December 31 2008
05-146
IN THE SUPREME COURT OF THE STATE OF MONTANA
2008 MT 460
KIM J. KAFKA and CINDY R. KAFKA, Individually and as Husband and Wife; and as
members of DIAMOND K RANCH ENTERPRISES LLC, a Montana Limited Liability
Company,
Plaintiffs and Appellants,
and
JACK BRIDGEWATER and MYRA BRIDGEWATER, Individually and as members of
PHANTOM BULL ELK RANCH LLC, and JIM BOUMA and BARBARA BOUMA,
Plaintiff-Intervenors and Appellants,
v.
THE MONTANA DEPARTMENT OF FISH, WILDLIFE AND PARKS, and THE STATE OF
MONTANA,
Defendants and Appellees,
and
SPORTSMEN FOR I-143, MONTANA WILDLIFE FEDERATION,
Defendant-Intervenors and Appellees.
APPEAL FROM: District Court of the Twelfth Judicial District,
In and For the County of Hill, Cause No. DV 2002-059
Honorable David G. Rice, Presiding Judge
COUNSEL OF RECORD:
For Appellants:
John E. Bloomquist (argued), Abigail J. St. Lawrence, Doney Crowley
Bloomquist Payne Uda P.C., Helena, Montana
For Plaintiff-Intervenors and Appellants:
Ward E. Taleff, Taleff Law Office, P.C., Great Falls, Montana
For Appellee:
Hon. Mike McGrath, Montana Attorney General, Chris D. Tweeten
(argued), Assistant Attorney General, Helena, Montana
Robert N. Lane, Montana Department of Fish, Wildlife and Parks,
Helena, Montana
For Defendant-Intervenors and Appellees:
Jack R. Tuholske (argued), Sarah K. McMillan, Tuholske Law Office,
P.C., Missoula, Montana
Argued: September 13, 2006
Submitted: June 20, 2007
Decided: December 31, 2008
Filed:
__________________________________________
Clerk
2
Justice Patricia O. Cotter delivered the Opinion of the Court.
¶1 Appellants Kim and Cindy Kafka, Jack and Myra Bridgewater, and Jim and
Barbara Bouma appeal an order of the Twelfth Judicial District Court denying their
takings claims against the state of Montana and the Department of Fish, Wildlife and
Parks (FWP), an agency of the state of Montana. We affirm.
FACTUAL AND PROCEDURAL BACKGROUND
¶2 Appellants in this case are all owners and operators of alternative livestock game
farms (Game Farms) within the state of Montana. To operate a Game Farm, the
owner/operator must have a valid alternative Game Farm license (License) issued by
FWP. The requirements for the Licenses are found in Title 87, chapter 4, part 4 of the
Montana Code Annotated and are fairly demanding due to the threat posed by chronic
wasting disease (CWD).1 The appellants in this case all obtained their Licenses at
varying times throughout the 1990’s and have complied with the requirements of part 4
since that time.
¶3 Kim and Cindy Kafka (Kafkas) are members of Diamond K Ranch Enterprises,
LLC, located in Hill County. In 1996, the Kafkas applied for a License with FWP and
entered into a lease for a tract of land on which to operate an alternative livestock
breeding operation. After receiving their License, they began operating in March 1997.
In 1998, after obtaining a second License, the Kafkas expanded their operations to focus
on the fee-shooting of alternative livestock as their primary revenue source. This
1
“CWD is a fatal disease of the central nervous system of captive and free-ranging mule deer,
white-tailed deer, and Rocky Mountain elk.” Hagener v. Wallace, 2002 MT 109, ¶ 25 n. 1, 309
Mont. 473, ¶ 25 n. 1, 47 P.3d 847, ¶ 25 n. 1.
3
operation was conducted on an 1100-acre parcel of land roughly twenty miles from the
site of the original breeding operation. The Kafkas purchased this land through a series
of three transactions, beginning in 1993 and ending with the finalization of a deed in
2003. In addition to purchasing land and going through the License application process,
the Kafkas invested several hundred thousand dollars in other start-up costs, including
fencing and the acquisition of stock. According to the record, these costs totaled roughly
$463,000. In 1999, the Kafkas reported $11,000 in income from their Game Farm
operations on their federal tax returns, with that figure rising significantly during the year
2000.
¶4 Jim and Barbara Bouma (Boumas) operate a Game Farm in Teton County. The
Boumas began their Game Farm operations in May 1997, by operating a breeder facility
which would allow them to market large shooter bulls to other Game Farms which
allowed fee-shooting. Like the Kafkas, the Boumas hold Licenses issued by FWP. The
Boumas’ breeder operation spans three parcels of land, two of which they acquired in
1996 at a price of $55,000 and a third totaling 126.777 acres, which was acquired as part
of a larger purchase of 258.067 acres in December 1999 for approximately $325,000. In
March 2000, the Boumas sought to expand their operations onto the remaining 129 acres
of their parcel. Like the Kafkas, the Boumas made other investments necessary to
institute their breeder operation, such as acquiring stock, License-related application
costs, and fencing. According to the record, the Boumas never sold significant numbers
of alternative livestock and their operation never generated a taxable profit.
4
¶5 Jack and Myra Bridgewater (Bridgewaters) are the owners of the Phantom Bull
Elk Ranch, LLC, located in Bridgewater County. The Bridgewaters entered into the
Game Farm business in 1992, and focused primarily on fee-shooting as the primary
source of income, although they had also harvested and marketed antlers from their
alternative livestock for the velvet market. They purchased the property on which their
Game Farm operated in 1990 for approximately $415,000. Like the other appellants, the
Bridgewaters invested in the infrastructure necessary to operate a Game Farm. Between
1993 and 2000, their Game Farm generated cash flow in excess of $1.1 million dollars,
although the Bridgewaters never reported any profit on their tax returns.
¶6 As is common among regulatory schemes, the requirements for maintaining a
License under part 4 have changed somewhat throughout the years. However, on
November 7, 2000, part 4 underwent a radical change as a result of the passage of
Initiative Measure No. 143 (I-143) by the citizens of Montana. I-143 amended two very
significant subsections of part 4. First, it resulted in the deletion of the existing language
in § 87-4-412(2), MCA (1999),2 which permitted a License holder to transfer his License,
and substituted the following: “An alternative livestock ranch license for a specific
facility is not transferable.” Section 87-4-412(2), MCA (2001). More significant was I-
143’s effect on § 87-4-414(2), MCA (1999), as indicated below. The pre-I-143 version
of the statute is in normal type face, and the I-143 addition to the statute is in bold.
2
The pertinent language of these statutes reads as follows: “An alternative livestock ranch
license for a specific facility is transferable with the consent of the department.” Section
87-4-412(2), MCA (1999).
5
(2) The licensee may acquire, breed, grow, keep, pursue, handle, harvest,
use, sell, or dispose of the alternative livestock and their progeny in any
quantity and at any time of year as long as the licensee complies with the
requirements of this part, except that the licensee may not allow the
shooting of game animals or alternative livestock, as defined in
87-2-101 or 87-4-406, or of any exotic big game species for a fee or
other remuneration on an alternative livestock facility.
Section 87-4-414(2), MCA (2001) (emphasis added).
¶7 Notably, the initiative did not revoke appellants’ Licenses, nor did it result in the
confiscation of their alternative livestock. Instead, I-143 prohibited Game Farm
operators from charging a fee to shoot alternative livestock. This was a significant
departure from the previous scheme because some individuals were willing to expend
significant amounts of money to shoot alternative livestock within the confines of a
Game Farm. By prohibiting fee-shooting, I-143 eliminated the most profitable use of the
alternative livestock, and thus the profitability of Game Farms in Montana. At the same
time, it did not eliminate all uses of the alternative livestock, as part 4 still permitted
Game Farm owners to maintain their herds, harvest the animals for their meat or antlers,
or sell them in out-of-state markets where fee-shooting was still legal.
¶8 Aside from these small but extremely significant changes, the remainder of part 4
was unaltered by I-143’s passage. All parties concede that the Game Farm industry was,
and still is, a highly regulated industry. Both before and after the passage of I-143, part 4
conditioned the ability of the licensee to breed, harvest, sell, or dispose of alternative
livestock upon “compli[ance] with the requirement of this part . . . .” Section
87-4-414(2), MCA. Part 4 also states that FWP reserves the right to revoke a License if
the owner/operator “fail[s] to operate an alternative livestock ranch according to the
6
provisions of this part, rules adopted under this part, or stipulations of the alternative
livestock ranch license . . . .” Section 87-4-427(1)(a), MCA. Part 4 outlines in detail the
reporting, testing, and recording duties incumbent upon a Game Farm operator, details
the steps the operator must take to receive a License, and gives FWP broad authority to
inspect and quarantine alternative livestock if necessary. Part 4 also requires
environmental assessments (EA) of any proposed operations. It places conditions upon
the use and disposition of alternative livestock, and further provides that alternative
livestock are the private property of the License holder “for which the licensee is
responsible as provided by law.” Section 87-4-414(1), MCA. Moreover, there are
numerous implementing regulations governing the Game Farms which control virtually
every aspect of the Game Farm industry. See Admin R. M. §§ 32.4.101-1320 (2008).
¶9 Because I-143 eliminated the in-state market for fee-shooting and impaired the
profitability of their Game Farm operations, the Kafkas challenged the validity of I-143
in District Court. On April 5, 2002, the Kafkas filed suit against the State and FWP,
challenging the lawfulness and constitutionality of I-143 on a variety of grounds. On
May 8, 2002, appellees-intervenors Sportsmen for I-143 and Montana Wildlife
Federation were permitted to intervene, opposing the Kafkas. On October 21, 2002, the
District Court dismissed six of the seven counts alleged in the original complaint, none of
which are on appeal before this Court. The remaining claim concerned whether the
passage and implementation of I-143 resulted in a taking of various property interests
held by the Kafkas under Article II, Section 29 of the Montana Constitution and the Fifth
Amendment to the U.S. Constitution. The property interests allegedly taken by I-143
7
included the Kafkas’ animals, Licenses, real property, improvements, business, goodwill
and livelihoods.
¶10 As litigation before the District Court proceeded, the Bridgewaters and Boumas
were granted leave to intervene and join the Kafkas in challenging I-143’s
constitutionality. On February 25, 2003, the District Court bifurcated the legal
proceedings and decided the takings claims would be determined separately. If the
District Court found a taking had occurred, it would then submit the determination of
damages to a jury.
¶11 On May 19 and 20, 2004, the District Court held a bench trial on appellants’
takings claims under the Montana and U.S. Constitutions. In the course of this trial, the
District Court received voluminous testimony and evidence. On February 8, 2005, the
District Court issued a detailed and comprehensive order containing seventy-three
findings of fact and fifty-one conclusions of law and ultimately denied appellants’ takings
claims. The District Court held that the enactment and enforcement of I-143 did not
amount to a compensable taking of appellants’ private property under the Montana or
U.S. Constitutions. Judgment was rendered against appellants and they have timely
appealed to this Court.
¶12 Appellants challenge the District Court’s order in several respects. We describe
the rationale underlying the order in broad terms to convey a sense of the District Court’s
reasoning and analysis. First, we turn to the relevant portions of the District Court’s
findings of fact. The District Court found that all parties knew the Game Farm industry
was highly regulated, existing only by virtue of legislative permission, and that the
8
legislature reserved the ability to change the regulations governing Game Farms at all
times. The District Court pointed to specific portions of the EA prepared for the Kafkas’
operations in which FWP warned them of public unrest regarding Game Farms due to the
threat posed by CWD and their negative impact on Montana’s fair chase hunting
tradition. For instance, in the EA prepared in 1996, FWP specifically noted that “[t]here
are many people who would like to see game farming prohibited in Montana. Some of
these people belong to organizations that will probably continue their efforts to have
legislation passed to eliminate game farming.” In the EA for the Kafkas’ second License,
FWP noted much public concern on the negative effect that Game Farms have on
Montana’s hunting heritage and the sport of hunting in Montana. However, FWP also
noted that game farms were legitimate, regulated activities, approved by the legislature,
and that it had “no authority to regulate game farms based solely on public sentiment.”
Although there was no evidence that the Boumas or Bridgewaters received these same
warnings, the District Court found that they knew, or should have known, about the
tentative status of Game Farms in Montana.
¶13 The District Court also issued findings concerning the economic effect of I-143
with respect to appellants’ property interests. On the one hand, the District Court found
appellants’ real estate retained significant value in spite of I-143 and that some of
appellants’ lands had appreciated in value since initially purchased. With respect to the
Kafkas, the District Court found that the “highest and best use” of the land associated
with their original breeder operation was as “a small tract of range land, with a possible
conversion to a rural home site with adjoining pasture.” Its value for this use as of
9
November 7, 2000, was $34,720. The second property’s “highest and best use” was
found to be as “rangeland with recreational influences, used for the production of
livestock and a potential homesite,” and its value as of November 7, 2000, was $336,000.
Although the Kafkas argued that covenants in the title documents prevented such a use,
the District Court was not persuaded by their evidence on this point. The District Court
also took notice of the fact that the covenants in question had already been lifted by
agreement entered into between the Kafkas and Hill County on March 29, 2004. Further,
the District Court rejected expert testimony presented by the Kafkas that the “highest and
best use” of their lands was as Game Farms, finding that their expert testimony failed to
conform to the standards established under the uniform standards for professional
appraisal practice.
¶14 With respect to the Bridgewaters’ property, the District Court similarly found that
its “highest and best use” was as a “recreational ranch,” and that the value of the land,
improvements, and fixtures was $945,000 as of November 7, 2000. This was an
approximately 100% appreciation in the value of the land since initially purchased in
1990. The District Court observed that the Bridgewaters did not provide expert
testimony regarding the value of the land and its fixtures, or its highest and best use, and
that their expert specifically denied having appraised any of the Bridgewaters’ tangible
real or personal property.
¶15 The District Court found the “highest and best use” of the Boumas’ property to be
for “agricultural production with the potential for future development for industrial or
rural use.” Its valuation for these uses as of November 7, 2000, was $258,000. This
10
represented the value of the two original lots, now worth $87,000, and the third lot worth
$171,000. These figures also represented a notable appreciation in the value of the
Boumas’ lands. Further, the District Court observed that the Boumas, like the
Bridgewaters, provided no testimony as to the value of the land, its fixtures, its highest
and best use, nor did they provide an expert appraisal of their tangible real or personal
property.
¶16 The District Court did, however, find that appellants’ alternative livestock suffered
a substantial loss in value as a result of I-143. As the District Court noted, before I-143,
the Kafkas could fetch $5,000 to $6,000 per head of alternative livestock by virtue of fee-
shooting. After I-143, each head of livestock was worth only between $1,700 and $1,800
in out-of-state markets. Although there was testimony of even greater devaluations of the
livestock of the Boumas and Bridgewaters, the District Court did not refer to these in its
order. See ¶ 84.
¶17 The District Court then issued findings suggesting that this particular economic
impact could be mitigated. The District Court noted that there still remained out-of-state
markets for alternative livestock, and that appellants could harvest the alternative
livestock for their meat and antlers. For instance, the Bridgewaters had been able to sell a
herd of 160 of their alternative livestock to an out-of-state concern for approximately
$80,000. The District Court also noted that none of the appellants had indicated any
taxable profit on their tax returns, thus implying that their businesses were not profitable
to begin with.
11
¶18 Ultimately, the District Court’s findings suggest that the Kafkas suffered the
greatest economic impact, the Bridgewaters somewhat less, while the Boumas suffered
no direct economic impact at all. The District Court tempered these conclusions by
observing that all appellants either knew, or should have known, that Game Farms were
highly controversial in Montana and that they were obliged to comply with any changes
in the governing laws. Further, the District Court found that I-143 served a legitimate
state interest, insofar as it promoted Montana’s hunting heritage, protected wild game
populations from the spread of disease and hybridization, and thus generally protected the
sport of hunting in Montana.
¶19 In its conclusions of law, the District Court examined each of appellants’ property
interests separately to determine if they had been taken by I-143. The District Court
began by considering whether appellants’ Licenses and intangible business assets (i.e.,
good will and going-concern value) were compensable property interests3 under the Fifth
Amendment and Article II, Section 29. After reviewing the pertinent authorities, the
District Court concluded that the Licenses were not compensable property interests and
therefore could not be “taken.” With respect to appellants’ intangible business assets, the
District Court concluded they were not taken because such interests are not compensable
in the regulatory taking context.
3
Throughout this Opinion, the phrase “compensable property interest” refers solely to a
property interest which is potentially compensable under the Fifth Amendment or Article II,
Section 29. This phrase does not refer to property interests that may be entitled to due process
protections under the U.S. or Montana Constitutions. See ¶ 40.
12
¶20 The District Court acknowledged that the land, alternative livestock, and other
physical assets were compensable property interests, but ultimately found that none of
these compensable property interests were taken by I-143. The District Court rejected the
argument that appellants had suffered a “categorical taking” under Lucas v. S.C. Coastal
Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 112 S. Ct. 2886 (1992), because these items continued to retain
economic value, even if greatly diminished; thus, the conditions necessary for applying
the Lucas analysis were not satisfied.
¶21 The District Court then went on to consider whether there was a taking under the
factors-based analysis from Penn Central Transp. Co. v. New York City, 438 U.S. 104, 98
S. Ct. 2646 (1978).4 On the one hand, the District Court failed to see any evidence of an
economic impact on appellants’ land and fixtures as a result of I-143. In this regard, the
District Court noted that appellants failed to provide any expert appraisals to demonstrate
the impact of I-143 on their real estate interests. However, the District Court did
recognize a significant impact on appellants’ alternative livestock. Overall, however, the
District Court concluded that any reasonable investment-backed expectations appellants
may have had regarding their Game Farms had to be tempered against the reality that
they were operating in a highly regulated, controversial field, where the State was free to
change the regulatory environment. In short, appellants should have reasonably
anticipated that something like I-143 was on the horizon. Additionally, the District Court
found that the character of the governmental action embodied in I-143 was a valid
exercise of the police power of the State and substantially advanced a number of
4
The Penn Central analysis is described in greater detail below at ¶¶ 67-72.
13
legitimate state interests. Accordingly, the State had no constitutional duty to
compensate appellants for the effects of I-143, no matter how greatly it impaired the
profitability of appellants’ businesses.
¶22 Appellants argue on appeal that several of the District Court’s findings were
clearly erroneous. The Kafkas, for instance, argue that the District Court improperly
relied on tax return information to conclude that their businesses suffered no significant
economic impact as a result of I-143. Additionally, they argue that the evidence before
the District Court showed that there was no viable out-of-state market for their alternative
livestock or their by-products, and that after I-143 they could only sell these animals at a
loss. They also argue the District Court improperly relied upon on the various “highest
and best use” appraisals for their parcels of land provided by the State’s experts. They
further dispute the finding that they should have known that the Montana voters might
approve and pass a measure like I-143. The Boumas and Bridgewaters join in these
arguments, adding further criticisms of the appraisal methods upon with the District
Court based its findings.
