Slip Op. 05-19
United States Court of International Trade
ALLEGHENY LUDLUM CORP., J&L SPECIALTY
STEEL, INC., BUTLER ARMCO INDEPENDENT
UNION, UNITED STEELWORKERS OF AMERICA,
AFL-CIO/CLC, and ZANESVILLE ARMCO
INDEPENDENT ORGANIZATION,
Plaintiffs, Before: Pogue, Judge
Court No. 03-00919
v.
UNITED STATES,
Defendant,
and
THYSSENKRUPP ACCIAI SPECIALI TERNI,
S.p.A. AND THYSSENKRUPP AST USA,
Defendant-Intervenors.
[Commerce’s Determination remanded]
February 8, 2005
COLLIER SHANNON SCOTT, P.L.L.C. (David A. Hartquist, Kathleen W.
Cannon, Eric R. McClafferty), for Plaintiffs.
Peter D. Keisler, Assistant Attorney General, David M. Cohen,
Director, Jeanne E. Davidson, Assistant Director, David
D’Alessandris, Trial Attorney, Commercial Litigation Branch,
Civil Division, U.S. Department of Justice, Robert E. Nielsen,
Senior Attorney, Office of the Chief Counsel for Import
Administration, United States Department of Commerce, for
Defendant United States Department of Commerce.
HOGAN & HARTSON, L.L.P. (Lewis E. Leibowitz, Lynn G. Kamarck),
for Defendant-Intervenors.
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 2
POGUE, JUDGE: Plaintiff (“Allegheny”) seeks this Court’s review of
Commerce’s application of its latest methodology for determining
when the privatization of a foreign firm extinguishes a subsidy
that is the basis for a countervailing duty order. The case arises
from the privatization of the Italian state-owned steel group ILVA.
ILVA, during much of the 1980's and early 1990's, was subsidized by
the Government of Italy (“GOI”) through major restructurings and
bailouts.1 After investigating the subsidies, but prior to ILVA’s
privatization, the Department of Commerce (“Commerce”) issued an
order imposing countervailing duties on ILVA’s importations into
the United States. See Stainless Steel Sheet and Strip in Coils
from Italy, 64 Fed. Reg. 30,624 (Dep’t Commerce June 8, 1999)
(final affirmative countervailing duty determination). Plaintiff
now challenges Commerce’s determination that these subsidies were
extinguished upon the privatization of ILVA and, therefore, the
modification of the countervailing duty order. The Court finds
that Commerce’s determination is not supported by substantial
evidence and remands this determination for further consideration
consistent with this opinion.
1
In Acciai Speciali Terni S.p.A. v. United States, slip op.
04-140 (CIT Nov. 12, 2004), the court analyzed a case similar to
the one at issue here under a different Commerce methodology.
The court found that that methodology employed an impermissible
“per se” test. Id. at 21.
Court No. 03-00919 Page 3
BACKGROUND
ILVA’s privatization was initiated on December 12, 1992 when
the Italian Council of Ministers gave their approval for the
privatization. See Dep’t of Commerce Mem. from Deputy Assistant
Sec’y, Imp. Admin., Group I to James J. Jochum, Assistant Sec’y for
Imp. Admin., Re: Issues and Decision Memorandum for the
Determination under Section 129 of the Uruguay Round Agreements
(Oct. 24, 2003), P.R. Doc. No. 332, Pl.’s Ex. 1 (“Determination”)
at 3. The GOI established a holding company, Istituto per la
Riconstruzione Industriale (“IRI”), to initiate a restructuring and
privatization plan. Id. The plan called for the demerger of ILVA
into two corporations: AST (the entity in controversy in this case)
and ILVA Laminati Piani S.R.L. (“ILP”), and placed the remaining
assets and liabilities in ILVA Residua which was to be liquidated.
Id. To advise with the sale of AST, IRI hired a private
consultant, Barclays de Zoete Wedd Limited (“BZW”), and
commissioned a valuation study by Istituto Mobiliare Italino
S.p.A.(“IMI”). Id. at 3,5. IRI requested that the latter devise
a valuation of AST so as to provide an “appropriate” rate of return
to prospective purchasers. Istituto Mobiliare Itlaliano S.p.A.,
Company Appraisal of “Acciai Speciali Terni” (August 25, 1993),
2
Documents contained on the public record are cited as “PR,”
followed by the document list in which they are contained,
followed by the document number. Documents in the confidential
record are cited as “CR,” followed by the document list in which
they are contained, followed by the document number.
Court No. 03-00919 Page 4
Pl.’s Ex. 5 at 3.
In December 1993, IRI publicly announced its intention to sell
AST and ILP through advertisements in the Italian and foreign
newspapers. Determination, P.R. Doc. No. 33, Pl.’s Ex. 1 at 3.
Interested parties were required to submit information about
themselves such as copies of their incorporation and bylaws. Id.
at 3 n.4. In response, nineteen private industrial and financial
entities had expressed interest by January 7, 1994. Id. at 4.
During this period, the bulk of AST’s debt was placed in ILVA
Residua. Determination, P.R. Doc. No. 33, Pl.’s Ex. 1 at 8. IRI
also commissioned another valuation study, by Pasfin Servizi
Finanziari (“Pasfin”), to determine what price it could get for
AST. Id. at 5.
