delivered the opinion of the court.
The question in this case is whether the secured creditor of this insolvent bank may prove and receive dividends upon the face of his entire claim — his whole debt — without crediting his collaterals or collections made therefrom and without surrendering the said collaterals. It is a question upon which there is a great conflict in the authorities; hut, after the maturest consideration, we prefer the view that such secured creditor is not so entitled, but must credit the value of the collaterals on the debt, and prove only for the balance. In view of the very able and very exhaustive consideration of this subject in the case of Merrill v. Nat. Bank of Jacksonville, 173 U. S., 131 (19 Sup. Ct., 360; 43 L. ed., 640), we deem it unnecessary to attempt any extended observations of our own. It is impossible for us to escape the conclusion that the better view is set forth *471in the opinion of the dissenting justices, delivered by Mr. Justice White, and we adopt the reasoning of that opinion as our own. We make just a few observations: These collaterals passed by the assignment to the assignee. The fact that-they were held as collateral to the debt did not change the fact that they were a mere security for the debt. The assignment provides that the distribution shall be ratable amongst the creditors. We think Mr. Justice White demonstrates that “the rule in bankruptcy did not depend upon express statutory requirement, but, on the contrary, that it was simply a necessary outgrowth of the command of the statute that there should be an equal distribution of the bankrupt’s assets.” As said by Justice White: “True it is that, both in our own act of 1867 and in the English bankrupt act of 1869, there were inserted express provisions requiring a secured creditor to account for his collaterals before proving against the general assets. But this was but the incorporation into the statutes of the rule which had arisen as a consequence of the requirement for a ratable distribution, and which had existed for hundreds of years before the statute’s of 1867 and 1869 were adopted. In other words, the express statutory requirement only .embodied in the form of a legislative enactment what theretofore .from the earliest time had been universally enforced, because of the provision for a ratable distribution.” Mr. Justice White further says: “It was undoubtedly from a consideration of this fundamental rule of equity, in construing the statutory requirement for ratable division of general assets, that the bankruptcy rule was formulated. That rule, however, in effect, declared that secured creditors might retain their preferential contract rights in particular portions of the estate of the insolvent debtor, but that it was the purpose of parliament, in commanding ratable distribution, that general assets — that is, assets disincumbered of liens — should be distributed only among the general or unsecured creditors; the necessary effect being that a secured creditor could not prove against general assets with*472out surrendering his security, thus becoming a general or unsecured creditor for the whole amount of the debt, or realizing upon the security, or in some form accounting for its value, in which latter contingency he would be general or unsecured creditor only for the deficiency. That the bankruptcy rule was deemed to be founded upon equitable principles, I think, is demonstrated by the statement of Lord Hardwicke in a case already mentioned (Broomley v. Goodere, 1 Atk., 77), where, after referring to the act of 13 Elizabeth, ch. 7, he said: ‘It is manifest that this act intended to give the commissioners an equitable jurisdiction as well as a legal one, for they have full power and authority to take by their discretions such order and direction as they shall see fit, and this has been the construction ever since; and therefore, when petitions have come before the chancellor, he has always proceeded upon the same rules as he would upon cases coming before him upon the bill — the rules of equity.’ ” As well said by Lord Chancellor Eldon: “Till his debt has been reduced by the proceeds of that sale [that is, of the security], it is impossible correctly to say what the actual amount of it is.”
This assignment expressly directs the distribution to be ratable; these collaterals pass sub modo by the assignment to the assignee; and, in any proper or just sense, it is impossible to say what the real debt due the secured creditor was until he had sold his collaterals and applied the money in reduction of his debt, and that balance of debt thus remaining constitutes the debt upon which alone he can prove. We add, to approve them, the observations of Chief Justice Parker and of Chief Justice Shaw. The former said in Amory v. Francis, 16 Mass., 308: “If it were not so, the equality intended to be produced by the bankrupt laws would be grossly violated, and the creditor holding the pledge would in fact have a greater security than that pledge was intended to give him. Eor originally it would have been security only for a portion of the debt equal to its .value; whereas, by proving the whole debt and holding *473the pledge for the balance, it becomes security for as much more than its value as is the dividend which may be received upon the whole debt.” The latter said in Farnum v. Boutelle, 13 Metc. (Mass.), 159: “If the mortgage remained in force at the time of the decease of the debtor, then it is very clear, as well upon principle as upon authority, that the creditors cannot prove their debt without first waiving their mortgage, or in some mode applying the amount thereof to the reduction of the debt, and then proving only for the balance.”
It follows from these views that the decree is affirmed.
Caxhoon, J., dissented.