¶23 In addition to challenging some of the District Court’s factual findings, appellants
fault the District Court for concluding that their Licenses and intangible business assets
were not compensable property interests. Appellants maintain that the District Court
should have concluded these interests were compensable and then analyzed them under
the appropriate takings analysis. Additionally, appellants argue that the District Court
erred in its takings analysis of its interests in the land and alternative livestock with
respect to each of the Penn Central factors. They argue that the District Court failed to
14
appreciate the economic impact I-143 had on their businesses and property, relying too
much on the fact that appellants failed to report a taxable profit on their tax returns. They
also assert that their investment-backed expectations were reasonable, in spite of the fact
that they were participating in a highly regulated field of business. Further, they fault the
District Court for placing too much emphasis on whether I-143 was a legitimate exercise
of the State’s police power, and overlooking the fact that I-143 unfairly forces appellants
to bear the economic burden associated with the elimination of Game Farms in Montana.
¶24 Appellants urge us to conclude that the District Court erred, and that I-143
effected an unconstitutional taking of their Licenses and tangible and intangible business
assets. The State and intervenors maintain the District Court’s order was correct in its
particulars and urge us to affirm.
ISSUES
¶25 We restate the issues on appeal as follows:
¶26 Issue One: Did the District Court err in concluding that the enactment and
enforcement of I-143 did not amount to a taking of appellants’ Licenses and the goodwill
and going-concern value of their businesses under the Fifth Amendment and Article II,
Section 29 of the Montana Constitution?
¶27 Issue Two: Did the District Court err in concluding that the enactment and
enforcement of I-143 did not amount to a taking of appellants’ real and tangible personal
property under the Fifth Amendment and Article II, Section 29 of the Montana
Constitution?
STANDARD OF REVIEW
15
¶28 We review a district court’s conclusions of law to determine whether they are
correct. State v. Fyant, 2004 MT 298, ¶ 7, 323 Mont. 408, ¶ 7, 104 P.3d 434, ¶ 7. We
review findings of fact under the clearly erroneous standard pursuant to M. R. Civ. P.
52(a). We use a three-part test to determine if a finding is clearly erroneous. Interstate
Prod. Credit Assn. v. DeSaye, 250 Mont. 320, 323, 820 P.2d 1285, 1287 (1991). First,
we examine the record to determine if the findings are supported by substantial evidence.
DeSaye, 250 Mont. at 323, 820 P.2d at 1287. Second, we consider whether the trial court
has misapprehended the effect of the evidence. DeSaye, 250 Mont. at 323, 820 P.2d at
1287. Third, if both of these tests are satisfied, we may still conclude that “[a] finding is
‘clearly erroneous’ when, although there is evidence to support it, a review of the record
leaves the court with the definite and firm conviction that a mistake has been committed.”
DeSaye, 250 Mont. at 323, 820 P.2d at 1287 (quotation omitted).
DISCUSSION
¶29 Issue One: Did the District Court err in concluding that the enactment and
enforcement of I-143 did not amount to a taking of appellants’ Licenses and the
goodwill and going-concern value of their businesses under the Fifth Amendment
and Article II, Section 29 of the Montana Constitution?
¶30 The Takings Clause of the United States Constitution provides in pertinent part
that private property shall not “be taken for public use without just compensation.” U.S.
Const. amend. V. Article II, Section 29 of the Montana Constitution states that “[p]rivate
property shall not be taken or damaged for public use without just compensation to the
full extent of the loss having been first made to or paid into court for the owner.”
Although the plain language of these provisions differ insofar as Section 29 refers to both
16
“taking” and “damaging” as a basis for just compensation, we have generally looked to
federal case law for guidance when considering a takings claim brought under Article II,
Section 29. Western Energy Co. v. Genie Land Co., 227 Mont. 74, 77-78, 737 P.2d 478,
480-83 (1987); Germann v. Stephens, 2006 MT 130, ¶¶ 27-28, 332 Mont. 303, ¶¶ 27-28,
137 P.3d 545, ¶¶ 27-28. This approach is consistent with that of other jurisdictions which
have similar or identical language in their state constitutions.5 E.g., San Remo Hotel L.P.
v. City and Co. of San Francisco, 41 P.3d 87, 100-101 (Cal. 2002) (citations and
quotations omitted, alterations in original) (“By virtue of including ‘damage[]’ to
property as well as its ‘tak[ing],’ the California clause protects a somewhat broader range
of property values than does the corresponding federal provision. But aside from that
difference . . . we appear to have construed the clauses congruently.”).
¶31 In its order, the District Court concluded that appellants had waived any argument
they may have had that Article II, Section 29 provides greater protection in the regulatory
taking context than the Fifth Amendment. In conclusion of law No. 3, the District Court
held that “Plaintiffs have conceded that analysis under the Montana Constitution does not
differ from that under the Fifth Amendment . . . .” In their briefing before this Court,
appellants have not mounted a challenge to this conclusion. Moreover, appellants rely
almost exclusively on federal case law to challenge the District Court’s application of the
Penn Central factors. Because the parties and the District Court have adhered to our
5
As an aside, we note that the plain language of Article II, Section 29 is not unique among state
constitutions. Roughly half the jurisdictions in the United States have the “or damaged”
language in their state constitutions. Julius L. Sackman, Nichols on Eminent Domain vol. 2A,
§ 6.01[12][c], 6-29 (3d ed., Matthew Bender 2008).
17
previous approach of looking towards federal jurisprudence when considering takings
claims under Montana law, we will continue to follow that approach here.
¶32 “A takings claim requires a two-step analysis in which a court first determines
whether a plaintiff possesses a cognizable property interest in the subject of the alleged
taking. The question of whether plaintiffs owned a compensable property interest
presents a question of law based on factual underpinnings.” Mohlen v. United States, 74
Fed. Cl. 656, 660 (Fed. Cl. 2006) (quotation omitted). After a compensable property
interest has been established “the court decides if the governmental action at issue
constituted a taking of that property.” Mohlen, 74 Fed. Cl. at 661. As we have stated in a
similar context, “[u]nder Montana law, the threshold question of whether one has a
protected property interest must . . . be answered in the affirmative before the question of
whether one was deprived of that interest may be submitted to the trier of fact.” Seven
Up Pete Venture v. State, 2005 MT 146, ¶ 26, 327 Mont. 306, ¶ 26, 114 P.3d 1009, ¶ 26
(quotation and alterations omitted, ellipsis in original); accord Maritrans, Inc. v. United
States, 342 F.3d 1344, 1351 (Fed. Cir. 2003).
¶33 Property interests themselves are not defined by the Takings Clause, or for that
matter by Article II, Section 29; “[r]ather, they are created and their dimensions are
defined by existing rules or understandings that stem from an independent source such as
state law.” Ruckleshaus v. Monsanto Co., 467 U.S. 986, 1001, 104 S. Ct. 2862, 2872
(1984) (quotation omitted); accord Germann, ¶ 27. “These ‘background principles’ and
‘rules and understandings’ focus on the nature of the citizen’s relationship to the alleged
property, such as whether the citizen had the rights to exclude, use, transfer, or dispose of
18
the property.” Members of the Peanut Quota Holders Assn. Inc. v. United States, 421
F.3d 1323, 1330 (Fed. Cir. 2005), cert. denied 126 S. Ct. 2967 (2006).
¶34 The District Court found that the Licenses were not compensable property
interests. The gist of the District Court’s reasoning was that the Licenses are more akin
to privileges, and not vested property interests which could be subject to a taking. The
District Court noted that this view was generally consistent with prevailing authority.
Moreover, the District Court found no case law for the proposition that a taking of a
license occurs when a new regulatory requirement, or in this case a regulatory
prohibition, “ma[kes] the licensed business less profitable than it had been prior to the
new regulations.” Further, the District Court observed that “[w]hen state law creates the
privilege of holding a license to engage in a heavily regulated business like game farming
is in Montana, it need not pay compensation when it changes the conditions under which
that privilege may be exercised.” Simply put, appellants possess no common law
property right to the Licenses, and the State retained the power at all times to revoke or
changes those Licenses if it chose to do so.
¶35 Similarly, the District Court found that appellants’ intangible business assets (i.e.,
the goodwill and going-concern value of their Game Farms) were not compensable
property interests in the regulatory takings context. The District Court, citing to Andrus
v. Allard, 44 U.S. 51, 100 S. Ct. 318 (1979), among others, noted precedent weighed
heavily against the notion that loss of future profits, without more, provided a basis for a
takings claim. The District Court concluded that appellants cited no case law “for the
proposition that loss of future business opportunity is a compensable property interest
19
under the Fifth Amendment.” Moreover, the District Court noted that the ability to
operate a Game Farm was not a common law right, and that because this ability was
wholly dependent upon legislative permission, the State was not required to pay
compensation for any business loss resulting from I-143.
¶36 Appellants’ challenge these conclusions. Generally speaking, appellants argue
that Licenses, goodwill, and going-concern value are property interests recognized under
Montana law. As such, they argue it was incorrect for the District Court to simply
conclude that they could not be taken as a result of the regulatory change occasioned by
I-143. Appellants urge us to reverse the District Court on this point, find these interests
were compensable, and then correctly apply the Penn Central or Lucas takings analysis.
¶37 In cases where there is a “mix” of property interests, it is appropriate, if warranted
under the circumstances, to consider those interests separately in a takings analysis. See
Conti v. United States, 291 F.3d 1334, 1340-43 (Fed. Cir. 2002), cert. denied 537 U.S.
1112 (2003); Maritrans, 342 F.3d at 1352-53. That was the approach applied by the
District Court and we will follow it here. Moreover, it is critical to bear in mind
throughout our discussion that appellants bear the burden of proving a taking has
occurred. Mohlen, 74 Fed. Cl. at 660.
A. Licenses as Compensable Property Interests
¶38 Generally speaking, a license is simply a right or privilege granted by a sovereign
authority to engage in certain activity. 53 C.J.S. Licenses § 2, 441-42 (West 2005);
Members, 421 F.3d at 1333 (stating that a fishing license “is merely a representation by
the government that it will not interfere with the licensee’s efforts to catch fish.”). “A
20
license is a right granted by some competent authority to do an act which, without such
license, would be illegal.” Beard v. City of Atlanta, 86 S.E.2d 672, 676 (Ga. App. 1955).
In a similar context, we have stated that “[a] license is a grant by a government authority
or agency of the right to engage in conduct that would be improper without such a grant.
The conferment of a license . . . is merely a privilege . . . .” Wallace v. Mont. Dept. of
Fish, Wildlife and Parks, 269 Mont. 364, 368, 889 P.2d 817, 820 (1995) (quotation
omitted, ellipsis in original).
¶39 At the same time, courts have recognized that some licenses may contain property
interests that go beyond their status as a “mere privilege.” “[A] license may implicate
property interests. A license holder, for example, may acquire a property right protected
by the Constitution’s Due Process Clause. A professional license may be property for the
purposes of equitable distribution. A license may be transferrable and may be worth a
substantial sum to its holder.” United States v. Berg, 710 F. Supp. 434, 437 (E.D.N.Y.
1988) (citations and footnote omitted). In State v. Pyette, 2007 MT 119, 337 Mont. 265,
159 P.3d 232, for instance, we observed that a state-issued driver’s license constitutes a
property interest for purposes of due process. Pyette, ¶ 13. Similarly, in United States v.
Dicter, 198 F.3d 1284 (11th Cir. 1999), the Eleventh Circuit Court of Appeals found that
a medical license was considered “property” for the purposes of a federal drug forfeiture
statute, 21 U.S.C. § 853, in reliance upon Georgia case law to the effect that a state-
issued license to practice medicine constituted a valuable property right. Dicter, 198 F.3d
at 1290; See also Goldberg v. Kelly, 397 U.S. 254, 262 n. 8, 90 S. Ct. 1011, 1017 n. 8
21
(1970) (discussing increasing tendency in modern society to recognize property rights in
government-conferred entitlements and licenses).
¶40 However, as the District Court recognized, appellants’ arguments generally fail to
appreciate the critical distinction between what might be considered property for
purposes of due process, and what types of interests are considered compensable under
the Fifth Amendment or Article II, Section 29. Appellants have cited cases such as
Mathews v. Eldridge, 424 U.S. 319, 96 S. Ct. 893 (1976) and Wedges/Ledges of Cal., Inc.
v. City of Phoenix, 24 F.3d 56 (9th Cir. 1994) which demonstrate that licenses can be
property for purposes of due process. But none of these cases are helpful or relevant in
this context. “Care . . . must be exercised not to analogize what is ‘property’ for purposes
of the Takings Clause and what might be viewed as a ‘property interest’ under the Due
Process Clause, as the two concepts are dissimilar.” Arctic King Fisheries, Inc. v. United
States, 59 Fed. Cl. 360, 372 n. 27 (Fed. Cl. 2004). Without belaboring the point, suffice
it to say that reliance on due process cases to prove a particular property interest is
compensable for purposes of a takings analysis is simply misplaced. See Kizas v.
Webster, 707 F.2d 524, 534-40 (D.C. Cir. 1983) (demonstrating that property interests for
purposes of due process are not equivalent to compensable interests under the Takings
Clause).
¶41 Courts which have directly considered the question at bar have taken a dim view
of the notion that government-issued licenses are compensable property interests. See
United States v. Fuller, 409 U.S. 488, 93 S. Ct. 801 (1973) (grazing permit not a
compensable property interest); accord Stevens Co. v. United States Dept. of Interior, 507
22
F. Supp. 2d 1127 (E.D. Wash. 2007); Conti, 291 F.3d at 1342 (no compensable property
interest in a government-issued fishing license); accord Am. Pelagic Fishing Co., L.P. v.
United States, 379 F.3d 1363, 1374 (Fed. Cir. 2004), cert. denied 545 U.S. 1139 (2005);
accord Arctic King, 59 Fed. Cl. at 371; Hawkeye Commodity Promotions, Inc. v. Vilsack,
486 F.3d 430, 439-40 (8th Cir. 2007) (no compensable property interest in a state-issued
license to operate lottery machines). As noted by the District Court, appellants presented
no authority under takings jurisprudence to counter this view.
¶42 Nevertheless, compensable property interests can exist in government-issued
licenses or permits if they are free from “express statutory language precluding the
formation of a property right in combination with the presence of the right to transfer and
the right to exclude.” Members, 421 F.3d at 1331. In Members, the Federal Circuit
Court of Appeals considered a takings claim brought by members of the Peanut Quota
Holders Association, Inc. (Members). The Members had been long-time participants in a
government-established program entitling them to receive quotas to grow specific
quantities of peanuts. Under the program, the Members were able to lease or sell their
quotas to other farmers. One of the significant benefits the Members enjoyed as a result
of this arrangement was the ability to secure favorable loan rates.
¶43 The Members were initially peanut farmers, but over time they ceased to grow
peanuts while retaining their right to sell and lease their peanut quotas. In 2002,
Congress changed the peanut quota program, allowing only individuals who actually
farmed peanuts to participate. Because the Members lost their ability to receive quotas,
they lost the favorable loan rates they had formerly secured. The Members argued that
23
the change in the program, which prevented them from participating in it, constituted a
taking of these favorable loan rates. Members, 421 F.3d at 1325.
¶44 The primary issue before the Court of Appeals was whether the quotas were
compensable property interests under the Fifth Amendment. To address this question, the
Court of Appeals turned to the seminal cases in this area for guidance, including Fuller,
Conti, Am. Pelagic, and Mitchell Arms, Inc. v. United States, 7 F.3d 212 (Fed. Cir. 1993),
cert. denied 511 U.S. 1106 (1994).6 First, the Court noted that “[t]he right to transfer is a
traditional hallmark of property” and that the quotas were indeed transferable. Members,
421 F.3d at 1332. Then the Court considered whether the quotas gave the Members the
“right to exclude,” observing that “[t]he Supreme Court has recently recognized that the
right to exclude is ‘perhaps the most fundamental of all property interests.’ ” Members,
421 F.3d at 1333 (quoting Lingle v. Chevron U.S.A., Inc., 544 U.S. 528, 539, 125 S. Ct.
2074, 2082 (2005)). The Court observed a critical distinction between licenses generally
and the quotas before it. The quotas were “considerably more concrete” than, for
instance, a license to fish because such a license “is merely a representation by the
government that it will not interfere with the licensee’s efforts to catch fish.” Members,
421 F.3d at 1333. In other words,
[s]o long as the government retains the discretion to determine the total
number of licenses issued, the number of market entrants is indeterminate.
Such a license is by its very nature not exclusive. Neither the fisherman
nor the firearms salesman can exclude later licensees from entering the
market, increasing competition, and thereby diminishing the value of his
license.
6
Mitchell Arms is discussed infra at ¶ 58.
24
Members, 421 F.3d at 1334.
¶45 The peanut quotas conferred the “right to exclude” because the quotas themselves
“represented a right to plant and produce a certain amount of peanuts at a certain price in
specific crop years.” Members, 421 F.3d at 1334. In other words, the quota program
conferred upon “the peanut quota holders . . . an excludable interest, because the peanut
quota program isolated their particular interest from competition.” Members, 421 F.3d at
1334. Ultimately, in spite of the fact that the quotas were compensable property interests,
the Court of Appeals found that the government was under no constitutional duty to
compensate the Members because neither the statute, nor the surrounding circumstances,
indicated that the quotas were irrevocable, and the government always maintained “its
right to withdraw those benefits or qualify them as it chooses.” Members, 421 F.3d at
1335.
¶46 As stated in Members, to qualify as compensable property interests, the Licenses
must be transferable, exclusive, and free of any “express statutory language precluding
the formation of a property right . . . .” Members, 421 F.3d at 1331. We address each of
these requirements in turn, as they apply to the Licenses before us.
¶47 With respect to whether the Licenses were transferrable, we note that
§ 87-4-412(2), MCA (1999), gave the licensee the right to transfer the Licenses subject to
FWP approval. According to the statute, FWP did not have broad discretion to deny the
transfer assuming the transferee complied with the statutory requirements of part 4.
Section 87-4-412(2), MCA (1999). Before the passage of I-143, the Licenses were
transferable.
25
¶48 It is arguably a closer question as to whether the Licenses were free of any express
statutory language that would prohibit the formation of a compensable property interest
in the License itself. Neither part 4 nor the Licenses themselves contain the type of
express “disclaimer” language discussed in cases like Fuller, Conti, or Am. Pelagic. See
Fuller, 409 U.S. at 489, 93 S. Ct. at 803 (quoting 43 U.S.C. § 315b); Conti, 291 F.3d at
1341-42 (citing 16 U.S.C. § 1853(d)(3)(D), (d)(2)(A)); Am. Pelagic, 379 F.3d at 1374
(citing 15 C.F.R. § 904.301(a)). In all of those cases, there was language in the enabling
regulations or statutes which expressly disclaimed that the licenses or permits themselves
created any compensable property interests.
¶49 However, part 4 does put the holder on notice that continued compliance with
applicable laws and regulations is required for maintenance of the License. See ¶ 8. Both
versions of part 4 state that the licensee may breed, harvest, sell, or dispose of alternative
livestock, so long as she “complies with the requirement of this part.” Both versions of
part 4 specifically state that FWP may revoke the Licenses if the operator fails “to
operate an alternative livestock ranch according to the provisions of this part, rules
adopted under this part, or stipulations of the alternative livestock ranch license.” Section
87-4-427(1)(a), MCA. Thus, nothing in part 4 limits the ability or discretion of FWP or
the State to make changes to the statute. Additionally, the Licenses issued to all
appellants stated that they were subject to the “general requirements of the game farm
statutes and rules for Montana Fish, Wildlife, & Parks and the Montana Department of
Livestock. . . .”