With nineteen potential bidders, IRI inaugurated the second
stage of the bidding process. Id. at 4. In this stage, IRI
required that the interested parties submit preliminary, non-
binding cash offers for 100 percent of AST’s shares. Id. Pursuant
to these requirements, four parties submitted non-binding purchase
offers. In March, IRI set forth the requirements for the final
stage of bidding, compelling submission of final offers by May 13,
1994 (allowing two months to conduct due diligence), see id., and
requiring a guarantee for the purchase of AST, see Dep’t of
Commerce Mem. from Deputy Assistant Sec’y, Imp. Admin., Group I to
James J. Jochum, Assistant Secretary for Imp. Admin., Re: Issues
Court No. 03-00919 Page 5
and Decision Memorandum for the Determination under Section 129 of
the Uruguay Round Agreements Act (Oct. 24, 2003), C.R. Doc. No. 11,
Pl.’s Ex. 9 (“Confidential Determination”) at 6. There is also a
suggestion in the record that IRI would favor bids from parties
that included Italian investors. Determination, P.R. Doc. No. 33,
Pl.’s Ex. 1 at 6. Only two parties submitted final bids: KAI
Italia S.r.L. (“KAI”) (Defendant-Intervenor TKAST’s predecessor in
interest) and Ugine (a French steel producer). Id. at 4. However,
IRI disqualified Ugine’s final bid as nonconforming with the
bidding requirements, because it did not bid for 100 percent of
AST’s shares, and thereby awarded the sale to KAI. Id. KAI, in
part, based its bid on a valuation study prepared by Morgan
Grenfell in May which it submitted as part of the Record.
Confidential Determination, C.R. Doc. No. 11, Pl.’s Ex. 9 at 7.
The amount bid for AST was well in excess of the two market
valuation studies prepared for AST and above that prepared by KAI’s
own consultant. Id. Additionally, after the final bids were
submitted and Ugine had been disqualified leaving KAI as the only
purchaser in the running, IRI empowered BZW to further negotiate
with KAI to improve the offer. Confidential Determination, C.R.
Doc. No. 11, Pl.’s Ex. 9 at 3. As a result of these negotiations,
KAI ended up paying more than it had bid for AST. Id.
Court No. 03-00919 Page 6
PROCEDURAL HISTORY
This case arises from an administrative review made pursuant
to Section 129 of the Uruguay Round Agreements Act, 19 U.S.C. §
3538 (2000) (“Section 129"). The Section 129 review followed the
World Trade Organization Appellate Body’s Decision (“WTO”) in
United States – Countervailing Measures Concerning Certain Products
from the European Communities, WT/DS212/AB/R (Dec. 9, 2002).
Section 129 authorizes Commerce to revise its determinations to
make them consistent with WTO decisions. See 19 U.S.C. § 3538(b).
Plaintiff brought a timely appeal of the Section 129 Determination
and the Court has jurisdiction over Allegheny’s complaint under 28
U.S.C. § 1581(c).
STANDARD OF REVIEW
The Court reviews Commerce’s decision to determine whether
it is supported by substantial evidence and in accordance with
law. 19 U.S.C. § 1516a(b)(1)(B)(2002).
DISCUSSION
Under Commerce’s new methodology for determining when the
privatization of a firm extinguishes a subsidy,3 Commerce creates
3
Promulgated in 2003, Commerce’s new methodology seeks to
address concerns raised by the Federal Circuit’s opinion in
Delverde Srl v. United States, 202 F.3d 1360, 1365 (Fed. Cir.
2000) (“Delverde III”) as well as by the WTO.
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 7
three stages of inquiry in which the presumption that a subsidy is
countervailable shifts between the importer and interested parties
looking to impose a countervailing duty. First, Commerce asks
whether a countervailable subsidy was conferred prior to the sale
of the company. Notice of Final Modification of Agency Practice
Under Section 123 of the Uruguay Round Agreements Act, 68 Fed. Reg.
37,125, 37,127 (Dep’t Commerce June 23, 2003) (“Methodology”). If
Commerce finds that a non-recurring subsidy was conferred, Commerce
creates a baseline presumption that the subsidy is countervailable
over the corresponding useful life of the recipient’s assets. Id.
Nevertheless, an interested party may rebut this presumption
where that party demonstrates that a “privatization occurred in
which the government sold its ownership of all or substantially all
of a company or its assets . . . and that the sale was an arm’s-
length transaction4 for fair market value.” Id. (emphasis added).
If the sale was not an arm’s-length transaction for fair market
value, Commerce will find that the presumption has not been
overcome and the subsidy will remain countervailable. Conversely,
if Commerce concludes that the sale was at arm’s-length for fair
4
The definition of an arm’s-length transaction used by
Commerce is “a transaction negotiated between unrelated parties,
each acting in its own self-interest, or between related parties
such that the terms of the transaction are those that would exist
if the transaction had been negotiated between unrelated
parties.” Determination, P.R. Doc. No. 33, Pl.’s Ex. 1 at 4-5.
Neither this definition nor Commerce’s finding that the sale
occurred at arm’s-length is at issue in this case.
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 8
market value, any “pre-sale subsidies will be presumed to be
extinguished in their entirety and, therefore, non-
countervailable.” Id.
Despite a finding that the assets have been sold at arm’s-
length for fair market value, an interested party may rebut this
latter presumption of extinguishment upon a demonstration that “at
the time of the privatization, the broader market conditions
necessary for the transaction price to reflect fairly and
accurately the subsidy and benefit were not present, or were
severely distorted by government action (or, where appropriate,
inaction),” id. (footnote omitted), such that “the transaction
price was meaningfully different from what it would otherwise have
been absent the distortive government action,” id. at 37,128. If
a party demonstrates that broader market distortions existed, the
subsidy will remain countervailable; if a party does not
demonstrate such distortions, the duties will be deemed
extinguished. Id.
In this case, TKAST concedes that AST did receive non-
recurring countervailable subsidies from the GOI; therefore, this
issue is not in dispute. However, TKAST submits that the
presumption that the subsidy remained countervailable was overcome
by the sale of AST in an arm’s-length transaction for fair-market
value and that distorting factors did not upset an inference that
the sale extinguished the subsidy. Allegheny does not challenge
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 9
Commerce’s methodology. Rather, Allegheny contends that Commerce’s
determinations violated its own methodology and are not supported
by substantial evidence as discussed below.
