consideration that the defendant did not use his dyer’s craft wri thin the city for a certain time, to wit, for half a year, thundered out in bad French: “ A ma intent mus purres avoir demurre sur luy que obligation est void eo que le condition est encounter common ley, et per Dieu. si le flai/ntiff fut icy, il irra al prison tang' il ul fait fine al JRoy” (In my opinion you might have demurred upon him, that the obligation is void inasmuch as the condition is against the common law; and by G— if the plaintiff were here he should go to prison till he paid a fine to the king.) Down to the present time, the fluctuating opinions, based as they have been upon considerations of public policy, have shifted now in this direction, and then in that, as cases decided upon what is thought to be for the best of the whole community, ever have and ever must, vary in accordance with the changing ideas of wherein the public welfare rests. If any rule can be said to be deducible from the authorities, it is that the question for determination in respect to contracts in restraint of trade is, whether the restraint is reasonable or not, that is, whether the restraint is such only as to afford a fair protection to the interests of the parties in favor of whom it is given, and is not so large as to interfere with the interests of the public. As the Supreme Court of this State say, in the case of Kraft et al. v. McOonoughy, “Whatever is injurious to the interests of the public is void on the ground of public policy;” and again, “ So long as competition is free, the interests of the public are safe;” it being understood that all general restraints of trade are unreasonable, and are, therefore, contrary to public policy, illegal and void. As to any restraint of trade, as, if it is unreasonable it is void, the question arises, what is meant by a reasonable restraint? Does it, as is argued in this case, in cases of this nature, and in contracts in respect to the sale of commodities, mean only that the restriction as to price shall be reasonable, or does it include more than this ? If restricted to agreements as to price, can it be said that so long as-any one individual is able and willing to sell flour for $5 a barrel, $6 a barrel is a reasonable price? In other words, in any cause wherein it clearly appears that one individual is able and willing to supply a commodity at a price considerably below what a dozen or a hundred experts may say is a reasonable price for such article, will the testimony of the great number of experts testifying as to their opinion of what is a reasonable price, be allowed to outweigh the undisputed fact that one individual, in the teeth of their assertions, is able and willing to supply the article to all who wish it at the lower rates, and have not the public, without reference to price, an interest in seeing that individuals shall not bind themselves, either directly or indirectly, not to engage in useful callings, and to perform useful service, except such engagements shall apply only to a limited territory, that is, to a territory so limited that the court can see that the public have not, by the contract, been deprived of the benefit which it might receive from the talents and the service of the individual in the calling or business concerning which the contract is made? As the Supreme Court of the United States has said in Oregon Steam Navigation Co. v. Winsor, 20 Wall. 64, “There are two principal grounds upon which the doctrine is founded that a contract in restraint of trade is void as against public policy. One is, the injury to the public by being deprived of the restricted party’s industry; the other is, the injury to the party himself by being precluded from pursuing his occupation, and thus being prevented from supporting himself and his family. ■s- * The country suffers the loss in both cases, and the party is deprived of his occupation, or is obliged to expatriate himself in order to follow it. A contract that is open to such grave objections is clearly against public policy.”

It has from time immemorial been an industrial maxim that competition is the life of trade, while monopolies have always been odious. Combinations looking to the destruction of competition have, therefore, always been unfavorably regarded by the law, for it is manifest that without competition there can be no such thing as freedom of trade. As Chief Justice Cooley has said, “The advantages of unrestricted competition are apparent to the public in industrial life all about us, and while in some kinds of business this is sharp, yet selfishness is generally sufficiently active and sufficiently intelligent to prevent its becoming ruinous;” and as was said in Metzger v. Cleveland & Adams, 3 Ind. Law Mag. 42, “The maxim that competition is the life of trade, is not the language of the street alone; it is a proverb in law. * * The law favors trade, and its first aim is to promote the public interest, and after that to preserve individual rights, and it will not permit any one to restrain a person from doing what the public welfare requires that lie should do.” That disasters sometimes result from competition, and injuries to the public sometimes grow therefrom, is no more a reason why the policy of the law in respect to competition should be abandoned, than are the unfortunate marriages which too frequently occur, and the evils incident to "the public as well as to individuals therefrom a reason why the institution of marriage should be abolished, or the law in respect to it radically changed. Man is an imperfect being, therefore all things made and carried on by him operate with more or less imperfection. Whatever may have been the rule centuries ago, it is now established that it is not an offense for workmen to combine to raise the rate of wages, but the question in this case is not whether a combination to keep up prices is an offense,- but whether the law so sanctions agreements of this kind that it will enforce the fulfillment of them by compelling the party who breaks the contract to pay such penalty or such damages as the agreement provides.