26
¶50 More importantly, nothing in the Licenses or part 4 expressly revokes the ability of
the State to alter those Licenses via duly enacted statutory amendments or changes. In
this regard, we note the operation of § 1-2-110, MCA, entitled “All statutes subject to
repeal,” which states: “Any statute may be repealed at any time except when it is
otherwise provided therein. Persons acting under any statute are deemed to have acted in
contemplation of this power of repeal.” Section 1-2-110, MCA. As the District Court
correctly held, the ability to operate a Game Farm is not a common law right incident to
the ownership of real property, and is legal only by virtue of legislative enactment. “That
the ownership of wild animals is in the state, held by it in its sovereign capacity for the
use and benefit of the people generally, and that neither such animals nor parts thereof are
subject to private ownership except in so far as the state may choose to make them so, are
principles now too firmly established to be open to controversy.” Rosenfeld v. Jakways,
67 Mont. 558, 562, 216 P. 776, 777 (1923). Assuming any statutory amendment is
lawful, there is no legal authority which would restrict the State from making
amendments to part 4 in the interests of further regulating the Game Farm industry. As
the Federal Circuit Court of Appeals stated in Members,
[t]he government is free to create programs that convey benefits in the form
of property, but, unless the statute itself or surrounding circumstances
indicate that such conveyances are intended to be irrevocable, the
government does not forfeit its right to withdraw those benefits or qualify
them as it chooses.
Members, 421 F.3d at 1335.
¶51 However, even assuming arguendo it is a closer question as to whether part 4 and
the Licenses are actually free of express language prohibiting the formation of a
27
compensable property interest, we do not need to resolve that question to conclude the
Licenses are not compensable property interests, because they undoubtedly lack the most
significant of all the indicia discussed in Members: the right to exclude. “In the bundle
of rights we call property, one of the most valued is the right to sole and exclusive
possession—the right to exclude strangers, or for that matter friends, but especially the
Government.” Hendler v. United States, 952 F.2d 1364, 1374 (Fed. Cir. 1991).
¶52 Nothing in the language of the Licenses or either version of part 4 gives the
License holders the right to exclude others from the Game Farm industry. There was no
limit to the number of Licenses which could be issued by FWP, and so the appellants
were never given the “right to exclude” by virtue of their Licenses. The License holders
in this case received a representation by the State that it would not interfere with their
efforts to operate Game Farms, so long as they complied with the requirements of part 4.
However, none were assured of freedom from competition, and none of the Licenses
conferred upon appellants a discrete segment of the Game Farm industry in Montana.
¶53 Moreover, as is conceded by all parties in this case, the Game Farm industry was
highly regulated due to concerns over the damaging impact of CWD. See ¶¶ 2, 8. As the
Federal Circuit noted in Members, “when a citizen voluntarily enters into a market
subject to pervasive government control, he cannot be said to possess the right to
exclude.” Members, 421 F.3d at 1331. While the appellants certainly had the right to
exclude others from fee-shooting on their property, that right was not due to the Licenses,
but due to their inherent rights in the real property on which those operations were
conducted. See Presley v. City of Charlottesville, 464 F.3d 480, 492 n. 2 (4th Cir. 2006)
28
(stating that “perhaps the most important aspect of real property ownership [is] the right
to exclude others from one’s property.”) (citing Kaiser Aetna v. United States, 444 U.S.
164, 179-80, 100 S. Ct. 383, 62 L.Ed.2d 332 (1979)).
¶54 Accordingly, because the Licenses did not meet the three required criteria for
compensability under Members, we conclude the District Court did not err when it held
the Licenses were not compensable property interests under the Fifth Amendment of the
U.S. Constitution, or Article II, Section 29 of the Montana Constitution.
B. Appellants’ Intangible Business Assets
¶55 We turn now to the District Court’s conclusion that I-143 did not take appellants’
intangible business assets. We start with the proposition that intangible assets are
statutorily recognized forms of property in Montana, and possess the indicia of property
which the Licenses do not. See Section 70-1-104(4), MCA; In re Marriage of Hull, 219
Mont. 480, 484-85, 712 P.2d 1317, 1320-21 (1986). However, this does not necessarily
mean that such intangibles can be “taken” in the regulatory context. In its order, the
District Court stated that “[a]n intangible interest in a business has never been held to be
a proper subject of a regulatory taking claim.” This is true. While goodwill and going-
concern value can be taken as a result of government condemnation, appellants point to
no cases where a taking of going-concern or goodwill has been found in the regulatory
takings context.
¶56 In Kimball Laundry Co. v. United States, 338 U.S. 1, 69 S. Ct. 1434 (1949), the
Supreme Court established that, under limited circumstances, intangible assets like going-
concern value can be taken in a manner requiring just compensation be paid to the owner.
29
There, the Supreme Court held that when the government temporarily condemned a
laundry plant, it was required to compensate plaintiffs for the going-concern value of
trade routes. Kimball, 338 U.S. at 11-16, 69 S. Ct. at 1440-43. However, since Kimball
was decided, courts have found these types of takings only in those rare circumstances
where the government actually intends to take over the claimant’s business and thereby
appropriate the goodwill and going-concern value for its own use. Thus, the federal
district court for the Eastern District of Michigan held no compensation was due for loss
of going-concern value to a claimant’s trucking business as a result of a government
condemnation of land, because the claimant did not demonstrate that the government
condemned the land with the intent of operating a similar business. United States v. Five
Parcels, 1.11195 Acres of Land, More or Less, Situated in the City of Detroit, Wayne
County, State of Michigan, 765 F. Supp. 1283, 1286 (E.D. Mich. 1991). The federal
district court for the Western District of Michigan stated the general approach to these
questions as follows:
The Court concludes that where, as in this case, 1) the government intends
to construct facilities in substitution for an existing business; 2) the new
business is operated under the government’s pervasive regulation; 3) the
government creates a monopoly situation and realizes a pecuniary interest
by doing so, the government’s activity is tantamount to the operation of the
ongoing concern which, in turn, comprises a business taking.
United States v. 0.88 Acres of Land, 670 F. Supp 210, 213 (W.D. Mich. 1987).
¶57 As the jurisprudence in this area makes plain, taking of goodwill or going-concern
value differs markedly from other types of taking. This is likely because what the
30
claimant alleges has been “taken” is an expectation of future profitability..7 As the
United States Supreme Court stated in Andrus, a “loss of future profits—unaccompanied
by any physical property restriction—provides a slender reed upon which to rest a takings
claim. Prediction of profitability is essentially a matter of reasoned speculation that
courts are not especially competent to perform.” Andrus, 444 U.S. at 66, 100 S. Ct. at
327. In cases such as Kimball, where there is an actual physical occupation of land by
the government, fundamental property rights are implicated; thus, if the going-concern
value is based upon a right or ability to exclusive use of the property which the
government is occupying, it makes sense to provide compensation for the value lost.
Turning to this case, it is important to note that appellants cite no authority for the
proposition that compensation of the loss of their intangible assets should be paid under
their regulatory takings claims. Any citation to Kimball is unavailing for the simple
reason that Kimball involved actual physical occupation of land—a critical fact which is
absent in this case.
¶58 An expectation of profitability in a highly regulated field of business, where a
license or permit is required for participation, is virtually never, in and of itself,
considered a compensable property interest. In Mitchell Arms, for instance, the Federal
Circuit Court of Appeals found that an arms dealer had no cognizable property interest in
an expectation of selling assault rifles in domestic commerce, because that right was
7
Black’s defines “going-concern value” as “value of a commercial enterprise’s assets or the
enterprise itself as an active business with future earning power, as opposed to the liquidation
value of the business or its assets.” Black’s Law Dictionary 1587 (Bryan Garner ed., 8th ed.
2004). “Good will” is defined in part as “the ability to earn income in excess of the income that
would be expected from the business viewed as a mere collection of assets.” Black’s at 715.
31
totally dependent upon the government’s granting him a license to sell those weapons.
Mitchell Arms, 7 F.3d at 217. Thus, when the government withdrew the permit, the arms
dealer had no basis upon which to assert a takings claim because all the government
‘‘ ‘took’ . . . [was] the ability to realize an expectation in the ultimate market disposition
of the rifles. This ‘collateral interest’ incident to [the] ownership of the rifles is not
property protected by the Fifth Amendment.” Mitchell Arms, 7 F.3d at 217; See United
States v. Gen. Motors Corp., 323 U.S. 373, 378, 65 S. Ct. 357, 360 (1945) (“[T]he Fifth
Amendment concerns itself solely with the ‘property,’ i.e., with the owner’s relation as
such to the physical thing and not with other collateral interests which may be incident to
his ownership.”).
¶59 Similarly, in Allied-General Nuclear Servs. v. United States, 839 F.2d 1572 (Fed.
Cir. 1988), the Federal Circuit Court of Appeals found that a private company which had
been induced by the federal government to invest $200 million dollars into the
development of a nuclear power plant, had no takings claim when the government
suddenly changed its mind and decided that the construction of the plant would represent
a danger to national security. Allied-General, 839 F.2d at 1576-78. The Court of
Appeals noted that the licensing power of the government when “use[d] for purposes
within the object of the power reserved will be valid even if detrimental to the owner’s
full utilization of the property.” Allied-General, 839 F.2d at 1577 (citing Nollan v.
California Coastal Commn., 483 U.S. 825, 832-35, 107 S. Ct. 3141, 3146-47 (1987)).
The appeals court rejected the notion that excessive inducement from the government to
enter into this area and expend significant amounts of money should alter its conclusion,
32
finding that in the absence of a direct contract between the government and the private
corporation, the expectation of profiting in such a highly regulated and risky field could
not by itself be considered a compensable property interest. Allied-General, 839 F.2d at
1577-78. More recently, in Hawkeye Commodity, the Eighth Circuit found that a
company had no property interest in a right to continued operation in the state-regulated
lottery business. Hawkeye Commodity, 486 F.3d at 439-40. Thus, when the state of Iowa
enacted legislation which prohibited a particular type of lottery game, the company,
which had been previously engaged in that type of business, had no basis for a takings
claim. Hawkeye Commodity, 486 F.3d at 440.
¶60 Similarly, in Huntleigh USA Corp. v. United States, 75 Fed. Cl. 642 (Fed. Cl.
2007), the Federal Claims Court found no compensable property interest when the
government federalized airport screening in 2001 under the Aviation and Transportation
Security Act (ATSA), and allegedly “took” the company’s entire screening business,
including its “contracts, goodwill and going concern value.” Huntleigh, 75 Fed. Cl. at
645. The Claims Court concluded it was immaterial whether the private company could
have anticipated the regulatory changes, because the federal government retained the
ability at all times to make those regulatory changes. Huntleigh, 75 Fed. Cl. at 646. In
Huntleigh USA Corp. v. United States, 525 F.3d 1370 (Fed. Cir. 2008) (Huntleigh II)—a
case cited, but not discussed or analyzed by the Dissent at ¶¶ 167, 168, 201—the Federal
Court of Appeals affirmed the claims court decision in Huntleigh. In affirming the lower
court, the court noted that Huntleigh’s argument was not whether the government
actually “took” its screening contracts—because there was no physical condemnation or
33
occupation by the ATSA—but rather whether the regulatory change embodied in the
federalization of airport screening under the ATSA “rendered the contracts and the going
concern value and goodwill associated with Huntleigh’s security screening business
worthless.” Huntleigh II, 525 F.3d at 1379. When Congress federalized airport
screening under the ATSA “it effectively eliminated the market for [Huntleigh’s
services], given that it concentrated all screening functions in the federal government.
Thus . . . Huntleigh and the other airlines with which it had contracts treated their
contracts as terminated upon the government’s full assumption of screening functions at
airports, resulting in considerable loss of business to Huntleigh.” Huntleigh II, 525 F.3d
at 1375.
¶61 However, while the ATSA frustrated Huntleigh’s business expectations, it did not
take any of Huntleigh’s property within the meaning of the Fifth Amendment. Huntleigh
II, 525 F.3d at 1380-82. Accordingly, the Federal Court of Appeals distinguished the
application of Kimball as follows:
Our reasoning applies to all property interests possessed by
Huntleigh, including its contracts and any going concern value or goodwill
associated with its security screening business. Thus, the authority of
Kimball Laundry does not alter our holding. Though going concern value
and goodwill are indeed compensable property interests, Kimball Laundry,
338 U.S. at 11, 69 S.Ct. 1434, those property interests, like Huntleigh’s
contracts, were merely “frustrated” by the government’s enactment of
ATSA. They were not taken. Moreover, going concern value is a
property interest that has been held to be compensable in the context of a
temporary, but not a permanent, taking.
Huntleigh II, 525 F.3d at 1382 n. 3.
34
¶62 Huntleigh’s unsuccessful argument is nearly identical to that advanced by the
appellants. It is indisputable that in the enactment and enforcement of I-143, the State
has not “appropriated for its own use any property owned by [the appellants].” Huntleigh
II, 525 F.3d at 1381. Thus, I-143 did not physically appropriate or “take” any of the
appellants’ property, although it did eliminate the in-state market for fee-shooting and
had a significant impact upon the value of their businesses.
¶63 In this case, appellants have alleged a taking of their intangible business assets
because I-143 eliminated the in-state market for fee-shooting. In other words, I-143 has
“taken” appellants’ ability to profit from fee-shooting. Yet, as is clear from the foregoing
authorities, these interests are not compensable in this case under the Fifth Amendment or
Article II, § 29 of the Montana Constitution because there has been no physical
condemnation or occupation of appellants’ property by the State. We disagree with
appellants’ assertions that the District Court was splitting hairs by not considering the
economic impact on the intangible aspects of their businesses and licenses. The District
Court correctly recognized that takings claims for goodwill and going-concern value have
never been recognized in the regulatory taking context. The unique circumstances
required to assert a taking of these intangible assets, namely a physical condemnation of
some sort by the State, are not present in this case.
¶64 Accordingly, the District Court did not err when it found that appellants were not
entitled to compensation for damage to the goodwill and going-concern value of their
businesses as a result of I-143.
35
¶65 Issue Two: Did the District Court err in concluding that the enactment and
enforcement of I-143 did not amount to a taking of appellants’ real and tangible
personal property under the Fifth Amendment and Article II, Section 29 of the
Montana Constitution?
¶66 We now address appellants’ contention that I-143 effected a regulatory taking of
their real and personal property—i.e., their land and attached fixtures, and their livestock.
There is no question that a person has a compensable property interest arising out of the
ownership of such real and personal property.
¶67 Once a claimant establishes a compensable property interest, “the court must then
determine whether a part or a whole of that interest has been appropriated by the
government for the benefit of the public.” Members, 421 F.3d at 1330. Initially, courts
assumed that “the Takings Clause reached only a direct appropriation of property, or the
functional equivalent of a practical ouster of [the owner’s] possession.” Lucas, 505 U.S.
at 1014, 112 S. Ct. at 2892 (citations and quotations omitted, alterations in original). In
the modern world, it is well-established that state action or regulation may go “too far,”
and constitute a taking, in the absence of physical invasion or outright appropriation.
Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon, 260 U.S. 393, 414-15, 43 S. Ct. 158, 159-60 (1922).8
These so-called “regulatory takings” fall into one of two categories.
8
Curiously, the Dissent criticizes the Court for claiming that regulatory takings were not
recognized prior to Pennsylvania Coal in 1922. (Dissent at ¶¶ 140-141.) However, this
statement is both historically accurate and well-established.
[U]ntil the Court’s watershed decision in Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon, 260
U.S. 393, 43 S.Ct. 158, 67 L.Ed. 322 (1922), “it was generally thought that the
Takings Clause reached only a ‘direct appropriation’ of property, or the
functional equivalent of a ‘practical ouster of [the owner’s] possession.’ ” Lucas
v. South Carolina Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 1014, 112 S.Ct. 2886, 120
36
First, where government requires an owner to suffer a permanent physical
invasion of her property—however minor—i t mu s t provide just
compensation. See Loretto v. Teleprompter Manhattan CATV Corp., 458
U.S. 419, 102 S.Ct. 3164, 73 L.Ed.2d 868 (1982) (state law requiring
landlords to permit cable companies to install cable facilities in apartment
buildings effected a taking). A second categorical rule applies to
regulations that completely deprive an owner of “all economically
beneficial us[e]” of her property. Lucas, 505 U.S., at 1019, 112 S.Ct.
2886 (emphasis in original).
Lingle, 544 U.S. at 538, 125 S. Ct. at 2081.
¶68 In other words, aside from an outright physical invasion, a “categorical taking” is
deemed to have occurred when a regulation or state action forces an owner “ ‘to sacrifice
all economically beneficial uses in the name of the common good, that is, to leave his
property economically idle . . . .’ ” Seven Up Pete, ¶ 21 (quoting Lucas, 505 U.S. at
1019, 112 S. Ct. at 2895). Thus, when land or other interests retain economic value, no
categorical taking has occurred. Tahoe Sierra Preservation Council, Inc. v. Tahoe
Regional Planning Agency, 535 U.S. 302, 330-32, 122 S. Ct. 1465, 1483-84 (2002).
¶69 However, even when a compensable property interest still retains economic value,
just compensation may be required if “ ‘justice and fairness’ require that economic
injuries caused by public action be compensated by the government, rather than remain
disproportionately concentrated on a few persons.” Penn Central, 438 U.S. at 124, 98
S. Ct. at 2659. Determining when such compensation is required is essentially an “ad
L.Ed.2d 798 (1992) (citations omitted and emphasis added; brackets in original);
see also id., at 1028, n. 15, 112 S.Ct. 2886 (“[E]arly constitutional theorists did
not believe the Takings Clause embraced regulations of property at all”).
Lingle, 544 U.S. at 537, 125 S. Ct. at 2081.
37
hoc, factual inquiry” based on the circumstances of each case. In Penn Central, the
Supreme Court suggested that courts examine the following factors in the course of
making this determination: (1) the character of the governmental action; (2) the extent to
which the regulation has interfered with distinct investment-backed expectations; and (3)
the economic impact of the regulation on the claimant. Penn Central, 438 U.S. at 124, 98
S. Ct. at 2659. While courts may consider all three factors, in some cases one or more are
dispositive. E.g., Ruckleshaus, 467 U.S. at 1005-06, 104 S. Ct. at 2874 (finding the
reasonable investment-backed expectation prong dispositive under Penn Central
analysis).
¶70 In jurisprudence under Penn Central, courts have fleshed out the practical
meaning of each of these factors. In analysis of the first factor, the “character of the
governmental action,” the inquiry focuses primarily on “whether the [governmental
action] amounts to a physical invasion or instead merely affects property interests
through ‘some public program adjusting the benefits and burdens of economic life to
promote the common good . . . .’ ” Lingle, 544 U.S. at 539, 125 S. Ct. at 2082 (quoting
Penn Central, 438 U.S. at 124). In Lingle, the United States Supreme Court clarified that
under the “character of the governmental action” prong of the Penn Central regulatory
takings analysis, whether a challenged regulation “substantially advances” a legitimate
state interest “is not a valid method of identifying regulatory takings for which the Fifth
Amendment requires just compensation.” Lingle, 544 U.S. at 545, 125 S. Ct. at 2085.