A. THE SIGNIFICANCE OF A FAIR MARKET VALUE DETERMINATION
Under the countervailing duty law, a firm receives a subsidy
if it gets something it did not pay for, i.e., when a government
sells assets for less remuneration than the assets are worth, the
buyer receives a benefit from that government. See 19 U.S.C. §
1677(5)(E)(iv) (a benefit includes the sale of goods “provided for
less than adequate remuneration”); cf. United States – Imposition
of Countervailing Duties on Certain Hot-Rolled Lead and Bismuth
Carbon Steel Products Originating in the United Kingdom,
WT/DS138/AB/R (May 10, 2000) at 25 (“The question whether a
‘financial contribution’ confers a ‘benefit’ depends, therefore, on
whether the recipient has received a ‘financial contribution’ on
terms more favorable than those available to the recipient in the
market.”). As applied to the purchase of a firm which has received
a prior subsidy, if a buyer does not remunerate the government for
the value of the company plus the value of the subsidy at the time
of purchase, then the buyer receives a benefit. For example, if a
firm is valued at $100 million, and the government contributes a
$50 million value to the firm, then the value of the firm is $150
million (assuming no depreciation or appreciation between the time
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 10
of the subsidy and sale and that the contribution actually
conferred an economic value of $50 million5).
The fair market value of the company takes into account all of
a company’s liabilities and assets including assets that were
incurred with government support. Therefore, the payment of fair
market value means that the purchasing firm did not receive more
than it paid for (assuming the government did not distort the
market in a manner affecting the sale.) That the aggregation of
the monetary amount of past subsidies is not an appropriate
benchmark for whether the purchase price reflected the value of the
subsidies has been firmly established and warrants no further
consideration here. See Acciai Speciali Terni S.p.A. v. United
States, slip op. 04-140 at 21 & n.13 (CIT Nov. 12, 2004), Allegheny
Ludlum Corp. v. United States, 246 F. Supp. 2d 1304, 1310, 26 CIT
___, ___, (2002).
Appropriately, Commerce’s inquiry focuses on whether the sale
price was at fair market value. When a company or assets are sold
under a transparent competitive bidding system, the potential
5
The observation that the value of a given subsidy may have
depreciated, or not have conferred future value to a firm, was
discussed in Allegheny Ludlum Corp. v. United States, 246 F.
Supp. 2d 1304, 1310, 26 CIT ___, ___, (2002). That a subsidy may
not confer an actual economic value equal to the monetary amount
of the subsidy simply reflects the reality that the government
often has other interests than economic profit such as full
employment or granting favor to certain constituents. For
example, the government may have provided the upkeep of obsolete
facilities to keep workers employed even though such upkeep would
not be justified in terms of cost feasibility.
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 11
buyers will, at least theoretically, push the purchase price to its
fair market value. Therefore, the winning firm will not get more
value than that for which it paid.6 However, this theoretical
analysis assumes that the bidding process will drive the sale price
so as to reflect the value of the company (including the subsidy)
and its assets. This assumption is somewhat precarious under the
facts and circumstances of a privatization. The seller, a
government which has manifested an interest in conferring benefits
on domestic industries by virtue of past subsidies, may have
motives other than recouping the highest price for the company and
its assets, and therefore may constrain or manipulate the sales
process to benefit domestic industries or serve some other
governmental interests. Delverde III, 202 F.3d at 1369. One
cannot simply assume that the invisible hand of the market will
work its magic where there are so many interests at work and the
hand of the government is so visible. See United States –
Countervailing Measures Concerning Certain Products from the
European Communities, WT/DS212/AB/R (Dec. 9, 2002) at 61 (during
privatizations “market conditions are not necessarily always
6
This assumes, among other things, that the threat of
countervailing duties is not factored into the purchase price.
If they are, the purchase price will be reduced. Therefore, if
the United States does not impose countervailing duties, the
purchaser will obtain a windfall, i.e., the amount of money that
buyers thought would be countervailed. This point was not
addressed by either party and the Court will not raise it sua
sponte.
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 12
present and they are often dependent on government action.”). That
the sale process may be open to manipulation, or otherwise
distorted, is recognized by 19 U.S.C. § 1677(5)(F) and case law.7
See, e.g., Allegheny Ludlum v. United States, 367 F.3d 1339 (Fed.
Cir. 2004), cf. Saarstahl AG v. United States, 78 F.3d 1539, 1544
(Fed. Cir. 1996). Both require Commerce to look behind a sale to
ensure that competitive bids were made, and that the government did
not distort the terms of the sale, such that the sale price truly
reflected the value of the privatized company or assets as would be
assigned by the market in a sale between private parties under the
terms of the sale. Cf. Allegheny, 367 F.3d at 1347.
Commerce’s new methodology recognizes this concern insofar as
it frames “the basic question [of whether a subsidy has been
extinguished as] whether the full amount that the company or its
assets (including the value of any subsidy benefits) were actually
worth under prevailing market conditions was paid, and paid through
monetary or equivalent compensation.” Methodology, 68 Fed. Reg. at
37,127. Accordingly, “[a] primary consideration in this regard
normally will be whether the government failed to maximize its
7
Pursuant to 19 U.S.C. § 1677(5)(F):
A change in ownership of all or part of a foreign
enterprise or the productive assets of a foreign
enterprise does not by itself require a determination by
the administering authority that a past countervailable
subsidy received by the enterprise no longer continues to
be countervailable, even if the change in ownership is
accomplished through an arm's length transaction.
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 13
return on what it sold, indicating that the purchaser paid less for
the company or assets than it otherwise would have had the
government acted in a manner consistent with the normal sales
practices of private, commercial sellers in that country.”8 To
conduct this inquiry, the new methodology sanctions two approaches:
(1) an inductive approach, using a benchmark analysis wherein
Commerce compares the sales price with “comparable benchmark
prices” and (2) a deductive approach using a process of sale
analysis wherein Commerce looks at “process factors” to determine
if the sale was manipulated or distorted such that the bid accepted
by the government would not reflect the fair market value of the
company or assets. Id.