If the landlords of a city should, by an agreement among themselves, contract that they would not let any tenement or room for housekeeping purposes, at a rental of less than §20 per month, and that whoever violated such contract should pay to the association a penalty and be liable for all damages which any party to the contract might sustain in consequence of the violation thereof, would the courts enforce the collection of such penalty or damages because the allegation was made and the preponderance of evidence showed that the rate so fixed was a reasonable one ? And still more, would the court sustain an action brought for such penalty or such damage if it appeared in evidence that any person in the city was able and willing to furnish such tenement or rooms for a less sum than that fixed by the association ?

Or, if the physicians of a city should agree that no one of their number should visit any sick person without a fee of §2 paid in advance, and that whoever violated this compact should pay a penalty of §100, or compensate the physician whose custom or business he had taken away by such violation, would not the courts refuse to enforce such a contract, notwithstanding it might be o.f the opinion that the rate fixed and the provision for advance payment was as regards the physicians, a reasonable one ? Would it not hold that the public had interests in reference to such matter ? Or, if a trustee, entitled to a reasonable compensation for his services and to his reasonable expenditures, should report to the court that he had paid stenographers at the rate of $10 a day, would the court allow him that sum, in the face of the undisputed fact that he could have employed other stenograjihers, equally competent, for So a day? Has any court ever held that for one charged with a duty to another, it is reasonable to pay, either for commodities or labor, a larger sum than the article can readily be obtained for?

A large proportion of the cases in restraint of trade, to which our attention has been called, where such restraints, being partial and limited,have been held valid and enforceable, are cases in which a party selling out his stock of goods, machinery, tools, fixtures, lease or premises, has also sold therewith the good will of his business, and as a means of securing to the purchaser such good will, has covenanted that for a limited time, or within a limited distance, he would not carry on his former trade or business.

It was said by the vice-chancellor, in Leather Cloth Co. v. Lorsont, Law Rep. 9th Eq.: “ All the cases in regard to restraints of trade, when they come to be examined, seem to establish this principle, that all restraints upon trade are bad, as being in violation of public policy, unless they are natural, and not unreasonable for the protection of the parties in dealing legally with some subject-matter of contract. The principle is this: Public policy requires that every man shall be at liberty to work for himself, and shall not be at liberty to deprive himself or the State of his labor, skill or talent by any contract that he enters into. On the other hand, public policy requires that when a man has, by skill or other means, obtained something which he wants to sell, he should be at liberty to sell it in the most advantageous way in the market, and in order to enable him to sell it advantageously in the market, it is necessary that he should be able to preclude himself from entering into competition with the purchaser. In such a case the same public policy that enables him to do that does not restrain him from alienating that which he wants to alienate, and therefore enables him to enter into any. stipulation, however restrictive it is, provided that restriction, in the judgment of the court, is not unreasonable, having regard to the subject-matter of the contract”

Bronson, J., in Chappell v. Brockway, 21 Wend. 157, declares the rule to be that “ It is not enough that there may be such a consideration as would be sufficient to uphold a contract in which the public had no interest. Whatever may be the pecuniary condition, it must appear, in addition, that there w'as some good reason for entering into the contract, and that it imposes no restraint upon one party which is not beneficial to the other.” To the same effect is the opinion given in Ross v. Sadgbur, 21 Wend. 166, and also that in the leading case of Mitchell v. Reynolds, 1 P. Williams, 181.

There is another reason why this action can not be maintained. Any agreement, which, in its object or necessary operation, tends to diminish competition as to anything the public have for sale, or it is necessary that the public should use, is void. Public policy requires that the public shall obtain the things necessary for its use upon fair competition in a free and open market, or under such rules and regulations as the public laws may prescribe. The contract mentioned in this case, which it is said the plaintiffs had obtained, was one with the county of Cook; the service rendered was being performed for the public; the public authorities had no right to pay a larger sum than that for which they could get the work satisfactorily done, and any agreement depriving the county of its right to secure the performance of this work from any one competent to do it, was void, as opposed to public policy. The authorities upon this subject are numerous. Greenhood on Public Policy, page 177; Gulick v. Bailey, 10 N. J. Law, 102; Gibbs v. Smith, 115 Mass. 592; Atchison v. Mallon, 43 N. Y. 147; Woodworth v. Bennett, 43 N. Y. 273; People v. Lord, 6 Hun, 390; Engelman v. Skrainka, 14 Mo. App. 438; Hale v. Henderson, 4 Hump. (Tenn.) 198; Hannah v. Fife, 27 Mich. 173; Woodruff v. Berry, 40 Ark. 251; Noyes v. Day, 14 Vt. 384; King v. Winants, 71 N. C. 469.

We are of the opinion that the agreement set up in the declaration was contrary to public policy and therefore void. Parties who make such promises must depend upon the disposition of the promisors to keep the same; the law will not enforce such undertakings.

Why the appellees failed to tile a brief in this case or suggest any reasons why this judgment should not be reversed, we do not know.

The judgment of the court below sustaining the demurrer to the declaration is affirmed.

Judgment affirmed.