While the Supreme Court did not state with perfect clarity how the character of the
governmental action is to be measured, it did state that
38
[T]he “substantially advances” inquiry reveals nothing about the
magnitude or character of the burden a particular regulation imposes upon
private property rights. Nor does it provide any information about how
any regulatory burden is distributed among property owners. In
consequence, this test does not help to identify those regulations whose
effects are functionally comparable to government appropriation or
invasion of private property; it is tethered neither to the text of the Takings
Clause nor to the basic justification for allowing regulatory actions to be
challenged under the Clause.
Lingle, 544 U.S. at 542, 125 S. Ct. at 2084.
¶71 The rejection of the “substantially advances” formula with respect to the character
of the governmental action prong was simply meant to ensure that courts correctly
quantify the effect of the regulation in terms of actual property rights and the magnitude
of the infringement on those rights. Physical occupations, however slight, automatically
require some form of compensation “because of the unique burden they impose: A
permanent physical invasion, however minimal the economic cost it entails, eviscerates
the owner’s right to exclude others from entering and using her property—perhaps the
most fundamental of all property interests.” Lingle, 544 U.S. at 539, 125 S. Ct. at 2082.
Similarly, the “complete elimination of a property’s value” may give rise to a
“categorical” or total regulatory takings. Lingle, 544 U.S. at 539-40, 125 S. Ct. at 2082.
Regulatory takings, by contrast, turn more on the magnitude of the economic impact and
“the degree to which it interferes with legitimate property interests.” Lingle, 544 U.S. at
540, 125 S. Ct. at 2082. Thus, under the “character of the governmental action” prong
courts should inquire concerning the magnitude or character of the burden imposed by
the regulation, and determine whether i t is functionally comparable to government
appropriation or invasion of private property.
39
¶72 Under the “reasonable investment-backed expectations” factor, the claimant’s
expectation must be “reasonable . . . [and] must be more than a unilateral expectation or
an abstract need.” Ruckleshaus, 467 U.S. at 1005-06, 104 S. Ct. at 2874 (quotation
omitted). This factor limits takings claims to those who can “demonstrate that they
bought their property in reliance on a state of affairs that did not include the challenged
regulatory regime.” Rose Acre Farms, Inc. v. United States, 373 F.3d 1177, 1190 (Fed.
Cir. 2004) (quotation omitted). “This factor also incorporates an objective test—to
support a claim for a regulatory taking, an investment-backed expectation must be
‘reasonable.’ ” Cienega Gardens v. United States, 331 F.3d 1319, 1346 (Fed. Cir. 2003).
Under the third criteria, “economic impact,” the court measures the impact of the
regulatory change by considering “the change in the fair market value of the subject
property caused by the regulatory imposition—in other words, the court must ‘compare
the value that has been taken from the property with the value that remains in the
property.’ ” Arctic King, 59 Fed. Cl. at 374 (quoting Keystone, 480 U.S. at 497, 107
S. Ct. at 1248). In assessing this factor, the court will look at the magnitude of the impact
on the “parcel as a whole.” Rose Acre Farms, 373 F.3d at 1185 (citing Penn Central, 438
U.S. at 130-31, 98 S. Ct. at 2662).
¶73 With respect to the land, the District Court found there was no categorical taking
under Lucas because the evidence showed those lands still retained substantial economic
value; indeed, some of those lands even appreciated. The District Court also rejected
appellants’ arguments that they were entitled to just compensation for these interests
under the Penn Central analysis. Under the “economic impact” factor, the District Court
40
concluded that appellants did not show that their real estate interests suffered any
significant economic impact as a result of I-143, and further that they failed to
demonstrate any change in the fair market value of their land as a result of I-143. See
¶¶ 13-15.
¶74 The District Court did recognize a substantial economic impact on appellants’
alternative livestock; however, it concluded that the economic impact was not severe, in
part because none of the appellants reported taxable profit on their tax returns for the
years their Game Farms were in operation. Under the “reasonable investment-backed
expectations” factor, the District Court acknowledged that appellants’ had significant
expectations, but noted “their subjective expectation of profit must be legally tempered
by the objective reality that they were engaged in a highly regulated and speculative new
industry.” The District Court concluded all appellants knew the Game Farm industry was
highly regulated, that they were allowed to participate in the business because the
privilege was extended by the State, and that they knew the regulations could change.
¶75 With respect to the “character of the governmental action,” the District Court
concluded that I-143 was a valid exercise of the State’s police power. The District Court
cited to ample authority demonstrating that when a state exercise of police power is valid,
“its actions may injure investment-backed expectations with respect to commerce in the
goods at issue without having to pay compensation.” One line of authority on which the
District Court placed particular reliance was a series of prohibition-era cases showing that
state action could put an industry completely out of business without having to pay just
compensation so long as the state action was a valid exercise of police power. E.g.,
41
Mugler v. Kan., 123 U.S. 623, 8 S. Ct. 273 (1887); James Everard’s Breweries v. Day,
265 U.S. 545, 44 S. Ct. 628 (1924). Further, the District Court found that I-143
prohibited only one use of the alternative livestock—i.e., charging a fee to shoot them—
and that otherwise appellants maintained all their rights and property interests in the
alternative livestock. As a result, I-143 left appellants “free to make other economically
viable use of their property, removing only one potential use that has been validly
deemed to be injurious to public health, safety, and welfare.”
¶76 Appellants challenge the District Court’s application of each of the Penn Central
factors. With respect to the economic impact of I-143, appellants assert that the District
Court improperly relied on the lack of a taxable profit in their tax returns, and failed to
appreciate the impact I-143 had on their alternative livestock and real estate interests.
¶77 Under the “reasonable investment-backed expectations” factor, appellants assert
the District Court was wrong to conclude that their expectations were not reasonable, in
spite of the fact that the Game Farm industry was highly regulated. They assert that
I-143 was not in fact a regulation of the Game Farm industry, but instead a prohibition
against Game Farms which destroyed their property. Appellants maintain that they
reasonably expected some changes in the regulations governing the Game Farm industry,
but that it is not reasonable to expect them to anticipate a regulatory change, based on the
whims of Montana voters, which would wipe out the in-state market for fee-shooting.
Appellants cite to Cienega Gardens and NRG Co. v. United States., 24 Fed. Cl. 51 (Cl.
Ct. 1991) in support of their argument under this factor.
42
¶78 With respect to the “character of the governmental action” factor, appellants
criticize the District Court for focusing too much on whether I-143 was a valid exercise
of the State’s police power, and too little on the actual purpose behind takings
jurisprudence: to prevent the government from forcing a few individuals to bear an
economic burden which should be borne by society as a whole. In light of Lingle,
appellants’ argue i t is legally inappropriate to conduct a “means-ends” analysis to
determine whether I-143 substantially advances legitimate state interests. Instead, they
argue, the proper focus should be on the nature of the interference with appellants’
property interests and whether I-143 requires appellants to unfairly shoulder the
economic burden of eliminating the in-state market for fee-shooting.
¶79 With these arguments in mind, we will examine the appellants’ remaining
compensable property interests under the Penn Central factors.
C. Appellants’ Real Estate Interests and Fixtures
¶80 The District Court correctly determined that I-143 did not effect a taking of
appellants’ real estate interests, including appellants’ land and the fixtures constructed for
the purpose of operating Game Farms. In this regard, we find the “economic impact”
factor dispositive because Appellants presented no evidence to support their claims that
I-143 had a measurable economic impact on their lands and fixtures.
¶81 The State presented expert testimony and evidence at trial which showed that the
“highest and best use” of appellants’ lands were for uses other than Game Farms, and that
they all retained significant value in spite of I-143; indeed, most of those lands even
appreciated. Other than simply disagreeing with this view, appellants offered no
43
evidence—such as appraisals of their own—to support the contention that these findings
were clearly erroneous. Indeed, appellants’ experts admitted at trial that they had
conducted no appraisals of the real property or fixtures themselves. Instead, appellants
presented expert testimony to the effect that I-143 constituted a categorical taking of their
businesses and the Licenses themselves. But the District Court was correct to give no
weight to this expert testimony, because those interests are not compensable under the
circumstances at bar. Moreover, a review of the expert opinions presented by appellants
shows that these experts did not understand how the Penn Central takings analysis is
actually applied by the courts.
¶82 There was testimony from Mr. Bridgewater that his property was less marketable
without an operating Game Farm, but at any rate it is equally true that the Bridgewaters’
land had appreciated 100% since its date of purchase. Additionally, while the Kafkas
contended that certain restrictive covenants in their title documents precluded the
alternative uses which the State’s appraisal deemed appropriate, the District Court
adequately addressed this issue by taking notice of the fact that these covenants had been
removed by the Kafkas and Hill County, and did not impair the marketability of their
lands for uses other than Game Farms.
¶83 Applying the “parcel as a whole” standard to appellants’ real estate interests,
including their land and fixtures, we find that the “economic impact” factor weighs
overwhelmingly against finding a compensable taking. Appellants have not shown that
I-143 had any economic impact on their lands, and have not presented evidence to
counter the weight of the State’s evidence. In short, they provide no basis to assert a
44
taking of their real estate interests, regardless of the weight of the remaining two factors.
Accordingly, the District Court did not err in concluding I-143 did not constitute a
regulatory taking of appellants’ compensable property interests in their lands.
D. Alternative Livestock
¶84 Next we turn to appellants’ claim that their alternative livestock was “taken” by
I-143. Returning to the Penn Central analysis, we will first examine the economic
impact of I-143. In this connection, we agree with appellants that the District Court
underestimated the economic impact that I-143 had on their alternative livestock. Unlike
their real estate interests, appellants’ have demonstrated that their alternative livestock
suffered a significant devaluation as a result of I-143. Prior to I-143, the Kafkas received
approximately $5,000 to $6,000 per head of alternative livestock; after I-143 that figure
was reduced to $1,700 to $1,800. This represented a devaluation of roughly 70%. The
District Court had evidence before it suggesting similar or greater devaluations for both
the Bridgewaters and the Boumas, although it did not cite to this evidence in its order.
According to the record, the Bridgewaters once had received approximately $8,000 to
$9,000 for each head, while after I-143 they sold 160 head to an out-of-state interest for
approximately $80,000, representing a price of around $500 per head, or a roughly 95%
devaluation. The Boumas had sold their animals for roughly $5,000 a head before I-143,
while after its passage they received $500 per head. These figures show a devaluation in
the neighborhood of 90%.
¶85 Moreover, the facts in the record support the view that this diminished value was
insufficient to even cover the cost of raising and maintaining those livestock. While there
45
do exist some markets for their alternative livestock either for meat or antlers, or for
resale to out-of-state markets, the return from such activities is less than the actual cost of
maintaining the alternative livestock. In other words, after I-143, appellants could only
sell the alternative livestock at a loss. This factor weighs in favor of finding a
compensable taking of appellants’ alternative livestock.
¶86 We turn next to the second Penn Central factor, the “character of the
governmental action.” We start with the proposition that I-143 places the economic
burden of eliminating Game Farms in Montana squarely on the shoulders of individuals,
like the appellants, who have entered into this industry in reliance on the continued
legality of fee-shooting. As such, it seems to run afoul of one of the primary policy
concerns animating takings jurisprudence, namely the notion that the Takings Clause
“bar[s] Government from forcing some people alone to bear public burdens which, in all
fairness and justice, should be borne by the public as a whole.” Armstrong v. United
States, 364 U.S. 40, 49, 80 S. Ct. 1563, 1569 (1960). Whatever the rationale for
preventing fee-shooting, it is clear that individuals like appellants, and not the public as a
whole, are being asked to bear the burden.
¶87 However, the type of intrusion upon the alternative livestock embodied by I-143 is
minimal. The animals have not been seized by virtue of I-143—they still belong to the
appellants. Moreover, Appellants may still sell their animals to out-of-state markets for
any usage, and may even allow others to shoot them in Montana, so long as no fee is
charged. It is well-established that regulations which impair or significantly decrease the
profitable use of property do not amount to a taking. In Andrus, for instance, the
46
Supreme Court held that an act of Congress which banned the sale and transfer of eagle
feathers, did not amount to a taking of the eagle feathers because the property holders still
maintained the rest of the bundle of rights, and could still make some minimal use of the
eagle feathers. Andrus, 444 U.S. at 65-66, 100 S. Ct. at 327. The Supreme Court
acknowledged that the act deprived claimants of the ability to make profitable use of the
eagle feathers, but declined to find a taking in large measure because they did not have a
right, under the Takings Clause to make profitable use of the eagle feathers. “[T]he
denial of one traditional property right does not always amount to a taking. At least
where an owner possesses a full ‘bundle’ of property rights, the destruction of one
‘strand’ of the bundle is not a taking, because the aggregate must be viewed in its
entirety.” Andrus, 444 U.S. at 65-66, 100 S. Ct. at 327.
¶88 Thus, the “character of the governmental action” with respect to the animals is
minimally intrusive. If the nature of the intrusion was greater and I-143 affected other
segments of appellants’ bundle of rights in the alternative livestock, such as their right to
sell the live animals or slaughter them for market, then this factor might lean more in
their favor because appellants, and not the general public, are shouldering this burden.
As it stands, however, the intrusion is so slight that this factor must weigh against finding
a compensable taking.
¶89 Thus we turn to the final Penn Central factor, “reasonable investment-backed
expectations.” With respect to the alternative livestock, appellants’ investment-backed
expectations were that they could charge a fee to shoot them. Indeed, that is why they
expended significant financial resources on their respective operations to begin with. The
47
District Court acknowledged these expectations but concluded that they “must be legally
tempered by the objective reality that they were engaged in a highly regulated and
speculative new industry.” While one can maintain reasonable investment-backed
expectations in highly-regulated industries, e.g., Ruckleshaus, 467 U.S. at 1010-11, 104
S. Ct. at 2877 (finding reasonable investment-backed expectations in the pesticide
industry), United Nuclear Corp. v. United States., 912 F.2d 1432, 1436-37 (Fed. Cir
1990) (finding distinct investment-backed expectations in the mining industry), we agree
with the view, as articulated by the District Court, that the regulated and speculative
nature of a particular industry should be considered in determining whether investment-
backed expectations are reasonable. In this case, then, the question becomes whether it
was reasonable for appellants to maintain an investment-backed expectation that they
would always be able to charge a fee to shoot alternative livestock in Montana, and that
the State could or would not interfere with this expectation. We find that such an
expectation is not reasonable; thus, this factor weighs against finding a compensable
taking of appellants’ alternative livestock.
¶90 In this regard, the facts at bar distinguish this case from both Cienega Gardens and
NRG Co., the two cases upon which Appellants rely. In Cienega Gardens, owners of
low-income apartments sued the government for an unconstitutional taking after
Congress nullified their contractual rights to prepay forty-year mortgage loans entered
into with the Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD) after a period of
twenty years. Cienega Gardens, 331 F.3d at 1323. This congressional action was
significant to the owners because so long as they participated in the HUD loan program,
48
they were forced to charge rental rates far below market value. The Federal Court of
Appeals agreed and found that the term in their contract with the Government
guaranteeing them the right to exit the HUD program after twenty years by paying off
their loans was “an explicit and material term of their mortgage contracts [and] simply
not a change the . . . Plaintiffs should have anticipated.” Cienega Gardens, 331 F.3d at
1351.
¶91 Similarly, in NRG Co., the Federal Claims Court found an unconstitutional taking
under the Fifth Amendment when Congress cancelled mining prospecting permits held
by several private companies. NRG Co., 24 Cl. Ct. at 52-55. In that case, the U.S.
Government issued permits to several private companies, but Congress later unilaterally
cancelled those permits, and related leases, out of concerns that the proposed mining
operations would negatively impact Indian tribes on whose lands those operations would
be conducted. NRG Co., 24 Cl. Ct. at 55-56. In analyzing the companies’ regulatory
takings claims, the Claims Court found the companies had reasonable investment-backed
expectations that, once they obtained the permits, they would have the option to obtain
valuable mineral leases, and that the congressional acts cancelling those permits after
they had already been issued was not reasonably within those investment-backed
expectations. NRG Co., 24 Cl. Ct. at 61-63.
¶92 Here by contrast, the State never assured appellants they would always be
permitted to charge a fee to shoot alternative livestock in Montana. Further, we agree
with the District Court that appellants knew, or should have known, that Game Farm
operations were highly controversial in Montana and that initiative measures could have
49
been passed which would outlaw Game Farms entirely. The record is clear that FWP was
aware of the significant public unrest and imparted this information to the Kafkas
beginning in 1996. See ¶ 12. Other appellants should have been aware of these same
facts. Nothing in the regulations, Licenses, or statutes, provides any assurance that the
regulations could not be changed and appellants received no guarantees from the State
that their operations would continue to be lawful.
¶93 We conclude that appellants should have reasonably anticipated that the Game
Farm industry might be phased out due to health and safety-related concerns over CWD,
or even that the State might make the regulatory burden of participating in this field so
onerous that Game Farms would no longer be profitable enterprises. In other words,
appellants could not maintain a reasonable investment-backed expectation that they
would be permanently insulated against the possibility that the Game Farm industry
would be either regulated so as to eliminate its profitability, or completely abolished. As
a result, since appellants could have reasonably anticipated the complete elimination of
Game Farms by the State or regulations that would make participation in the field
unprofitable, they should have also anticipated that the State could make the operations
less profitable by eliminating the in-state market for fee-shooting. Although appellants
may not have specifically anticipated the passage and enactment of I-143, the practical
effect of I-143—i.e., the elimination of the in-state market for fee-shooting—should have
been within their reasonable investment-backed expectations, given the absence of
assurances on this point from the State. Accordingly, the “reasonable investment-backed
expectation” factor weighs against finding a compensable taking of appellants’ livestock.
50
¶94 The Penn Central test ultimately calls for a weighing or balancing of these factors
in order “to identify regulatory actions that are functionally equivalent to the classic
taking in which government directly appropriates private property or ousts the owner
from his domain.” Lingle, 544 U.S. at 539, 125 S. Ct. at 2082. Utilizing this approach,
we have concluded that the purported taking here is not the functional equivalent of a
direct appropriation of property, nor does it constitute an ouster from appellants’ domain.
In weighing these factors together, we are mindful of the admonition that “[r]esolution of
each case . . . ultimately calls as much for the exercise of judgment as for the application
of logic.” Andrus, 444 U.S. at 65, 100 S. Ct. at 327. After weighing the effects of I-143
under the Penn Central factors, and particularly the “character of the governmental
action” factor, we conclude that appellants are not entitled to just compensation for the
regulatory taking of their alternative livestock.
CONCLUSION
¶95 In summary, we affirm the District Court’s findings of fact and conclusions of law
regarding appellants’ claims for compensation with respect to their Licenses, the
goodwill and other intangible assets of their businesses, their real estate and fixtures, and
their alternative livestock.
/S/ PATRICIA COTTER
We concur:
/S/ KARLA M. GRAY
51
/S/ W. WILLIAM LEAPHART
/S/ DEBORAH KIM CHRISTOPHER
District Court Judge Deborah Kim Christopher
sitting for Justice John Warner
52
Justice James C. Nelson, dissenting.