In this case, Commerce made a threshold determination that the
sale was at arm’s-length because the seller, AST, and the
purchaser, TKAST, were unrelated. Determination, P.R. Doc. No. 33,
Pl.’s Ex. 1 at 4-5. Accordingly, it proceeded into its second line
of analysis to determine whether the arm’s-length sale was at fair
market value. Commerce concluded that there was “no evidence in
the record of any contemporaneous sales of companies comparable to
AST nor any appropriate market benchmark price.” Determination,
P.R. Doc. No. 33, Pl.’s Ex. 1 at 5. Consequently, Commerce,
8
The Court notes that Commerce did not discuss the norm
regarding the sale of steel companies, or any company, in Italy
or elsewhere. Without this benchmark, it becomes difficult for a
Court to review a determination that a given sale process is, or
is not, atypical.
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 14
applying its methodology, was to base its conclusion solely on
whether it could infer that fair market value was paid from the
manner AST was sold. In considering the sale process, Commerce
identified a non-exhaustive list of factors: (1) Did the government
perform an objective analysis of the value of the company? (2) Were
there artificial barriers to entry which precluded potential
competitors from not participating in the process? (3) Did the
government accept the highest bid? and (4) Were there committed
investment requirements?9 Determination, P.R. Doc. No. 33, Pl.’s
Ex. 1 at 5 (citing Methodology 68 Fed. Reg. at 37,127).
Looking at these factors, Commerce observed that there were
9
Allegheny at times attempts to read the methodology
strictly and, under this strict reading, alleges that Commerce
did not apply its own methodology to the facts. For example, at
one point Allegheny claims that a government must “accept the
highest bid” to extinguish the subsidy. See Pl.’s Rule 56.2 Mem.
Law Supp. Mot. J. Agency R., at 18-19 (“Pl.’s Mem.”). According
to Allegheny, given that the word “highest” is a word of
comparison, because the GOI only considered one bid, its
acceptance thereof could not have been the acceptance of the
“highest” bid. Therefore, according to Allegheny, the
methodology requires a finding that the subsidy was not
extinguished because the GOI did not accept the “highest bid.”
The Court considers this hyper-technical reading of the
methodology unpersuasive. These factors are non-exhaustive and
are intended to assist Commerce in determining whether fair
market value was paid which it is required to do by law;
moreover, these factors must be read in a manner that promotes
the ultimate goal of determining whether fair market value was
paid. Application of the factors enunciated in Commerce’s new
methodology, without regard to how these factors promote the
ultimate goal of determining whether fair market value was paid,
is a misapplication of Commerce’s methodology, Methodology, 68
Fed. Reg. at 37,127, and accordingly is not in accordance with
law, Allegheny Ludlum, 367 F.3d at 1344.
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 15
some anomalies in the sale of AST. Most significantly, although
the bidding process started with nineteen interested firms, all the
firms except TKAST dropped out of the competition or were
disqualified. Determination, P.R. Doc. No. 33, Pl.’s Ex. 1 at 4.
More specifically, the GOI (a) required bidders to guarantee their
bids, Confidential Determination, C.R. Doc. No. 11, Pl.’s Ex. 9 at
6; (b) gave a short period to conduct due diligence, Determination,
P.R. Doc. No. 33, Pl.’s Ex. 1 at 6; (c) turned over incomplete
documents to the bidders, Confidential Determination, C.R. Doc. No.
11, Pl.’s Ex. 9 at 5; (d) may have required the winning firm to
have a partnership with an Italian firm,10 Determination, P.R. Doc.
No. 33, Pl.’s Ex. 1 at 6; and (e) required committed investments
such as restrictions on alienation and maintenance of production
and employment at certain levels, Confidential Determination, C.R.
Doc. No. 11, Pl.’s Ex. 9 at 7-8. Commerce found that these
restrictions may have deterred firms, especially foreign firms,
from bidding on AST. Determination, P.R. Doc. No. 33, Pl.’s Ex. 1
at 6. Nonetheless, Commerce found that these factors did not
seriously distort the sales process and that the sale price was
higher than that reflected in objective valuation studies conducted
by third parties. Determination, P.R. Doc. No. 33, Pl.’s Ex. 1 at
5, 12, Confidential Determination, C.R. Doc. No. 11, Pl.’s Ex. 9
10
Commerce did not make a definitive factual finding in this
regard. Commerce noted that there was suspicion that this was
the case. Determination, P.R. Doc. No. 33, Pl.’s Ex. 1 at 6.
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 16
at 7. As Commerce concluded:
On the one hand, there were some real and perceived
barriers in the bidding process that might have limited
the number of potential purchasers. On the other hand,
there is substantial record evidence that the
privatization of AST was accomplished through a fair-
market-value transaction.
Id. at 8. Allegheny alleges that Commerce’s analysis does not
comport with its methodology and its conclusion is unsupported by
substantial evidence. The Court disagrees with Allegheny’s former
contention but agrees that Commerce’s decision is not supported by
substantial evidence.
i. PROCESS FACTORS DO NOT SUPPORT AN INFERENCE THAT FAIR
MARKET VALUE WAS TENDERED
The Court agrees with Allegheny that an inference that the
sale process resulted in a sale at fair market value is not
supported by substantial evidence as explicated by Commerce in its
determination. Allegheny contends that if TKAST’s competitors had
dropped out of the competition, a rational bidder would not be
induced to offer the full market value for the company. Pl.’s Mem.
at 18; cf. Enserco, L.L.C. v. Drilling Rig Noram 253, 126 F. Supp.