I. INTRODUCTION
¶96 We are in danger of forgetting that a strong public desire to
improve the public condition is not enough to warrant
achieving the desire by a shorter cut than the constitutional
way of paying for the change.1
¶97 Ninety-one years ago, the State of Montana made i t a lawful “business or
occupation” to acquire, breed, own, harvest, sell, and otherwise control privately owned
game animals on alternative livestock ranches. As recently as 1999, the State suggested
this as “a viable economic opportunity” for any private property owner, as well as the
traditional livestock producers who were interested in diversifying their ranch
productivity. Although the State regulated alternative livestock ranching, the regulatory
scheme provided that these businesses could continue so long as the owner paid the
licensing fee each year and complied with all recording and reporting requirements.
Among other things, the State sanctioned “fee shooting,” where members of the public
could pay to shoot a preselected animal on an alternative livestock ranch under the
supervision of a guide. Indisputably, fee shooting was the primary source of income for
the alternative livestock businesses.
¶98 With the State’s blessing, and in reliance on this governmental enabling, the
Kafkas, the Bridgewaters, and the Boumas (collectively, “the Ranchers”) invested
substantial capital and resources to create going concerns. But then the State turned
around and told the Ranchers that while they could continue to acquire, breed, and
1
Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon, 260 U.S. 393, 416, 43 S. Ct. 158, 160 (1922).
harvest their alternative livestock, they could no longer charge a fee for hunting the
livestock. In thus prohibiting remuneration for the key economic activity on which the
Ranchers’ businesses depended, the State effectively legislated those businesses out of
existence. The State zeroed out the Ranchers’ intangible assets (e.g., goodwill and going-
concern value) and left them with a collection of tangibles whose value was either
worthless or substantially diminished.
¶99 The Court holds today that the Ranchers are not entitled under the United States
Constitution or the Montana Constitution to any compensation for the obliteration of their
businesses caused by the passage of Initiative No. 143 (“Initiative” or “I-143”) in
November 2000. The Court acknowledges that the Ranchers suffered substantial
property devaluation as a result of the Initiative, but the Court decides that such loss is
not compensable because the State did not physically condemn or occupy the Ranchers’
property and because the Ranchers should have anticipated a prohibition on charging a
fee for alternative livestock hunts. As will surely come as a surprise to many Montana
business owners, the Court announces that, absent an explicit “assurance” from the State,
the businessman or businesswoman has no reasonable expectation in being able to
receive remuneration for the goods and services he or she provides. Thus, when the State
says, “Go ahead and market your products, but don’t charge anything for them,” the
business owner is simply out of luck if his or her business is destroyed as a result.
¶100 At bottom, the Court holds that any individual in this State who, with the State’s
encouragement, invests capital and resources to create a going concern, but who does so
in a field that this Court considers “highly controversial,” simply has no compensable
2
interest in that business. Therefore, when the State up and decides to legislate the
business out of existence—through the unique expedient of depriving the business of any
income—the State need not provide any compensation for the owner’s loss of property.
¶101 The injustice in treating Montana businesspeople and property owners in this
manner is manifest, not to mention legally indefensible. I strenuously disagree with the
Court’s determination that the Ranchers, and others similarly situated, are without a
remedy for a taking of their property. I also cannot subscribe to the Court’s faulty
rationales in reaching this result. I therefore respectfully dissent from the Court’s
decision.
II. PRELIMINARY MATTERS
¶102 The issues in this case are unquestionably complex, in large part because takings
jurisprudence itself is “a confused body of law containing contradictory principles and
standards.” John D. Echeverria & Sharon Dennis, The Takings Issue and the Due
Process Clause: A Way Out of a Doctrinal Confusion, 17 Vt. L. Rev. 695, 696 (1993).
The Court, the District Court, the State, and the Sportsmen have further confounded the
proper resolution of this case by mischaracterizing the impact of I-143 on the Ranchers’
property interests and by injecting into this case a number of inapt legal theories and
irrelevant factual matters. For these reasons, and to lay the foundation for my analysis of
the Ranchers’ claims, I first address the following four subjects:
A. The regulatory history of alternative livestock ranching.
B. The purpose and impact of I-143.
C. Inapplicability of police power/noxious use theory.
D. Misplaced reliance on due process considerations.
3
After clarifying these preliminary matters in Part II, I proceed in Part III with an analysis
of the Ranchers’ entitlement to just compensation for a taking of their property under the
Fifth Amendment to the United States Constitution.
A. The Regulatory History of Alternative Livestock Ranching
¶103 On March 15, 1917, the Montana Legislature passed an act which, among other
things, declared it lawful for any person, company, or association to engage in the
“business or occupation” of propagating, owning, and controlling wild game animals of
this State upon premises owned, leased, or controlled by such person, company, or
association. Laws of Montana 1917, ch. 173, § 84, as amended, Laws of Montana 1919,
ch. 200, § 1, codified at § 3777, RCM (1921). The business owner was required to pay
an annual license fee and comply with any regulations prescribed by the State Fish and
Game Commission. In addition, a statement of the place where “such business” was to
be conducted and the game proposed to be raised on said premises had to be filed with
the Commission. Section 3777, RCM. To this end, upon obtaining a permit from the
Commission, the business owner was authorized “to capture alive such . . . game
quadrupeds as may be necessary for foundation stock for such game farm.” Section
3777, RCM. Finally, once the game farm was “in successful operation,” the owner was
authorized to “sell, transfer, or dispose of the game so bred and raised by him, as he
might do with domestic live stock, and without restriction so to do.” Section 3777, RCM.
¶104 The statutory scheme underwent a number of revisions in 1925, 1933, and 1947.
Most of these changes are not pertinent to the instant appeal, though the following are
worth noting. In 1925, the Legislature added an explicit fencing requirement and made it
4
unlawful for any person to enter a properly fenced game farm without the owner’s
consent. See Laws of Montana 1925, ch. 192, § 31. The Legislature also provided that
“the product of such game or fur-farm may be dealt with and sold as private property,”
Laws of Montana 1925, ch. 192, § 31, codified at § 3777, RCM (1935); however, this
language was not carried forward in the 1947 version of the statute, see § 26-1201, RCM
(1947). In 1947, the Legislature clarified that a permit must be procured “before”
establishing a game farm but that a game farm permit “shall” be issued to “responsible”
applicants who own or lease, and have properly fenced, the premises on which their
operations are to be conducted. Laws of Montana 1947, ch. 120, § 1. Thereafter, the
statutory scheme remained substantially unchanged through 1982.
¶105 In March 1982, Governor Ted Schwinden appointed a 13-member Game Farm
Task Force—consisting of sportsmen, game farm operators, bird farm owners, ranchers,
and state officials—to develop definitive legislation addressed to concerns about game
farming in Montana. The culmination of the task force’s work, Senate Bill No. 448
(“SB 448”), was passed by the 1983 Legislature. It repealed the existing game farm laws
and replaced them with an entirely new statutory framework. See Laws of Montana
1983, ch. 570. Among other things, the new scheme clarified that all game farm animals
lawfully raised on a licensed game farm “are the private property of the licensee,”
§ 87-4-414(1), MCA (1983); that the licensee “may acquire, breed, grow, keep, pursue,
capture, kill, use, sell, or dispose of the game farm animals and their progeny in any
quantity, at any time of year, and in any manner, as long as he complies with the
requirements of [Title 87, chapter 4, part 4, MCA],” § 87-4-414(2), MCA; and that the
5
laws applicable to game animals do not apply to game farm animals on a licensed game
farm, § 87-4-414(4), MCA. The hunting and sale of game farm animals was explicitly
recognized in §§ 87-4-414(3), -415(1), and -421, MCA. Persons wishing to operate a
game farm were still required to obtain a license, see §§ 87-4-407, -409, MCA; however,
once obtained, renewal of the license was a matter of right “upon payment of the renewal
fee if the licensee has not violated any provision under which the license was granted,”
§ 87-4-412(1), MCA. Finally, the reporting requirements were set out in greater detail
than previously. Compare § 87-4-404, MCA (1981), with § 87-4-417, MCA (1983).
¶106 Notably, the original version of SB 448 differed in a number of critical respects
from the proposed legislation submitted by the Game Farm Task Force. Among other
things, the drafters of SB 448 gave the Department of Fish, Wildlife, and Parks discretion
as to whether a game farm license would be issued (assuming the game farm application
was otherwise in order) by replacing the word “shall” with the word “may” in several
places. The drafters also revised the provision regarding the renewal of licenses such that
renewal would not be a matter of right. These sorts of changes prompted a somewhat
scathing rejoinder by counsel representing the interests of game farm operators. In a
February 1983 letter (which is part of the legislative history of SB 448), counsel pointed
out that the proposed legislation submitted by the drafters “violated the intent” of the
proposed legislation submitted by the Game Farm Task Force. At stake here, he stated,
was “the private property right that every individual has to raise livestock as long as he
complies with the other provisions of the Act as was discussed in the task force.”
Counsel stated that unless the language of SB 448 was amended so that “it represents
6
what the task force agreed upon and does not take away any rights that we negotiated,”
he would oppose the bill. Ultimately, his concerns were taken into account, and the final
version of SB 448 passed by the Legislature, as described above, included the “rights”
sought by the game farm operators and negotiated by the Game Farm Task Force.
¶107 The statutory scheme enacted in 1983 remained in place through November 6,
2000 (the day before I-143 went into effect), though various provisions were amended or
added over the years. For instance, in 1993, the Legislature adopted new procedures and
criteria for the issuance and revocation of game farm licenses, including additional
fencing and enclosure requirements, and authorized licensees to transfer their game farm
licenses. See Laws of Montana 1993, ch. 315, §§ 3, 4, 6, 12. The Legislature also
eliminated the “shooting license” that game farmers had been required to obtain before
allowing anyone to hunt on their property. See Laws of Montana 1993, ch. 315, § 7. In
1999, the term “game farm” was changed to “alternative livestock ranch.” See Laws of
Montana 1999, ch. 574, § 7. In addition, the Legislature added a provision explicitly
recognizing the production of alternative livestock as “a viable economic opportunity for
any private property owner as well as the traditional livestock producers who are
interested in diversifying their ranch productivity.” Laws of Montana 1999, ch. 574, § 1.
¶108 The substance of the statutory scheme as it relates to the instant appeal, however,
remained substantially unchanged. All alternative livestock lawfully possessed on a
licensed alternative livestock ranch were the licensee’s “private property,” which the
licensee could “breed, grow, keep, pursue, handle, harvest, use, sell, or dispose of . . . in
any quantity and at any time of year.” Section 87-4-414(1), (2) MCA (1999). Annual
7
renewal of the alternative livestock ranch license was a matter of right under
§ 87-4-412(1), MCA, which instructed the Department of Fish, Wildlife, and Parks to
renew each license “upon payment of the renewal fee if the licensee has complied with
all recording and reporting requirements.” Lastly, each license was transferable if certain
criteria were met. Section 87-4-412(2), MCA.
¶109 So, to sum up this historical background, although the regulatory scheme went
through a number of adjustments between 1917 and 2000, it was always a lawful
“business or occupation” to acquire, breed, own, harvest, sell, and otherwise control
privately owned game animals on an alternative livestock ranch. Furthermore, while the
regulations designed to protect native wildlife (through safety and fencing requirements)
became increasingly detailed and rigorous, so did the regulations designed to protect the
business owners’ interests (through explicit recognition of their alternative livestock as
“private property” and their businesses as “viable economic opportunities,” and through
the guarantee that their licenses would be renewed each year upon payment of the
renewal fee and compliance with all recording and reporting requirements).
B. The Purpose and Impact of I-143
¶110 On November 7, 2000, the voters passed I-143, which altered the statutory scheme
in several significant respects. See generally Laws of Montana 2001, 2000 Ballot Issues,
Initiative No. 143, §§ 1-9. First, it prohibited the establishment of any new alternative
livestock ranches. See §§ 1, 4. Second, it revoked the right of existing alternative
livestock ranch operators to transfer their alternative livestock ranch licenses. See § 4.
Lastly, it prohibited “the shooting of game animals or alternative livestock . . . for a fee or
8
other remuneration on an alternative livestock facility.” See § 6. These amendments
took effect immediately. See § 11.
¶111 The Sportsmen have sought in this Court to portray I-143 as creating nothing more
than a few “additional restrictions” on alternative livestock ranching. They assert that
these “additional restrictions” are not so onerous as to amount to a taking of private
property. The District Court likewise characterized I-143 as merely an “extension” of the
existing regulatory framework. Remarkably, this Court minimizes the impact of I-143
even further, declaring it to be only a “slight” and “minimally intrusive” burden on the
Ranchers’ property interests. For the reasons which follow, these characterizations are
baseless and patently misleading.
¶112 The Sportsmen inform us that they conceived, designed, and drafted I-143 “to
address specific dangers stemming from the proliferation of game farms in this state.”
They list a number of such dangers: the threat posed by alternative livestock ranches to
Montana’s “proud heritage of ethical hunting”; the increased risk of disease (e.g., chronic
wasting disease), hybridization, and competition to native wildlife posed by alternative
livestock interacting with native elk and deer (as a result of escape, or nose-to-nose
contact through the fence); and the “European style” privatization of wildlife. The
Sportsmen also report that they opposed and sought to prohibit the “penned hunts”
offered by many alternative livestock ranches. They note that this practice, which they
criticize as “a sport for the wealthy,” had become a “poster child” for anti-hunting
groups. Finally, although the Legislature took action in 2000 to address concerns over
chronic wasting disease—see Laws of Montana 2001, May 2000 Special Session, ch. 1
9
(imposing a moratorium on new applications for initial alternative livestock ranch
licenses “until a live test for chronic wasting disease is developed and is approved by the
department of livestock”)—the Sportsmen assert that “the problems” associated with
alternative livestock ranches were not “adequately addressed” by the legislative action.
The Sportsmen thus characterize I-143 as “vital” to the protection of Montana’s wildlife,
to the availability of plentiful populations of big game, and to the preservation of
Montana’s proud tradition of hunting these animals under fair-chase conditions. They
conclude that I-143 serves “weighty” and “important” purposes.
¶113 Yet, notwithstanding the Sportsmen’s concerns with disease, fair-chase hunting
ethics, and privatization of wildlife, the Ranchers’ activities remain lawful and state-
sanctioned in most respects. I-143 did not revoke their alternative livestock ranch
licenses, confiscate their alternative livestock, or impose stricter regulations on the care
and management of the livestock. As a matter of fact, the Initiative does not prohibit the
Ranchers from continuing to acquire, breed, grow, keep, pursue, handle, harvest, use,
sell, or dispose of alternative livestock. Section 87-4-414(2), MCA (2001). The
Initiative allows the Ranchers to keep penned elk, in spite of the concern about contact
between wild ungulates and alternative livestock and the concern about transmission of
diseases through intermediate hosts. The Initiative also allows “penned hunts,” in spite
of the concern with preserving Montana’s tradition of ethical fair-chase hunting. And the
Initiative allows private ownership of alternative livestock, § 87-4-414(1), MCA, in spite
of the concern over European-style privatization of wildlife. In short, I-143 neither
outlawed alternative livestock ranches nor directly addressed any of the concerns cited by
10
the Sportsmen in support of the Initiative. (The Sportsmen’s concerns were set out in the
Proponents’ arguments included with the 2000 Voter Information Pamphlet.) I-143 did
not create new regulations concerning fencing, it did not create new testing requirements
for diseases, and people can still shoot privately owned penned elk. I-143 actually
addressed none of the “weighty” and “important” purposes for which it was promoted to
the voters.
¶114 The reason for all of this is simple: The Sportsmen’s ultimate goal was to shut
down all alternative livestock businesses, and in drafting I-143, they recognized the
constitutional implications of doing so outright. As explained by counsel for the
Sportsmen during oral argument in the companion case, Buhmann v. State (No. 05-473):
There was a recognition by my clients that if they passed a statute that
simply said, “Every game farm is done tomorrow,” that that would be a
very difficult takings claim to defend against. And we didn’t want to have
to go down that road. And so the statute was carefully crafted to address
the problem in a way that was not offensive to taking but at the same time
benefitted the wildlife and the wildlife management of this State.
¶115 Thus, in a striking display of legerdemain, the Sportsmen devised the “carefully
crafted” solution of imposing a ban on charging a fee for what remains a lawful activity
in this State: shooting alternative livestock on alternative livestock ranches. They
recognized that because the value of each alternative livestock business derived from its
ability to sell “penned hunts,” I-143 would effectively shut those businesses down by
prohibiting remuneration for such hunts. Indeed, as the District Court aptly observed:
“I-143 does appear to have been intentionally crafted in such a way that would for all
intents and purposes snuff out alternative livestock ranching and in the process possibly
11
save the State from footing the bill in the event it was found that the obvious takings were
compensable.” Likewise, despite its attempts elsewhere in the Opinion to minimize the
impact of I-143, the Court acknowledges that the Initiative’s prohibition on fee shooting
effectively “outlaw[ed] Game Farms entirely.” Opinion, ¶ 92. Similarly, the Attorney
General’s explanatory statement of I-143 in the 2000 Voter Information Pamphlet points
out that “[a]bolishing fee shooting may force closure of some game farms.” Notably
absent from the Voter Information Pamphlet, however, is any acknowledgement that the
State might have to foot the bill for destroying the Ranchers’ property rights. As a result,
the voters were never required to weigh the costs and benefits of taking the Ranchers’
property. They were simply asked whether an initiative “prohibiting new game farms,
prohibiting transfer of existing game farm licenses, and prohibiting shooting of game
farm animals for a fee” should be approved, given the dire public need described by the
Proponents.
¶116 In blunt terms, the Sportsmen determined to rid Montana of a perceived blight, but
euthanizing the Ranchers outright was thought to be too “offensive” and costly. So, they
decided instead to pull the plug on the Ranchers’ life-support. That way, they could
argue that the Ranchers died of natural causes and that the State, therefore, bears no
responsibility. Counsel’s assertion that this transparent charade is “not offensive” to the
guarantee of just compensation for a taking of private property is dubious, if not
preposterous. Moreover, that this ruse was wrapped in the mantle of Montana’s “proud
heritage of ethical hunting” is a stain on the sport that the Sportsmen purport to protect.
12
¶117 Even more troubling is the Court’s decision to ratify this end-around the
Constitution’s just compensation requirement. This constitutional guarantee is worthless
when the Court allows it to be circumvented by means of a “carefully crafted” political
ploy. Moreover, the purpose of the constitutional guarantee is undermined when property
rights can be devalued with no thought whatsoever as to the burdens and benefits
involved. From the taxpayers’ perspective, it is easy and painless to vote for an initiative
such as I-143 when this Court holds that the government is free to take property without
having to pay for it. Yet, if government regulation involves “adjusting the benefits and
burdens of economic life to promote the common good,” Penn Central Transp. Co. v.
New York City, 438 U.S. 104, 124, 98 S. Ct. 2646, 2659 (1978), then taxpayers should be
required to weigh the costs of taking property against the expected public benefits of
doing so. In point of fact, this weighing is mandated by fairness, efficiency, and the
Constitution.