2d 443, 447 (S.D. Tex. 2000). TKAST and Commerce counter that
Allegheny has not accurately summarized the facts. See
Determination, P.R. Doc. No. 33, Pl.’s Ex. 1 at 12. Rather, when
TKAST bid for AST, at least one other bidder was still in the
competition and submitted a final bid (although later it was
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 17
rejected). Id.
Theoretically, at least where bidding is in a one-time winner-
take-all auction form, a competitor is induced to bid its valuation
of the company. Given that bidders only bid once under such an
auction model, a competitor cannot rebid a higher price if its
competitors outbid it. Therefore, assuming bidder A has no
knowledge of its opponent’s bid, if bidder A does not bid close to
the valuation of the company, another bidder will win, and bidder
A will lose the competition (and therefore a financial
opportunity). Consequently, TKAST contends, with the specter of
competition looming, TKAST had every incentive to bid a price it
considered to be fair market value. The Court agrees with TKAST
and Commerce that a reasonable inference can be drawn that TKAST
had an incentive to bid its valuation of AST. See Determination,
P.R. Doc. No. 33, Pl.’s Ex. 1 at 12.
However, the Court also agrees with Allegheny that this fact
alone is insufficient to prove that the sale price reflected the
fair market value of AST in light of Commerce’s findings that there
were real and perceived barriers in the bidding process. Because
of these barriers, the process itself does not provide a basis to
conclude that the GOI maximized the return on what it sold to
justify a fair market value determination. There is too much
uncertainty. TKAST may have bid in good faith on what it perceived
fair market value to be; however, it may have had special
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 18
knowledge, it may have wrongly assessed AST’s assets, or it may not
have been in the position to offer fair market value, such that in
a situation with multiple bidders, its bid would have been woefully
inadequate. This concern is particularly acute here, where the
short period of time permitted to conduct due diligence was
acknowledged by a bidder as a significant obstacle in crafting a
reliable valuation of AST. Confidential Determination, C.R. Doc.
No. 11, Pl.’s Ex. 9 at 5. Because of this complication, the Court
agrees with Allegheny that Commerce’s analysis of the sale process,
by itself, cannot support a reasonable inference that fair market
value was tendered, especially given that TKAST must overcome the
presumption that prior subsidies remain countervailable.
ii. OBJECTIVE VALUATIONS AND THE CONCLUSION THAT FAIR MARKET
VALUE WAS TENDERED
Commerce implicitly recognized this short-coming and proposed
an additional justification that the sale price was at, or above,
fair market value. See Determination, P.R. Doc. No. 33, Pl.’s Ex.
1 at 12 (“However, as discussed in the Analysis section above, we
continue to find that certain other aspects of the bidding process
might have served to limit the number of bidders. Nevertheless,
the three independent valuations of AST show that the GOI received
fair market value for AST . . . . The valuations provide relevant
evidence that the real or perceived restrictions did not result in
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 19
a non-competitive skewed process.”).11 Commerce looked at three
independent valuation studies of AST conducted by disinterested
third parties. Finding that the sale price was above AST’s
valuation in these studies, Commerce concluded that at least fair
market value was tendered by TKAST. Determination, P.R. Doc. No.
33, Pl.’s Ex. 1 at 12, Confidential Determination, C.R. Doc. No.
11, Pl.’s Ex. 9 at 9.
Before proceeding to analyze whether Commerce’s conclusion is
supported by substantial evidence, the Court notes that Commerce
discussed this as part of its “objective analysis” of its process
of sale analysis. According to the Court’s reading of Commerce’s
methodology, the process of sale analysis looks into the manner the
sale was conducted.12 Consequently, following Commerce’s “process”
11
The Court further notes that the Determination’s
discussion on fair market value incorporates the Confidential
Determination, Determination, P.R. Doc. No. 33, Pl.’s Ex. 1 at 4,
which placed weight on the fact that the bid was above the
valuation studies’ estimate, Confidential Determination, C.R.
Doc. No. 11, Pl.’s Ex. 9 at 9.
12
By way of comparison, 19 U.S.C. § 1592(e) authorizes
Customs to seek damages against parties who negligently or
fraudulently misclassify their products entering the United
States. According to the case law, a defendant may assert a
defense that he acted with reasonable care, inter alia, if he
obtained the advice of counsel, and relied on that advice, in
classifying his products. United States v. Optrex Am., Inc.,
slip op. 04-79 (CIT July 1, 2004). In allowing this defense, the
case law is not suggesting that counsel’s advice was accurate –
rather, if the Government is prosecuting a claim, most likely
that advice was wholly erroneous. Rather, it is the fact that
advice of counsel was sought which demonstrates that the
defendant exercised reasonable care. In other words, it is the
process of seeking advice that is probative, not the actual
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 20
methodology, it is the fact that a government sought objective
valuations, and relied on those valuations, that is important. But
by using the valuations to prove the sale price was for fair market
value, Commerce is comparing a resulting sale price to a benchmark.
Commerce is not using the valuations to prove the validity of the
procedure used to sell the company. In so doing, Commerce opens
the door to claims that the valuation studies were inaccurate.13
Moreover, by opening the door to a claim that it was not following
its own methodology, Commerce undermines its own contention that
there were no “benchmarks” by which to compare the sale price. In
fact there were: the valuation studies.
Setting aside this methodological objection, Allegheny seeks
to discredit the valuations as having been engineered by the GOI to
boost projections of future rates of return at the expense of
devaluing the present value of AST.14 In assessing Allegheny’s
advice received.
13
The accuracy of the valuations may, or may not, be
relevant to whether a government sought objective advice and
reasonably relied on those valuations.
14
At oral argument, the Government and TKAST argued that
Allegheny did not raise this argument before Commerce and waited
until its reply brief to raise the argument in this proceeding.
The Court agrees that arguments not raised before Commerce may
not be raised before a reviewing court and that a party may not
raise an argument for the first time in its reply brief.