¶118 Given the Sportsmen’s goals in drafting I-143, it is disingenuous to argue, as the
Sportsmen do, that the Ranchers have not suffered a taking of private property under the
“additional restrictions” created by I-143 because the Initiative merely “modified” their
alternative livestock ranch licenses and because the Ranchers “can continue operating as
a game farm, albeit less profitably.” The Court’s assertion that I-143 made the Ranchers’
operations only “less profitable” is similarly far-fetched. Opinion, ¶ 93. The purpose of
I-143, as admitted by the Sportsmen themselves, was not to create a few “additional
restrictions” (e.g., new testing and fencing regulations) that might incidentally make the
business of alternative livestock ranching less profitable. The Initiative’s purpose, rather,
13
was to eliminate the economic viability of these businesses entirely and thereby make it
unfeasible for the Ranchers and other alternative livestock business owners to operate
their ranches at all. In this connection, the Sportsmen and the Court concede that the
Ranchers invested in specialized equipment, inventory, and fixtures and expended
significant financial resources to develop their property for the specific purpose of fee
shooting. Moreover, the Court acknowledges that as a result of I-143, the value of the
Ranchers’ alternative livestock was diminished to such an extent that the Ranchers are no
longer able to cover the cost of raising and maintaining the livestock. Opinion, ¶ 85.
Simply put, I-143 was designed to shut down all alternative livestock businesses, and it
succeeded in doing so. It is irrelevant that this was accomplished in a less direct and
expeditious manner than passing a statute that simply said, “Every game farm is done
tomorrow.” The result—destruction of the Ranchers’ businesses—is clearly the same.
¶119 Ultimately, the Sportsmen’s assertion that I-143 served “weighty” and “important”
purposes is immaterial to our resolution of this appeal. The District Court and several
other courts have already concluded that I-143 furthered legitimate state interests, and the
Ranchers have not appealed these conclusions. See Kafka v. Hagener, 176 F. Supp. 2d
1037, 1042 (D. Mont. 2001); Or. on Mot. to Dismiss (Dkt. 40) at 4, Kafka v. Montana
Dept. of Fish, Wildlife and Parks, DV-02-059 (Mont. Dist. Oct. 21, 2002); Spoklie v.
Montana, 411 F.3d 1051, 1059 (9th Cir. 2005); see also Hagener v. Wallace, 2002 MT
109, ¶¶ 22-28, 309 Mont. 473, ¶¶ 22-28, 47 P.3d 847, ¶¶ 22-28. Rather, the point of this
discussion is that I-143 was intended to shut down the alternative livestock industry
without the State’s having to pay for it, and thus the Sportsmen’s and the Court’s
14
portrayals of I-143 as something other than it is—as merely a slight, minimally intrusive
“adjustment” of the regulatory scheme—are implausible. Indeed, they are flat wrong.
The Court even contradicts itself by arguing on one hand that I-143 amounts to a “slight”
and “minimally intrusive” burden on the Ranchers’ property interests, Opinion, ¶ 88, but
on the other hand that the Ranchers “should have reasonably anticipated that the Game
Farm industry might be phased out,” Opinion, ¶ 93. “Phasing out” an entire industry is
certainly not the result one would reasonably anticipate from a regulation whose intrusion
on property interests is “slight” and “minimally intrusive.”
¶120 In any event, the fact is that I-143 did not adjust the regulatory scheme as the
amendments over the preceding 83 years had done. Rather, it rendered the regulatory
scheme entirely pointless, since none of the businesses in the industry can exist
economically after I-143, which was the admitted purpose of the Initiative from the
outset.
C. Inapplicability of Police Power/Noxious Use Theory
¶121 Citing Mugler v. Kansas, 123 U.S. 623, 8 S. Ct. 273 (1887), the State argues that
“the government can ban commerce that it deems to be injurious to public health, safety,
and welfare without having to compensate the traffickers in such commerce for the loss
of their businesses.” Likewise, during oral argument, the State emphasized the theory
that the Ranchers are not entitled to any compensation because I-143 is “a valid police
power regulation” necessary for the protection of the public health, safety, and welfare.
The State asserted on this basis that this Court has “no choice” but to affirm the District
Court’s decision.
15
¶122 In rejecting the Ranchers’ takings claims, the District Court articulated a similar
theory based on Mugler:
The State has the power to determine that certain commerce is injurious to
the welfare of the State and its citizens, and to regulate or even outlaw that
commerce. The State has done so here with respect to the fee-shooting
prohibition in I-143. When the State does so, its actions may injure
investment-backed expectations with respect to commerce in the goods at
issue without having to pay compensation.
¶123 The Court remarks that “ample authority” supports the District Court’s reasoning.
Opinion, ¶ 75. According to the Court, this “ample authority” demonstrates the State
may put an industry completely out of business without having to pay just compensation,
so long as the state action was a valid exercise of its police power. Opinion, ¶ 75. In this
connection, the Court observes that the activity targeted by I-143 was “ ‘validly deemed
to be injurious to public health, safety, and welfare.’ ” Opinion, ¶ 75 (quoting the District
Court’s conclusions of law). The Court does not identify what the injurious byproducts
of charging a fee to shoot alternative livestock were, but it appears that the Court has the
Sportsmen’s concerns in mind (i.e., diseases, unethical hunting, and private ownership of
game animals), given that the Court refers to these repeatedly throughout its Opinion.
¶124 The State insists that Mugler is “still viewed as authoritative under modern taking
jurisprudence.” As authority for this contention, the State cites Lucas v. South Carolina
Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 112 S. Ct. 2886 (1992), Keystone Bituminous Coal
Ass’n v. DeBenedictis, 480 U.S. 470, 107 S. Ct. 1232 (1987), and Andrus v. Allard, 444
U.S. 51, 100 S. Ct. 318 (1979). In addition, the State asserted during oral argument that
Mugler “continues to be cited as good law,” since “it was cited last term by the Court in
16
the Kelo case”—a reference to Kelo v. City of New London, 545 U.S. 469, 125 S. Ct.
2655 (2005). A careful reading of Kelo, however, reveals that Mugler was cited by one
of the dissenting Justices, not by the Kelo majority. See Kelo, 545 U.S. at 519-20, 125
S. Ct. at 2685 (Thomas, J., dissenting).
¶125 Although the Ranchers, citing Loveladies Harbor, Inc. v. United States, 28 F.3d
1171 (Fed. Cir. 1994), and Whitney Benefits, Inc. v. United States, 926 F.2d 1169 (Fed.
Cir. 1991), argue that Mugler’s validity is suspect, this debate over Mugler’s current
vitality is beside the point. For the reasons which follow, Mugler is inapplicable to the
case at hand.
1. The Mugler Decision
¶126 At the outset, it is necessary to point out that Mugler, which involved a challenge
to certain Kansas statutes, was decided on substantive due process grounds. The Fifth
Amendment’s Takings Clause was not at issue for the simple reason that, under the law at
the time, the Clause was understood as “intended solely as a limitation on the exercise of
power by the government of the United States, and . . . not applicable to the legislation of
the states.” Barron v. Baltimore, 32 U.S. 243, 250-51 (1833); accord Pumpelly v. Green
Bay & Mississippi Canal Co., 80 U.S. 166, 176-77 (1872). Rather, during the period in
which Mugler was decided, the “just compensation” requirement (as applied to state
action) was a matter of state constitutional law, natural law, common law, and Fourteenth
Amendment due process. See Kris W. Kobach, The Origins of Regulatory Takings:
Setting the Record Straight, 1996 Utah L. Rev. 1211, 1229, 1270-76; Bradley C.
Karkkainen, The Police Power Revisited: Phantom Incorporation and the Roots of the
17
Takings “Muddle,” 90 Minn. L. Rev. 826, 847-49 (2006); see also Chicago, Burlington
& Quincy Railroad Co. v. Chicago, 166 U.S. 226, 236, 17 S. Ct. 581, 584 (1897).
¶127 The question in Mugler was whether state statutes prohibiting the manufacture and
sale of intoxicating liquors (except for medical, scientific, and mechanical purposes)
violated the Fourteenth Amendment’s Due Process Clause or Privileges and Immunities
Clause. See Mugler, 123 U.S. at 657, 8 S. Ct. at 295. In answering this question, the
Supreme Court first acknowledged the power of the States, known as the “police power,”
“to control their purely internal affairs, and, in so doing, to protect the health, morals, and
safety of their people by regulations that do not interfere with the execution of the powers
of the general government, or violate rights secured by the Constitution of the United
States.” Mugler, 123 U.S. at 659, 8 S. Ct. at 296. The Court decided that the power to
regulate or prohibit the manufacture and sale of intoxicating liquors, whether for general
use or merely personal use, was within the ambit of the state’s police powers. See
Mugler, 123 U.S. at 658-63, 8 S. Ct. at 295-98.
¶128 Next, the Court considered and rejected the contention that Kansas was required
under the Fourteenth Amendment to pay just compensation for the resulting devaluation
of the appellants’ breweries. See Mugler, 123 U.S. at 664-70, 8 S. Ct. at 298-301. The
Court reasoned that “all property in this country is held under the implied obligation that
the owner’s use of it shall not be injurious to the community.” Mugler, 123 U.S. at 665,
8 S. Ct. at 299. Thus, where a particular use of property is a nuisance to the surrounding
community, the government may exercise its police power to abate the nuisance. Mugler,
18
123 U.S. at 667, 8 S. Ct. at 300. In explaining that no compensation is required in that
situation, the Court stated as follows:
The power which the states have of prohibiting such use by individuals of
their property, as will be prejudicial to the health, the morals, or the safety
of the public, is not—and, consistently with the existence and safety of
organized society, cannot be—burdened with the condition that the state
must compensate such individual owners for pecuniary losses they may
sustain, by reason of their not being permitted, by a noxious use of their
property, to inflict injury upon the community. The exercise of the police
power by the destruction of property which is itself a public nuisance, or
the prohibition of its use in a particular way, whereby its value becomes
depreciated, is very different from taking property for public use, or from
depriving a person of his property without due process of law. In the one
case, a nuisance only is abated; in the other, unoffending property is taken
away from an innocent owner.
Mugler, 123 U.S. at 669, 8 S. Ct. at 301.
2. Mugler’s Inapplicability to the Case at Hand
¶129 Seen in its historical context, Mugler stands for the limited proposition that the
government need not pay compensation when i t exercises its power to prohibit a
“noxious” use of property, i.e., a use akin to a “public nuisance.” See Lucas, 505 U.S. at
1010, 1022-23, 1029-30, 112 S. Ct. at 2890, 2896-97, 2900-01 (explaining that the
Takings Clause does not require compensation when the state exercises its power to abate
a nuisance which affects the public generally). This is so because the right to engage in
the noxious use was never in the property owner’s title to begin with; thus, nothing is
taken when the state prohibits that use. See Lucas, 505 U.S. at 1029-30, 112 S. Ct. at
2900-01. But this proposition gets the State nowhere in its attempt to avoid paying
compensation for the Ranchers’ losses. Alternative livestock ranching, which was done
and maintained under the express authority of Title 87, chapter 4, part 4, MCA, was in no
19
way a public nuisance. See § 27-30-101(2), MCA (“Nothing which is done or maintained
under the express authority of a statute can be deemed a nuisance.”). Mugler, therefore,
is inapposite.
¶130 The State suggested otherwise at oral argument, asserting emphatically and with
unmistakable disdain that use of alternative livestock for the purpose of fee shooting
threatened the public health, safety, and welfare. Likewise, in its appellate brief, the
State disparages the Ranchers’ activities as “injurious to public health, safety, and
welfare.” That the State would describe alternative livestock ranching with such smug
intolerance is astounding, given that the State not only sanctioned the industry’s existence
for 83 years but also facilitated—and even encouraged—the establishment of numerous
alternative livestock businesses. Indeed, the State conceded at oral argument that “[t]here
is some evidence to suggest that it was the policy of the political branches of government
to encourage people to look at game farming as an alternative to traditional agriculture --
actually, to subsidize traditional agriculture so they could stay on the farms and ranches.”
Yet, at the same time, the State argued that the very activities it had sanctioned and
encouraged for 83 years needed to be prohibited in the interest of the public health,
safety, and welfare. This is hypocrisy personified.
¶131 The State’s condemnation of the alternative livestock industry as some sort of
noxious or abhorrent threat to the public health, safety, and welfare rings hollow in light
of the State’s role in creating, developing, and nurturing the industry in the first place.
That said, any suggestion that no compensation is owed the Ranchers because the State
was abating some sort of public nuisance is legally unsustainable. Section 27-30-101(2),
20
MCA. For that matter, the State has provided nothing but conclusory assertions that
alternative livestock ranching constituted a public nuisance in the first place.
¶132 On a related point, as noted above, the District Court reasoned:
The State has the power to determine that certain commerce is injurious to
the welfare of the State and its citizens, and to regulate or even outlaw that
commerce. The State has done so here with respect to the fee-shooting
prohibition in I-143. When the State does so, its actions may injure
investment-backed expectations with respect to commerce in the goods at
issue without having to pay compensation.
¶133 This reasoning is legally unsustainable. Assuming, arguendo, that I-143 reflects a
determination by the State that fee shooting is a noxious use of property, it has long been
established that the mere declaration by the government that a certain property or use
thereof constitutes a nuisance does not make it so. See Yates v. Milwaukee, 77 U.S. 497,
505 (1871); see also Lucas, 505 U.S. at 1031, 112 S. Ct. at 2901-02. Addressing such a
declaration in Yates, the Supreme Court observed:
It is a doctrine not to be tolerated in this country, that a municipal
corporation, without any general laws either of the city or of the state,
within which a given structure can be shown to be a nuisance, can, by its
mere declaration that it is one, subject it to removal by any person supposed
to be aggrieved, or even by the city itself. This would place every house,
every business, and all the property of the city, at the uncontrolled will of
the temporary local authorities. Yet this seems to have been the view taken
by counsel who defended this case in the Circuit Court; for that single
ordinance of the city, declaring the wharf of Yates a nuisance, and ordering
its abatement, is the only evidence in the record that it is a nuisance or an
obstruction to navigation, or in any manner injurious to the public.
Yates, 77 U.S. at 505; see also Lawton v. Steele, 152 U.S. 133, 140, 14 S. Ct. 499, 502
(1894) (“[T]he legislature has no right arbitrarily to declare that to be a nuisance which is
clearly not so.”).
21
¶134 After 83 years of sanctioning alternative livestock ranching, it appears that the
State has now decided that this activity is a noxious use of property. However, declaring
it to be so does not retroactively make it so. The State may not escape paying just
compensation for the Ranchers’ losses through the mere expedient of declaring that
which formerly was not a public nuisance to have been a public nuisance all along.
3. Undertone about Alternative Livestock Ranchers
¶135 One final point must be made before concluding this discussion. There exists in
the State’s and the Sportsmen’s briefs, and in the Court’s Opinion as well, an undertone
that alternative livestock ranchers are bad people who were engaged in an offensive
business and deserved to be shut down. This undertone is not properly a part of the
takings calculus. Montana has many businesses that strike some citizens as ill-advised or
repugnant for one reason or another. Adult bookstores, strip clubs, bars, and casinos are
obvious examples, though tobacco companies, insurance companies, oil companies, and
power companies are also viewed by many with contempt. Though regulated, we tolerate
the existence of businesses and activities that offend some segments of the population as
the price for living in a free-market economy and an open society that values
entrepreneurial activity. The fact that an individual’s lawful business activity is offensive
to some, however, does not itself negate the requirement that the State pay just
compensation for taking that individual’s property.
D. Misplaced Reliance on Due Process Considerations
¶136 The foregoing discussion leads into the fourth and final preliminary matter:
misplaced reliance on due process considerations. Broadly speaking, the issue we must
22
decide on this appeal is whether the governmental action embodied in I-143 amounted to
a “taking” of the Ranchers’ property. In answering this question, relevant considerations
include “the actual burden imposed on property rights” and “how that burden is
allocated.” Lingle v. Chevron U.S.A. Inc., 544 U.S. 528, 543, 125 S. Ct. 2074, 2084
(2005). In contrast, whether I-143 “substantially advances legitimate state interests” or is
“reasonably necessary to the effectuation of a substantial public purpose” is irrelevant,
since such considerations are pertinent to a due process analysis, not a takings analysis.
See Lingle, 544 U.S. at 540-42, 125 S. Ct. at 2082-84.
¶137 Although the Sportsmen acknowledge that due process tests have “no proper
place” in takings analysis, they embark on a lengthy discussion about the legitimacy of
I-143, arguing that it is “vital” to the protection of Montana’s wildlife and to the tradition
of fair-chase hunting. Indeed, the Sportsmen consume roughly a third of their appellate
brief expounding on “I-143’s purposes and the importance of those purposes.” The
Sportsmen conclude that the “weighty” and “important” purposes served by I-143 “tip the
scales” against the State’s having to pay compensation for any diminution in the value of
the Ranchers’ property.
¶138 Similarly, the State acknowledges that due process precedents “are not especially
helpful” in resolving the Ranchers’ takings claims. Nevertheless, the State contends that
I-143 is “a valid police power regulation that substantially advances a number of
important interests.” Likewise, the District Court observed that I-143 is “a valid police
power regulation that reasonably advances the protection of the health, safety, and
welfare of the State and its citizens” and that “[t]he State introduced unrebutted evidence
23
that I-143 advances substantial state interests.” The District Court concluded that these
factors “weigh heavily against requiring the State to pay compensation here.”
¶139 That the Sportsmen, the State, and the District Court have emphasized these sorts
of considerations in their respective analyses is not surprising, given that the Supreme
Court long analyzed takings claims under substantive due process principles. Such
considerations, however, are not instructive of whether property has been taken; indeed,
they are completely irrelevant. Thus, as the Ranchers correctly point out, it is improper
(for purposes of analyzing their takings claims) to conduct a “means-ends” analysis of
I-143 and the District Court, therefore, erred in factoring due process considerations into
its analysis. To understand why, it is helpful to begin with some historical background.
1. Nineteenth Century Regulatory Takings
¶140 Contrary to the Court’s assertion in ¶ 67, the notion of a regulatory taking—where
the government regulates private property rights, as opposed to condemning or directly
appropriating private property—was recognized in this country long before 1922.
Indeed, recognition of this sort of taking may be found in the 19th century decisions of
numerous state courts and even the Supreme Court. See generally Kris W. Kobach, The
Origins of Regulatory Takings: Setting the Record Straight, 1996 Utah L. Rev. 1211;
Andrew S. Gold, Regulatory Takings and Original Intent: The Direct, Physical Takings
Thesis “Goes Too Far,” 49 Am. U. L. Rev. 181, 228-38 (1999); Eric R. Claeys, Takings,
Regulations, and Natural Property Rights, 88 Cornell L. Rev. 1549 (2003); David A.
Thomas, Finding More Pieces for the Takings Puzzle: How Correcting History Can
Clarify Doctrine, 75 U. Colo. L. Rev. 497, 519-33 (2004).
24
¶141 The Court insists that its contrary version of history is “both historically accurate
and well-established.” Opinion, ¶ 67 n. 8. Yet, tellingly, the Court fails to produce one
single shred of historical authority to back up this claim. Rather, the Court merely cites
the same demonstrably incorrect historical accounts that the scholars ably refute in their
respective articles cited above. The Court apparently fails to recognize that “[the
Supreme] Court’s opinions frequently make assertions of historical fact, but those
assertions are not authoritative as to history in the same way that [the Supreme Court’s]
interpretations of laws are authoritative as to them.” Seminole Tribe of Florida v.
Florida, 517 U.S. 44, 106 n. 5, 116 S. Ct. 1114, 1148 n. 5 (1996) (Souter, Ginsburg, &
Breyer, JJ., dissenting). Moreover, that the Supreme Court has “repeated [a] mistake
does not transform error into truth.” Dickerson v. United States, 530 U.S. 428, 460, 120
S. Ct. 2326, 2345 (2000) (Scalia & Thomas, JJ., dissenting). If the origins of regulatory
takings doctrine is critical to the Court’s analysis—and footnote 8 of the Opinion seems
to suggest that it is—then it is curious that the Court would ignore authority which
plainly refutes its statements in this regard. Not wanting to expend an inordinate amount
of time on this point, I note just four of the cases here. Others are discussed in the
articles cited above.
¶142 At issue in People v. Platt, 17 Johns. 195 (N.Y. Sup. 1819), were statutes that
required the owners of dams on certain rivers to alter the dams so that salmon could pass
freely over them. Platt, who owned a milldam across a nonnavigable river that flowed
through his property, refused to make the required alterations. In considering the case,
the court first observed that Platt had a “right to the exclusive enjoyment of the river”
25
within the bounds of his property. Platt, 17 Johns. at 212. The court acknowledged that
the legislature had the power to take property for public purposes, but the court reasoned
that such appropriations “are constitutional, legal, and justifiable, only when a fair and
just equivalent is awarded to the owner of property thus taken.” Platt, 17 Johns. at 215.
Here, the court observed, “no equivalent is offered, or provided, for the loss which must
inevitably ensue, upon a compliance with the requirements of the statutes.” Platt, 17
Johns. at 215. Thus, because the statutes interfered with the usage rights associated with
Platt’s riparian property, the court held the statutes were void as applied to him, absent
payment of compensation.
¶143 In Woodruff v. Neal, 28 Conn. 165 (1859), the defendant impounded the plaintiff’s
cow, which had been grazing along a public highway that passed through the defendant’s
land. The plaintiff claimed he had the right to depasture his cow along the highway by
virtue of a government-issued license authorizing neat cattle to go at large. The court,
however, observed that a highway is an easement conferring on the public only a right of
passage and that the landowner retains the fee and “all rights of property” in the land.
Woodruff, 28 Conn. at 167. Among the retained rights, the court noted, was that of “the
herbage of the land, which belongs exclusively to him, and having himself thus the right
to depasture it, he may maintain trespass against any one who puts his cattle upon it to
graze.” Woodruff, 28 Conn. at 167. Accordingly, in the absence of compensation to the
owner of the land upon which the plaintiff’s license was to be exercised, the court held
that granting the license was “beyond the constitutional power of the legislature.”
Woodruff, 28 Conn. at 169. Notably, a government-authorized permanent physical
26
invasion of another’s private property is now recognized as one of “two categories of
regulatory action that generally will be deemed per se takings for Fifth Amendment
purposes.” Lingle, 544 U.S. at 538, 125 S. Ct. at 2081 (citing Loretto v. Teleprompter
Manhattan CATV Corp., 458 U.S. 419, 102 S. Ct. 3164 (1982) (state law requiring
landlords to permit cable companies to install cable facilities in apartment buildings
effected a taking)).
¶144 Lastly, Walker v. Shepardson, 4 Wis. 486 (1855), and Yates v. Milwaukee, 77 U.S.
497 (1871), involved a wharf that extended from Yates’s lot into the Milwaukee River.
Under Wisconsin law, a riparian proprietor bounded by a navigable stream owned the
land to the center of the stream, subject to a public easement to use the stream for
navigation. See Walker, 4 Wis. at 508. Furthermore, he had “the right to use [his] land
which is covered by the water of the river, in any way compatible with the use of the
stream for the purposes of navigation,” including constructing docks or landing places for
goods or passengers. Walker, 4 Wis. at 508-09. The City of Milwaukee, however,
established a dock line which, as it passed in front of Yates’s lot, was 100 feet away from
the navigable channel of the river. In other words, the City prohibited Yates from
maintaining a dock over that part of his land between the dock line and the navigable part
of the river, though a dock in this location would not have interfered with the public’s
easement. In so doing, the City rendered this section of his property worthless, and the
court held that “it would be necessary to make compensation to the owner for the
property which would thus be rendered valueless by this act of the common council.”
Walker, 4 Wis. at 512; cf. Lingle, 544 U.S. at 538, 125 S. Ct. at 2081 (a regulation that
27
completely deprives an owner of “all economically beneficial use” of her property is a
per se taking (citing Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 1019, 112
S. Ct. 2886, 2895 (1992))).
¶145 The City then declared Yates’s wharf to be a nuisance and ordered its abatement.
See Yates, 77 U.S. at 505. The case eventually reached the Supreme Court, which held
that the mere declaration that Yates’s wharf is a nuisance does not make it so. Yates, 77
U.S. at 505. More pertinent to the present discussion are the Supreme Court’s statements
respecting Yates’s entitlement to compensation. In particular, the Court observed that
among “the rights of a riparian proprietor whose land is bounded by a navigable stream”
are “access to the navigable part of the river from the front of his lot” and “the right to
make a landing, wharf or pier for his own use or for the use of the public.” Yates, 77 U.S.
at 504. This “riparian right,” the Court observed,
is property, and is valuable, and, though i t must be enjoyed in due
subjection to the rights of the public, it cannot be arbitrarily or capriciously
destroyed or impaired. It is a right of which, when once vested, the owner
can only be deprived in accordance with established law, and if necessary
that it be taken for the public good, upon due compensation.
Yates, 77 U.S. at 504. Thus, the Supreme Court held that if the City creates a dock line
which “deprive[s] riparian owners of the right to avail themselves of the advantage of the
navigable channel by building wharves and docks to it for that purpose,” compensation is
required. Yates, 77 U.S. at 505, 507. Notably, the following year, the Supreme Court
reaffirmed “that a serious interruption to the common and necessary use of property may
be . . . equivalent to the taking of it, and that under the constitutional provisions it is not
28
necessary that the land should be absolutely taken.” Pumpelly v. Green Bay &
Mississippi Canal Co., 80 U.S. 166, 179 (1872).
¶146 In sum, 19th century courts recognized what we now think of as “regulatory
takings” of property, and the assertion that these are a “modern” phenomenon (Opinion,
¶ 67) is simply wrong. Indeed, none of the foregoing cases involved “physical invasion
or outright appropriation” by the government (Opinion, ¶ 67).
¶147 As an aside, it is interesting that the “bundle-of-sticks” conception of property—
i.e., the view that “property” is a bundle of discrete rights associated with a thing, such as
the rights of usage, exclusion, alienation, access, and alteration—was frequently seen in
the cases of this period. See Kobach, 1996 Utah L. Rev. at 1236, 1252. Each discrete
right was protected to the same degree as the next. Moreover, in determining whether a
state action constituted a compensable taking, courts which adhered to this conception of
property, “imposed neither a threshold dollar value for the total injury nor a minimum
percentage by which the entire property had to be devalued. Instead, a much simpler rule
seemed to underlie their opinions: if any discrete stick in the bundle was taken,
compensation was required.” Kobach, 1996 Utah L. Rev. at 1252.
2. The Supreme Court’s Substantive Due Process Approach
¶148 As touched on in the discussion of police power/noxious use theory above, the
Supreme Court during the last quarter of the 19th century analyzed regulatory takings
claims against the States under the Fourteenth Amendment’s Due Process Clause. See
Bradley C. Karkkainen, The Police Power Revisited: Phantom Incorporation and the
Roots of the Takings “Muddle,” 90 Minn. L. Rev. 826, 847-50 (2006); see also Kobach,
29
1996 Utah L. Rev. at 1276-85 (explaining that in Railroad Co. v. Richmond, 96 U.S. 521
(1878), Transportation Co. v. Chicago, 99 U.S. 635 (1879), Mugler v. Kansas, 123 U.S.
623, 8 S. Ct. 273 (1887), and Scranton v. Wheeler, 179 U.S. 141, 21 S. Ct. 48 (1900), the
Supreme Court “retreated” from the takings doctrine it had enunciated in Yates and
Pumpelly). The analysis turned centrally on whether the challenged regulation fell within
the legitimate bounds of the state’s police power, since that power was viewed as an
inherent limitation on state-law property rights. In other words, if the regulation was a
legitimate exercise of the police power, no compensation was required for the simple
reason that no deprivation of property had occurred. See Karkkainen, 90 Minn. L. Rev. at
830-31, 838-42; see also e.g. Powell v. Pennsylvania, 127 U.S. 678, 683-87, 8 S. Ct. 992,
995-97 (1888); Chicago, Burlington & Quincy Railroad Co. v. Chicago (“Chicago,
B & Q”), 166 U.S. 226, 252, 17 S. Ct. 581, 590-91 (1897). The Court followed this
approach well into the 20th century.2 See e.g. Atlantic Coast Line R. Co. v. Goldsboro,
2
Chicago, B & Q has been cited as the case in which the protections of the Fifth
Amendment’s Takings Clause were made applicable to the States through the Fourteenth
Amendment. See e.g. Penn Central Transp. Co. v. New York City, 438 U.S. 104, 122, 98
S. Ct. 2646, 2658 (1978); Dolan v. City of Tigard, 512 U.S. 374, 383-84, 114 S. Ct. 2309,
2316 (1994). However, Chicago, B & Q contains no mention of either the Takings
Clause or the Fifth Amendment. Rather, the case was decided on substantive due process
grounds. The Supreme Court held that the Fourteenth Amendment’s Due Process Clause
“requires compensation to be made or adequately secured to the owner of private
property taken for public use under the authority of a State.” See Chicago, B & Q, 166
U.S. at 235-41, 17 S. Ct. at 584-86; see also Dolan, 512 U.S. at 405-06, 114 S. Ct. at
2326-27 (Stevens, Blackmun, & Ginsburg, JJ., dissenting). This compensation
requirement derived from “universal law” and “natural equity,” not the Fifth
Amendment. See Chicago, B & Q, 166 U.S. at 236, 17 S. Ct. at 584; Karkkainen, 90
Minn. L. Rev. at 829-30. In his article, Professor Karkkainen persuasively demonstrates
that it was not until 1978, in Penn Central, that the Supreme Court first explicitly held the
Takings Clause applicable to the States. See Karkkainen, 90 Minn. L. Rev. at 838-78.
30
232 U.S. 548, 558-59, 34 S. Ct. 364, 368 (1914); New Orleans Public Service, Inc. v.
New Orleans, 281 U.S. 682, 687, 50 S. Ct. 449, 450 (1930); Goldblatt v. Hempstead, 369
U.S. 590, 592, 82 S. Ct. 987, 989 (1962); but see Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon, 260
U.S. 393, 415, 43 S. Ct. 158, 160 (1922) (“When this seemingly absolute protection [of
private property] is found to be qualified by the police power, the natural tendency of
human nature is to extend the qualification more and more until at last private property
disappears. But that cannot be accomplished in this way under the Constitution of the
United States.”).
¶149 The line which separated legitimate from illegitimate exercises of the police
power, in turn, hinged on the following: whether the regulation was in some way
designed to promote the health, safety, or welfare of the community; whether the means
employed had a real and substantial relation to the avowed or ostensible purpose of the
regulation; and whether the interference with private rights was not wanton or arbitrary.
See e.g. Mugler, 123 U.S. at 661, 8 S. Ct. at 297; Lawton v. Steele, 152 U.S. 133, 137, 14
S. Ct. 499, 501 (1894); Dobbins v. Los Angeles, 195 U.S. 223, 238-39, 25 S. Ct. 18, 21
(1904); St. Louis, Iron Mt. & S. Ry. Co. v. Wynne, 224 U.S. 354, 359-60, 32 S. Ct. 493,
494 (1912); Atlantic Coast Line, 232 U.S. at 559, 34 S. Ct. at 368; Reinman v. Little
Rock, 237 U.S. 171, 176-77, 35 S. Ct. 511, 513 (1915); Hadacheck v. Sebastian, 239 U.S.
394, 410, 36 S. Ct. 143, 145 (1915); Village of Euclid v. Ambler Realty Co., 272 U.S.
365, 387, 395, 47 S. Ct. 114, 118, 121 (1926); Miller v. Schoene, 276 U.S. 272, 279-80,
48 S. Ct. 246, 247-48 (1928); Nectow v. Cambridge, 277 U.S. 183, 188, 48 S. Ct. 447,
448 (1928); Goldblatt, 369 U.S. at 594-95, 82 S. Ct. at 990.
31
3. Penn Central’s Conflation of Doctrines
¶150 Meanwhile, during this same period, the Fifth Amendment’s Takings Clause
operated as a parallel and similar, but nonetheless distinct and independent strand of
constitutional doctrine, with its own canonical precedents. See Karkkainen, 90 Minn. L.
Rev. at 855-61 (and cases discussed therein). In Penn Central Transp. Co. v. New York
City, 438 U.S. 104, 98 S. Ct. 2646 (1978), however, the Supreme Court collapsed its
substantive due process and takings precedents into a single Fifth Amendment regulatory
takings test applicable to both state and federal actions, thereby creating a “muddle.” See
John D. Echeverria & Sharon Dennis, The Takings Issue and the Due Process Clause: A
Way Out of a Doctrinal Confusion, 17 Vt. L. Rev. 695, 695-703 (1993). The Court
articulated a number of factors that it considered pertinent under this test, including the
economic impact of the regulation on the property owner, the extent to which the
regulation has interfered with distinct investment-backed expectations, the character of
the governmental action, and whether the regulation has an unduly harsh impact upon the
owner’s use of the property. Penn Central, 438 U.S. at 124, 127, 98 S. Ct. at 2659,
2660-61. In addition, the Court retained the fundamental precepts of substantive due
process doctrine. See Penn Central, 438 U.S. at 125-27, 98 S. Ct. at 2659-61 (discussing
or citing, among others, Nectow, Euclid, Miller, Hadacheck, Reinman, Mugler, and
Goldblatt). In particular, the Court reaffirmed that “a use restriction on real property may
constitute a ‘taking’ if not reasonably necessary to the effectuation of a substantial public
purpose.” Penn Central, 438 U.S. at 127, 98 S. Ct. at 2660. Ultimately, the Court
concluded that the regulation at issue (New York City’s Landmarks Preservation Law)
32
had not effected a taking of the appellants’ property because “[t]he restrictions imposed
are substantially related to the promotion of the general welfare and not only permit
reasonable beneficial use of the landmark site but also afford appellants opportunities
further to enhance not only the Terminal site proper but also other properties.” Penn
Central, 438 U.S. at 138, 98 S. Ct. at 2666.
¶151 As a conflation of substantive due process and takings doctrines, the Penn Central
inquiry necessarily reflected elements of both. Two years later, in Agins v. City of
Tiburon, 447 U.S. 255, 100 S. Ct. 2138 (1980), the Supreme Court summarized the
takings inquiry as follows: “The application of a general zoning law to particular
property effects a taking if the ordinance does not substantially advance legitimate state
interests or denies an owner economically viable use of his land.” Agins, 447 U.S. at
260, 100 S. Ct. at 2141 (citing Nectow, 277 U.S. at 188, 48 S. Ct. at 448, and Penn
Central, 438 U.S. at 138 n. 36, 98 S. Ct. at 2666 n. 36). The “substantially advances”
prong of this test was repeated in numerous subsequent cases, see Monterey v. Del Monte
Dunes at Monterey, Ltd., 526 U.S. 687, 704, 119 S. Ct. 1624, 1636 (1999) (citing cases),
and remained in place for the next 25 years.
4. Lingle’s Clarifications
¶152 In Lingle v. Chevron U.S.A. Inc., 544 U.S. 528, 125 S. Ct. 2074 (2005), the
Supreme Court jettisoned the “substantially advances” formulation. The Court observed
that the Takings Clause was designed not to limit governmental interference with
property rights per se, but rather to secure compensation in the event of otherwise proper
interference amounting to a taking. Lingle, 544 U.S. at 537, 125 S. Ct. at 2080. With
33
respect to regulatory takings, the Court framed the dispositive question as whether the
regulation is “so onerous that its effect is tantamount to a direct appropriation or ouster.”
Lingle, 544 U.S. at 537, 125 S. Ct. at 2081. To answer this question, the Court explained,
courts must focus on “the severity of the burden that government imposes upon private
property rights.” Lingle, 544 U.S. at 539, 125 S. Ct. at 2082.
¶153 The “substantially advances” formula, however, suggests a means-ends test: It
asks, in essence, whether a regulation of private property is effective in achieving some
legitimate public purpose. Lingle, 544 U.S. at 542, 125 S. Ct. at 2083. Of course, this is
the due process inquiry the Court had long applied when analyzing regulatory takings
claims against the States under the Fourteenth Amendment. In Lingle, however, the
Court made clear that this sort of inquiry is ineffective for discerning whether private
property has been “taken” for purposes of the Fifth Amendment:
[T]he “substantially advances” inquiry reveals nothing about the magnitude
or character of the burden a particular regulation imposes upon private
property rights. Nor does i t provide any information about how any
regulatory burden is distributed among property owners. In consequence,
this test does not help to identify those regulations whose effects are
functionally comparable to government appropriation or invasion of private
property; it is tethered neither to the text of the Takings Clause nor to the
basic justification for allowing regulatory actions to be challenged under
the Clause.
. . .
Instead of addressing a challenged regulation’s effect on private
property, the “substantially advances” inquiry probes the regulation’s
underlying validity. But such an inquiry is logically prior to and distinct
from the question whether a regulation effects a taking, for the Takings
Clause presupposes that the government has acted in pursuit of a valid
public purpose. The Clause expressly requires compensation where
government takes private property “for public use.” It does not bar
government from interfering with property rights, but rather requires
34
compensation “in the event of otherwise proper interference amounting to a
taking.” Conversely, if a government action is found to be impermissible—
for instance because it fails to meet the “public use” requirement or is so
arbitrary as to violate due process—that is the end of the inquiry. No
amount of compensation can authorize such action.
Lingle, 544 U.S. at 542-43, 125 S. Ct. at 2084 (citation omitted).
¶154 Lingle, therefore, is an important clarification of federal regulatory takings law.
The critical focus in a regulatory takings case is on the severity of the burden a particular
regulation imposes on private property rights and how that regulatory burden is
distributed among property owners. The due process and means-ends considerations that
had informed the Court’s prior decisions are no longer appropriate measures of whether a
taking has occurred.
¶155 It is also important to note here that in Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council,
505 U.S. 1003, 112 S. Ct. 2886 (1992), the Supreme Court explicitly rejected the notion
that a valid police power regulation never requires compensation to the owner. The
Court observed that there are “limits to the noncompensable exercise of the police
power.” Lucas, 505 U.S. at 1026, 112 S. Ct. at 2899. Otherwise, if “the uses of private
property were subject to unbridled, uncompensated qualification under the police power,
‘the natural tendency of human nature [would be] to extend the qualification more and
more until at last private property disappear[ed].’ ” Lucas, 505 U.S. at 1014, 112 S. Ct. at
2892-93 (brackets in Lucas) (quoting Mahon, 260 U.S. at 415, 43 S. Ct. at 160).