However, the Court deems that Allegheny adequately raised this
argument below, see Petitioner’s Case Brief, Attachment to Letter
from David A. Hartquist, Kathleen W. Cannon & Eric R.
McClafferty, Collier Shannon Scott, PLLC, to Sec’y of Commerce,
Re: Stainless Steel Sheet and Strip in Coils from Italy, C.R.
Doc. No. 9 at 12-14 (Sept. 26, 2003)at 12-14, and adequately
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 21
argument, the Court is mindful that courts grant considerable
deference to an agency’s review of valuation studies. Cf. New
Haven Inclusion Cases, 399 U.S. 392, 434-35 (1970) (“‘The judicial
function is to see to it that the Commission’s ‘estimate’ is not a
mere ‘guess’ but rests upon an informed judgment based upon an
appraisal of all . . . relevant . . . facts . . . , and is not at
variance with the statutory command.’”) (quoting Freeman v.
Mulcahy, 250 F.2d 463, 473 (1st Cir. 1957)) with Allegheny, 367
F.3d at 1344 (noting the Commerce must consider all the facts and
circumstances behind a privatization). Consideration of valuation
studies requires extensive fact finding and expertise a court does
not have when reviewing agency determinations. This does not mean
that agencies have carte blanche to ignore facts, misread studies,
or otherwise use valuation studies such that their factual findings
are unsupported by substantial evidence. Id. The agency must
explain its rationale in adopting a valuation study such that a
court may follow and review its line of analysis, its reasonable
assumptions, and other relevant considerations. Id.
Granting this deference owed to Commerce, the Court
nonetheless finds that, in this case, Commerce has not adequately
explained its adoption of the valuation studies, especially in
light of Allegheny’s objections. In its determination, Commerce
raised this argument in its initial brief before the Court, Pl.’s
Mem. at 21-27.
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 22
noted that “[w]e consider these studies timely as they were
conducted prior to the agreement on the final transaction price.
Further, the studies are objective and complete since they were
conducted by independent parties and contained information
typically considered by sellers contemplating such a sale.”
Determination, P.R. Doc. No. 33, Pl.’s Ex. 1 at 5. Allegheny
challenges the IMI study’s write-down of certain assets and
addition of certain “provisions” to AST’s balance sheet, and claims
that the two subsequent studies adopted these distorted values.
Pl.’s Mem. at 21-27. Commerce did not address these concerns in
its Determination.15 Nor did Commerce make a determination that the
studies reflected any of the committed investment requirements or
that the concurrent subsidies were reflected in the IMI or Pasfin
studies.16
15
In its market distortion analysis, Commerce argues that it
does not have to address the GOI decisions about which assets and
liabilities to place in AST because these decisions were not in
the nature of a governmental function or governmental regulation
but instead were similar to the action of a private seller.
Determination, P.R. Doc. No. 33, Pl.’s Ex. 1 at 14. This
response does not in any way validate Commerce’s decision to rely
on the valuations in determining fair market value.
16
The Court is mindful that Commerce only made an explicit
finding that the Morgan Grenfell valuation study considered AST’s
debt after AST’s debt write-down in December. See Confidential
Determination, C.R. Doc. No. 11, Pl.’s Ex. 9 at 7. Commerce
never indicated that the other two studies included the
concurrent subsidies or that any of the studies contemplated any
committed investment requirements. Cf. Confidential
Determination, C.R. Doc. No. 11, Pl.’s Ex. 9 at 7. The fair
market price for AST should reflect AST’s “core value” combined
with the value of any prior and concurrent subsidies (subsidies
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 23
It is not inappropriate for Commerce to rely on valuation
studies when, and to the extent, these valuation studies consider
all of the facts and circumstances of the value of a privatized
firm.17 However, when a valuation study, or valuations studies,
have not considered all the facts and circumstances, reliance
thereon is misplaced. Cf. Delverde III, 202 F.3d at 1367. Because
a court does ”not defer to the agency’s conclusory or unsupported
suppositions,” McDonnell Douglas Corp. v. United States Dept. of
the Air Force, 375 F.3d 1182, 1187 (D.C. Cir. 2004) (citing Motor
Vehicle Mfrs. Ass’n of United States, Inc. v. State Farm Mut. Auto.
Ins. Co., 463 U.S. 29, 43 (1983)), Commerce’s adoption of these
conferred during the privatization of a company) and committed
investment requirements. Accordingly, the prior subsidy and
concurrent subsidy analyses are inextricably linked when Commerce
infers fair market value from valuation studies. Consequently,
either the purchasing firm remunerated the government for of all
of these values or did not remunerate the government for all of
these values. Moreover, the Court notes that although some
conclusions may be logically deducible from the facts, e.g., that
the committed investments would lower the valuation therefore any
error would be harmless or that the IMI study was based on the
same level of debt write-off that actually occurred five months
after the study was commissioned, Commerce must make these
considerations explicit. Cf. Siderca v. United States, slip op.
04-133 (Oct. 27, 2004) at 29 n.15 (noting that the Court should
not be left to guess if Commerce considered certain facts and how
it reached its conclusions); see also infra note 18.
17
The Court is not implying that Commerce must accept or
reject a valuation study in total. Rather, it may be appropriate
for Commerce to adopt such portions as it deems relevant, add,
and detract values so as to determine the true valuation of
assets.
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 24
studies cannot be grounded in substantial evidence.18 Furthermore,
whatever the merits of Commerce’s and TKAST’s arguments before the
Court, such arguments cannot be a substitute for a reasoned
decision by the agency on the record. Al Tech Specialty Steel
Corp. v. United States, slip op. 04-114 at 51 (CIT Sept. 8, 2004)
18
Other anomalies give the Court pause. First, the price
TKAST bid for AST was actually higher than the valuation range
provided by the study it commissioned and the price it eventually
paid was significantly higher than the maximum valuation for AST.
Confidential Determination, C.R. Doc. No. 11, Pl.’s Ex. 9 at 7.
Second, IRI did not rely very heavily on its valuation studies.
After receiving a bid that was noticeably higher than the
projected value for AST, Confidential Determination, C.R. Doc.
No. 11, Pl.’s Ex. 9 at 7, IRI then proceeded to negotiate a price
for the following months, id. at 3. This does suggest that IRI
was interested in securing the highest obtainable price for AST,
but also, that it did not place great weight on the studies. At
oral argument, TKAST presented an explanation for this, i.e.,
that during the post-bidding negotiations changes occurred which
may have changed the value of the assets on the table. Oral
Argument Before Judge Donald C. Pogue in Allegheny Ludlum v.
United States, Jan. 18, 2005 at 1:58:56 (statement of Lewis E.
Leibowitz). However, this explanation did not appear in the
Determination and therefore constitutes a post-hoc
rationalization. Moreover, TKAST’s argument casts doubt on
whether any of the valuation studies was completely based on the
transaction that actually occurred. If there were negotiations
regarding the assets TKAST would assume, which changed from the
assets the valuation studies valued, then these valuation studies
could not have been “complete” or “timely.” To make a
determination as to whether a valuation study is timely or
complete, Commerce must make an express determination that a
valuation study valued the total package being sold, adjust the
valuation study to reflect the total package being sold, or
explain why any changes between the assets considered in the
valuation study did not materially deviate from the valuation of
the assets sold, if it wants to rely on valuation studies. In
sum, Commerce must make a determination that no benefit was
conferred because the purchaser fully remunerated the government
for the “package” of assets acquired – whatever form the
subsidy/subsidies assume(s). See 19 U.S.C. 1677(5)(B) &
(E)(iv); see also Delverde, 202 F.3d at 1364-67.
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 25
(citing Burlington Truck Lines, Inc. v. United States, 371 U.S.
156, 168-69 (1962)). Accordingly, the Court remands this case to
Commerce to consider Allegheny’s objections to the valuation
studies.19
B. IF FAIR MARKET VALUE WAS CONFERRED, ALLEGHENY HAS NOT OVERCOME
THE PRESUMPTION THAT FAIR MARKET VALUE EXTINGUISHED THE SUBSIDY
If Commerce concludes that fair market value has been
tendered, the presumption shifts, i.e., the presumption then
becomes that the subsidy was extinguished, but the presumption, in
turn, may be rebutted upon a showing that the sale process was
distorted through government intervention. Methodology 68 Fed.
Reg. at 37,127. The Methodology defines this consideration as
follows:
A party can, however, obviate this presumption of
extinguishment by demonstrating that, at the time of the
privatization, the broader market conditions[] necessary
for the transaction price to reflect fairly and
accurately the subsidy benefit were not present, or were
severely distorted by government action (or, where
appropriate, inaction).[] In other words, even if we
find that the sales price was at "market value," parties
can demonstrate that the broader market conditions were
severely distorted by the government and that the
transaction price was meaningfully different from what it
would otherwise have been absent the distortive
government action.
19
Allegheny has also raised objections as to Commerce’s
concurrent subsidies methodology. Because the Court has
considered concurrent subsidies in context of the prior subsidies
analysis, the Court deems any further discussion unnecessary
until Commerce issues a remand determination. Allegheny may
raise any properly preserved arguments at that time.
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 26
Id. (footnotes omitted); cf. United States – Countervailing
Measures Concerning Certain Products from the European Communities,
WT/DS212/AB/R (Dec. 9, 2002) at 62 (“However, governments may
choose to impose economic or other policies that, albeit respectful
of the market’s inherent functioning, are intended to induce
certain results from the market.”). The regulations further
specify what types of distortions will rebut the presumption that
fair market value has been extinguished:
1. Basic Conditions: For example, are the basic
requirements for a properly functioning market
sufficiently present in the economy in general as well as
in the particular industry or sector, including free
interplay of supply and demand, broad-based and equal
access to information, sufficient safeguards against
collusive behavior, effective operation of the rule of
law, and adequate enforcement of contracts and property
rights?
2. Legal and Fiscal Incentives: Has the government used
the prerogatives of government in a special or targeted
way that makes possible, or otherwise significantly
distorts the terms of, a sale in a way that a private
seller could not, e.g., through special tax or duty rates
that make the sale more attractive to potential
purchasers generally or to particular (e.g., domestic)
purchasers, through regulatory exemptions particular to
the privatization (or privatizations generally) affecting
worker retention or environmental remediation, or through
subsidization or support of other companies to an extent
that severely distorts the normal market signals
regarding company and asset values in the industry in
question?
Id.
Allegheny contends that through repeated bailouts and other
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 27
manipulations of the Italian steel sector, the GOI distorted the
market. Pl.’s Mem. at 28-31. Allegheny asserts that, without
government assistance, AST would have gone bankrupt long before its
privatization. Id. at 29-30. Although this consideration is not
a type of distortion envisioned by the methodology, because
Commerce must consider all of the facts and circumstances of a
privatization, the Court will read Commerce’s methodology broadly
and will consider all distortions raised by the parties that may be
lawfully considered relevant. See Fiskars, Inc. v. Hunt Mfg. Co.,
221 F.3d 1318, 1322 (Fed. Cir. 2000) (noting the presumption that
agencies act in accordance with law); see also Methodology Fed.
Reg. at 37,127 (noting the list includes only “some factors” that
might be considered). Nevertheless, even under this reading of
Commerce’s methodology, the Court is not persuaded that Allegheny’s
arguments are sufficient to carry its burden.
First, under countervailing duty law, the inquiry focuses on
whether a purchasing firm received a financial contribution and
benefit. See Delverde III, 202 F.3d at 1367 (the statute requires
“Commerce to make a determination that a purchaser of corporate
assets received both a financial contribution and benefit from a
government, albeit indirectly through the seller, before concluding
that the purchaser was subsidized.”) (emphasis added), cf. Uruguay
Round Trade Agreements Act Statement of Administrative Action, H.
Doc. 103-316 at 257 (1994) (“subparagraph (E) reflects the
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 28
‘benefit-to-the-recipient’ standard which long has been a
fundamental basis for identifying and measuring subsidies under
U.S. CVD practice, and which is expressly endorsed by Article 14 of
the Subsidies Agreement.”). When a sale is for fair market value,
the true value of the subsidy has, at least theoretically, been
factored into the purchase price. At this price, a purchaser whose
reservation price is at fair market value should be indifferent to
buying the company or assets or investing its money elsewhere.
Consequently, the purchaser would not be the receiver of this
“benefit” as required by law.
For example, a government may build a state-of-the-art
facility for the production of widgets even though the factor costs
in that country, e.g., labor or resource costs, place that country
at a significant comparative disadvantage in the operation of the
facility. When the government sells the facility, theoretically,
these high factor costs will be considered in the purchase price –
they will depress the purchase price (from the construction price)
to reflect these high factor costs. The ultimate purchaser does
not necessarily receive a benefit because it pays the value of the
facility given market conditions (assuming the facility is sold
under competitive market conditions) – the market should price the
facility at the point where it is just profitable enough to justify
the operation of the facility. At least part of the money the
government spent would be a sunk cost (and sunk benefit) and does
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 29
not confer a benefit on the purchaser. Cf. Certain Steel Products
from Austria, 58 Fed. Reg. 37,217, 37,264 (DOC July 9, 1993) (final
affirmative countervailing duty determination).20
Second, as the WTO Appellate Body has recently concluded:
[O]nce a fair market price is paid for the equipment, its
market value is redeemed, regardless of the utility the
firm may derive from the equipment. Accordingly, it is
the market value of the equipment that is the focal point
of analysis, and not the equipment’s utility value to the
privatized firm.
United States – Countervailing Measures Concerning Certain
Products from the European Communities, WT/DS212/AB/R (Dec. 9,
2002) at 51. In this case, given that Commerce’s methodology
and its Section 129 determination are intended to implement
WTO rulings, this factor is relevant. See SEC v. Chenery
Corp., 318 U.S. 80, 87 (1943) (“The grounds upon which an
administrative order must be judged are those upon which the
record discloses that its action was based.”). Additionally,
the WTO Appellate Body decisions have persuasive weight here
20
The Court has some discomfort with the fact that a
government may induce its industry to compete against U.S.
industries through use of devices such as committed investment
requirements. For example, by a government requiring a company
to maintain production for a period of time, and so reducing the
purchase price to make this feasible, that government is
injecting distortions into the international market, i.e.,
creating potential competition that would not exist but for
government intervention. Nevertheless, the Court is constrained
by the case law to disregard this type of distortion because
there is no benefit to the purchasing firm. Such constraint,
however, does not limit the requirement that Commerce determine
that no benefit be conferred on the purchasing firm.
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 30
because nonconformance of U.S. practice may result in
retaliatory tariffs against U.S. exporters – a result that
negates the U.S.’s benefit from the international agreement.
Cf. McCulloch v. Sociedad Nacional de Marineros de Honduras,
372 U.S. 10, 21 (1963). Accordingly, were the agency to
construe an ambiguous statute so as to benefit domestic
interests in violation of international agreements,
retaliatory tariffs would result, a penalty which Congress
presumably would wish to avoid. Consequently, courts should
prefer adhering to international law standards unless
otherwise indicated by Congress. See, e.g., id. at 20-21; cf.
The Federalist No. 3, at 43 (John Jay) (Clinton Rossiter ed.,
1961) (“It is of high importance to the peace of America that
she observe the laws of nations towards [its treaty partners],
and to me it appears evident that this will be more perfectly
and punctually done by one national government . . . .); see
also Allegheny, 367 F.3d at 1348 (citing Murray v. Charming
Betsy, 6 U.S. (2 Cranch) 64, 118 (1804)) (“an act of Congress
ought never to be construed to violate the law of nations if
any other possible construction remains . . . as understood in
this country.”); Federal Mogul Corp. v. United States, 63
F.3d 1572, 1582 (Fed. Cir. 1995). Because Congress has not
statutorily created an unavoidable conflict with the WTO, cf.
The Chinese Exclusion Case, 130 U.S. 581 (1889), there exists
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 31
no reason not to look to the WTO for assistance in
interpreting U.S. law. See 19 U.S.C. § 3512 (“no provision of
any of the Uruguay Round Agreements, nor the application of
any such provision to any person or circumstance, that is
inconsistent with any law of the United States shall have
effect”) (emphasis added).
Allegheny appears to base its distortion argument not on
the market value, but on the utility value of these past
distortions. Based on the record as it stands, the Court
cannot conclude that these past distortions can provide a
basis to overcome the presumption that a purchase at fair
market value extinguished the subsidy.
CONCLUSION
Commerce’s determination that fair market value was tendered
is not supported by substantial evidence. On remand, Commerce must
reconsider its determination consistent with this opinion. If
Commerce continues to rely on the valuations studies, Commerce
should justify its use of the valuation studies in face of
Allegheny’s challenges. Finally, Commerce must reconsider its
analysis of concurrent subsidies in accordance with this opinion.
Commerce shall have until May 9, 2005 to submit its remand
determination. The parties shall have until May 23, 2005 to submit
comments on the remand determination. Rebuttal comments shall be
Court. No. 03-00919 Page 32
submitted by June 6, 2005.
SO ORDERED.
/s/ Donald C. Pogue
Donald C. Pogue, Judge
February 8, 2005
New York, New York