5. Conclusion
¶156 The due process considerations pervading the District Court’s decision and the
Sportsmen’s and the State’s respective arguments may be understood in light of the many
35
Supreme Court precedents which analyze regulatory takings claims using due process
principles. However, such considerations are misplaced in light of Lingle. The Ranchers
are not precluded from recovering for a constitutional taking simply because the State
was exercising its police powers, or because I-143 substantially advances legitimate state
interests. Indeed, we assume going into the takings analysis that the governmental
actions embodied in I-143 are valid, and the central question we address is whether I-143
is “so onerous that its effect is tantamount to a direct appropriation or ouster.” See
Lingle, 544 U.S. at 537, 543, 125 S. Ct. at 2081, 2084.
III. ANALYSIS OF THE RANCHERS’ TAKINGS CLAIMS
A. The Basis of the Ranchers’ Claims
¶157 The Ranchers filed this action against the State, and the Sportsmen intervened as
defendants a month later. The Ranchers challenged I-143 on various grounds, including
due process and equal protection, and they sought declaratory and injunctive relief. In
the alternative, if I-143 were found to be constitutional and enforceable against them, the
Ranchers sought just compensation for a regulatory taking of their property. The
Ranchers, in other words, brought an “inverse condemnation” action.
¶158 The phrase “inverse condemnation” is a shorthand description of the manner in
which a property owner recovers just compensation for a taking of his property when
condemnation proceedings have not been instituted. United States v. Clarke, 445 U.S.
253, 257, 100 S. Ct. 1127, 1130 (1980). Whereas a condemnation proceeding typically
involves an action by the condemnor to acquire title to property, inverse condemnation is
an action by the property owner against a governmental defendant to recover the value of
36
property that has been taken, even though no formal exercise of the power of eminent
domain has been attempted by the government. See Clarke, 445 U.S. at 257, 100 S. Ct. at
1130; see also First English Evangelical Lutheran Church v. Los Angeles County, 482
U.S. 304, 316, 107 S. Ct. 2378, 2386 (1987) (“While the typical taking occurs when the
government acts to condemn property in the exercise of its power of eminent domain, the
entire doctrine of inverse condemnation is predicated on the proposition that a taking may
occur without such formal proceedings.”). Thus, “inverse condemnation” describes an
action that is the “inverse” or “reverse” of a condemnation proceeding. Clarke, 445 U.S.
at 257, 100 S. Ct. at 1130. “The owner’s right to bring such a suit derives from the self-
executing character of the constitutional provision with respect to condemnation.” Kirby
Forest Industries, Inc. v. United States, 467 U.S. 1, 5 n. 6, 104 S. Ct. 2187, 2191 n. 6
(1984) (internal quotation marks omitted).
¶159 Here, the State did not condemn the Ranchers’ property through a formal
proceeding; rather, the State regulated their property through passage of I-143. As a
result, the Ranchers brought an inverse condemnation action to recover for their losses
caused by the Initiative. See Southview Assoc. v. Bongartz, 980 F.2d 84, 93 n. 3 (2d Cir.
1992) (“Essentially, a regulatory taking—also known as inverse condemnation—occurs
when the purpose of government regulation and its economic effect on the property
owner render the regulation substantively equivalent to an eminent domain proceeding
and, therefore, require the government to pay compensation to the property owner.”);
Julius L. Sackman, Nichols on Eminent Domain vol. 2A, § 6.03[1], 6-182 (3d ed.,
Matthew Bender 2006) (“[S]ome regulatory or other activities may effect a taking,
37
necessitating that owners bring inverse condemnation proceedings against the
government.”).
B. The Constitutional Basis for Our Decision
¶160 The Ranchers seek relief under the Fifth Amendment to the United States
Constitution and Article II, Section 29 of the Montana Constitution. Yet, while the
Court’s decision purports to rest on both of these provisions, see Opinion, ¶¶ 29, 54, 63,
65, and while the Court acknowledges that the plain language of the two provisions
differs, Opinion, ¶ 30—indeed, the language of Article II, Section 29 is facially broader
than the language of the Fifth Amendment—the Court nevertheless offers no independent
interpretation of Article II, Section 29. Quite to the contrary, the Court decides to follow
“our previous approach of looking towards federal jurisprudence when considering
takings claims under Montana law.” Opinion, ¶ 31. In so doing, the Court equates the
Ranchers’ claims under the Fifth Amendment with the Ranchers’ claims under Article II,
Section 29.
¶161 The Court offers a singularly unpersuasive explanation for this approach: “[The
Ranchers] rely almost exclusively on federal case law.” Opinion, ¶ 31. That, however, is
hardly a justification for treating a claim brought under a facially broader provision of the
Montana Constitution as no different from a claim brought under the provision’s
counterpart in the United States Constitution. Moreover, if it seems that the Ranchers are
relying “almost exclusively” on federal caselaw, it is because there is very little, if any,
Montana caselaw on point. And this jurisprudential void is not likely to be filled when
this Court persists in the utterly circular and self-perpetuating syllogism: because this
38
Court in the past has looked to federal caselaw for guidance when considering takings
claims, the Ranchers have relied on federal caselaw in support of their position, and
because the Ranchers have relied on federal caselaw in support of their position, we will
look to federal caselaw in considering their takings claims.
¶162 Of course, “[i]t is perfectly proper for us to use criteria developed in federal cases”
when state law is silent or lacking. Pfost v. State, 219 Mont. 206, 216, 713 P.2d 495, 501
(1985), overruled on other grounds, Meech v. Hillhaven West, Inc., 238 Mont. 21, 26,
776 P.2d 488, 491 (1989). It is also proper for us to rely on federal jurisprudence as
persuasive authority. But there is a vast difference between looking to federal law for
guidance and allowing federal-court decisions to dictate the meaning and substance of
Montana’s Constitution. Unfortunately, in the case at hand, the Court has done the latter
by conflating the Ranchers’ federal and state constitutional claims into one.
¶163 It would be one thing if the Court simply refused to reach the Ranchers’ claims
under Article II, Section 29 on the ground that they had failed to raise it adequately. See
e.g. State v. Garrymore, 2006 MT 245, ¶¶ 38-39, 334 Mont. 1, ¶¶ 38-39, 145 P.3d 946,
¶¶ 38-39 (concluding that Garrymore’s argument under Article II, Sections 24 and 26
was “too undeveloped to undertake a distinctive application of state constitutional
principles”); State v. Rosling, 2008 MT 62, ¶ 66, 342 Mont. 1, ¶ 66, 180 P.3d 1102, ¶ 66
(same). But that is not what the Court does. Rather, notwithstanding the Ranchers’
reliance “almost exclusively” on federal caselaw and the Ranchers’ corresponding failure
to develop their theory of relief under the Montana Constitution to the Court’s
satisfaction—the exact situation we faced in Garrymore and Rosling—the Court proceeds
39
to issue a decision that likewise relies almost exclusively on Fifth Amendment cases but
is grounded, in part, on Article II, Section 29. This equating of the two constitutional
provisions is regrettable, not only because it denigrates our own Constitution and renders
Article II, Section 29 little more than a constitutional redundancy, but also because it is
totally unnecessary. If the Ranchers are to be faulted for failing to cite precedents under
Article II, Section 29 to the Court’s satisfaction, then their claims should be resolved
under M. R. App. P. 12(1)f., not by conflating their federal and state constitutional claims
into one.
¶164 According to the State, the Ranchers “conceded in the court below that the reach
of the Taking Clause under the Fifth Amendment and the protection from uncompensated
takings found in Article II, Section 29 of the Montana Constitution are co-extensive.” As
support for this assertion, the State directs us to the following statement by the Ranchers
in one of their District Court filings: “The Montana Supreme Court is generally in accord
with federal case law on the analysis of takings.” (The Court refers to this statement as
well. See Opinion, ¶ 31.) This, however, is hardly the concession the State makes it out
to be. The Ranchers did not “concede” that the protections of the Fifth Amendment and
Article II, Section 29 are “co-extensive.” They merely offered a candid
acknowledgement of this Court’s past approach, which is to “look[ ] towards federal
jurisprudence when considering takings claims under Montana law” (Opinion, ¶ 31).
More importantly, this supposed concession that the protections of the Fifth Amendment
and Article II, Section 29 are “co-extensive” does not establish that they are so. This
Court, not the Ranchers, determines the “reach” of Article II, Section 29.
40
¶165 We have recognized that the provisions of Article II are “separate and enforceable
constitutional rights insofar as the jurisdiction of the State of Montana extends.”
Madison v. Yunker, 180 Mont. 54, 60, 589 P.2d 126, 129 (1978). We have also said that
“we will not reach a federal constitutional challenge unless and until the case may not be
resolved on adequate and independent state grounds.” Buckman v. Montana Deaconess
Hosp., 224 Mont. 318, 325, 730 P.2d 380, 384 (1986). Along these same lines, we have
stated that where the constitutionality of a governmental act affecting property rights is
attacked under both the United States Constitution and the Montana Constitution, “we
believe it to be our duty, irrespective of the holdings of other courts, to consider and
apply the provisions of our own Constitution and general statutes thereto, and declare the
rule of property for Montana.” Gas Products Co. v. Rankin, 63 Mont. 372, 388, 207 P.
993, 997-98 (1922). Finally, when interpreting provisions of Article II, we have long
refused to march lockstep with the United States Supreme Court’s pronouncements
concerning similar provisions of the federal constitution.3
¶166 For these reasons, our approach in this case should be to address the Ranchers’
claims first under the Montana Constitution and then, if necessary, under the United
3
See e.g. Walker v. State, 2003 MT 134, ¶ 73, 316 Mont. 103, ¶ 73, 68 P.3d 872,
¶ 73 (holding that Article II, Sections 4 and 22 provide greater protection than the Eighth
Amendment); State v. Guillaume, 1999 MT 29, ¶ 16, 293 Mont. 224, ¶ 16, 975 P.2d 312,
¶ 16 (holding that Article II, Section 25 provides greater protection than the Fifth
Amendment); Woirhaye v. District Court, 1998 MT 320, ¶¶ 6-26, 292 Mont. 185, ¶¶ 6-
26, 972 P.2d 800, ¶¶ 6-26 (concluding that Article II, Sections 24 and 26 provide greater
protection than the Sixth Amendment); Gryczan v. State, 283 Mont. 433, 447-51, 942
P.2d 112, 120-23 (1997) (concluding that Article II, Section 10, provides greater
protection than the federal constitution’s right to privacy); Vernon Kills On Top v. State,
279 Mont. 384, 420-24, 928 P.2d 182, 204-07 (1996) (concluding that Article II, Section
22 provides greater protection than the Eighth Amendment).
41
States Constitution. The Court’s decision, however, is based entirely on Fifth
Amendment jurisprudence. Moreover, although the Ranchers cite Article II, Section 29
as a basis for relief, their corresponding argument is largely undeveloped. Cf.
Garrymore, ¶¶ 38-39; Rosling, ¶ 66. Accordingly, I will analyze the Ranchers’ claims
under the Fifth Amendment, rather than Article II, Section 29. In so doing, I will also
explain my disagreement with the Court’s corresponding Fifth Amendment analysis. As
for Article II, Section 29, the claim that I-143 effected a taking or damaging of property
under the Montana Constitution is better developed by the appellants in the companion
case, Buhmann v. State (No. 05-473). Therefore, I will address Article II, Section 29
within the context of that case and explain why that provision entitles the Buhmann
appellants to just compensation.
C. Analytical Framework and Relevant Principles under the Fifth Amendment
¶167 The Fifth Amendment states: “nor shall private property be taken for public use,
without just compensation.” U.S. Const. amend. V. In analyzing a takings claim in the
context of an inverse condemnation action, the court first determines whether the plaintiff
possesses a constitutionally protected property interest. Ruckelshaus v. Monsanto Co.,
467 U.S. 986, 1000, 104 S. Ct. 2862, 2871 (1984); Huntleigh USA Corp. v. United States,
525 F.3d 1370, 1377 (Fed. Cir. 2008). Whether one has a protected property interest is a
question of law. See Texas State Bank v. United States, 423 F.3d 1370, 1378 (Fed. Cir.
2005). If the plaintiff possesses a protected property interest, the court then determines
whether a part or a whole of that interest has been taken for public use, thus entitling the
plaintiff to just compensation. Monsanto, 467 U.S. at 1000-01, 104 S. Ct. at 2871;
42
Members of Peanut Quota Holders Ass’n v. United States, 421 F.3d 1323, 1330 (Fed. Cir.
2005). The issue of whether a taking has occurred is a question of law based on factual
underpinnings. Huntleigh, 525 F.3d at 1377.
¶168 With respect to the first question (whether the plaintiff possesses a constitutionally
protected property interest), the Constitution protects, but does not create, property
interests. Phillips v. Washington Legal Foundation, 524 U.S. 156, 164, 118 S. Ct. 1925,
1930 (1998). Rather, property interests “are created and their dimensions are defined by
existing rules or understandings that stem from an independent source such as state law.”
Monsanto, 467 U.S. at 1001, 104 S. Ct. at 2872 (internal quotation marks omitted);
accord Phillips, 524 U.S. at 164, 118 S. Ct. at 1930. In this regard, the term “property,”
as used in the Takings Clause, is not restricted to any particular type of property. To the
contrary, it encompasses a wide variety of interests. Clearly, it includes real property,
personal property, and intangible property. Huntleigh, 525 F.3d at 1377-78. But it also
“ ‘denote[s] the group of rights inhering in the citizen’s relation to the physical thing, as
the right to possess, use and dispose of it.’ ” PruneYard Shopping Center v. Robins, 447
U.S. 74, 82 n. 6, 100 S. Ct. 2035, 2041 n. 6 (1980) (brackets in PruneYard) (quoting
United States v. General Motors Corp., 323 U.S. 373, 378, 65 S. Ct. 357, 359 (1945)).
Property interests “are about as diverse as the human mind can conceive,” Florida Rock
Industries v. United States, 18 F.3d 1560, 1572 n. 32 (Fed. Cir. 1994), and the Takings
Clause is addressed to “every sort of interest the citizen may possess,” General Motors,
323 U.S. at 378, 65 S. Ct. at 359.
43
¶169 With respect to the second question (whether a part or a whole of the plaintiff’s
property interest has been taken for public use), the Supreme Court’s precedents stake out
two categories of regulatory action that generally will be deemed per se takings for Fifth
Amendment purposes: first, where the government requires an owner to suffer a
permanent physical invasion of her property, and second, where a regulation completely
deprives an owner of all economically beneficial uses of her property. See Lingle v.
Chevron U.S.A. Inc., 544 U.S. 528, 538, 125 S. Ct. 2074, 2081 (2005) (citing,
respectively, Loretto v. Teleprompter Manhattan CATV Corp., 458 U.S. 419, 102 S. Ct.
3164 (1982), and Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 112 S. Ct.
2886 (1992)). Outside these two relatively narrow categories (and the special context of
land-use exactions, which are not at issue here), regulatory takings challenges are
governed by the standards set forth in Penn Central Transp. Co. v. New York City, 438
U.S. 104, 98 S. Ct. 2646 (1978). See Lingle, 544 U.S. at 538, 125 S. Ct. at 2081.
¶170 The case at hand does not involve a Loretto-type “permanent physical invasion”
claim, but the Ranchers do make several assertions that could be construed as a Lucas-
type “total regulatory taking” claim. For instance, the Kafkas assert that after I-143, there
was “no economically viable use” of their alternative livestock and that the fair market
value of their licenses and businesses “went to zero.” Likewise, citing Lucas, the
Bridgewaters and the Boumas assert that passage of I-143 “destroyed the beneficial use”
of their property and “effectively left it economically idle.” The Court also perceives a
Lucas-based theory in the Ranchers’ arguments, noting that “Appellants urge us to . . .
correctly apply the Penn Central or Lucas takings analysis.” Opinion, ¶ 36.
44
¶171 At the same time, however, the Kafkas make the dubious pronouncement that
“Lucas analysis applies to categorical takings of land, not regulatory takings of other
property interests.” In an unexpected twist, the State counters that “[w]hile Lucas on its
facts involved a claimed categorical taking of land, the principles explained by the court
in its opinion govern in other regulatory taking contexts as well, as exemplified by
[American Pelagic Fishing Co. v. United States, 379 F.3d 1363 (Fed. Cir. 2004)].” Yet,
according to the Kafkas, application of Lucas to their regulatory takings claim would be
“misguided and erroneous.” They contend that “whether the regulation at issue has
denied the claimant of the economically viable use of its property” is to be examined
under the economic-impact prong of the Penn Central test. The Bridgewaters and the
Boumas do not go so far as to reject a Lucas-based theory outright, but they, like the
Kafkas, tie their Lucas arguments to their Penn Central analysis. Accordingly, given the
lack of a distinct Lucas-based analysis in the Ranchers’ briefs, and given that their Fifth
Amendment arguments track the analytical approach set forth in Penn Central, I likewise
will address their regulatory takings challenge under Penn Central’s standards.
¶172 Two fundamental principles underlie the Supreme Court’s regulatory takings
jurisprudence. The first is Justice Holmes’ proposition that “while property may be
regulated to a certain extent, if regulation goes too far it will be recognized as a taking.”
Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon, 260 U.S. 393, 415, 43 S. Ct. 158, 160 (1922). The
second is Justice Black’s articulation of the purpose of the Takings Clause: “The Fifth
Amendment’s guarantee that private property shall not be taken for a public use without
just compensation was designed to bar Government from forcing some people alone to
45
bear public burdens which, in all fairness and justice, should be borne by the public as a
whole.” Armstrong v. United States, 364 U.S. 40, 49, 80 S. Ct. 1563, 1569 (1960).
These two principles are cited time and again in the Supreme Court’s contemporary
takings cases.4
¶173 The Supreme Court has been “unable to develop any ‘set formula’ for determining
when ‘justice and fairness’ require that economic injuries caused by public action be
compensated by the government, rather than remain disproportionately concentrated on a
few persons.” Penn Central, 438 U.S. at 124, 98 S. Ct. at 2659; accord Lingle, 544 U.S.
at 538, 125 S. Ct. at 2081. Indeed, except for the two per se categories identified above
(permanent physical invasion, and complete deprivation of all economically beneficial
use), the Court has “ ‘generally eschewed’ any set formula for determining how far is too
far, choosing instead to engage in ‘ “essentially ad hoc, factual inquiries.” ’ ” Tahoe-
Sierra Preservation Council v. Tahoe Regional Planning Agency, 535 U.S. 302, 326, 122
4
See e.g. Penn Central, 438 U.S. at 123, 98 S. Ct. at 2659; PruneYard, 447 U.S. at
82-83, 100 S. Ct. at 2041-42; Webb’s Fabulous Pharmacies, Inc. v. Beckwith, 449 U.S.
155, 163, 101 S. Ct. 446, 452 (1980); Williamson County Regional Planning Com’n v.
Hamilton Bank, 473 U.S. 172, 197-98, 105 S. Ct. 3108, 3122 (1985); Connolly v. Pension
Benefit Guar. Corp., 475 U.S. 211, 227, 106 S. Ct. 1018, 1027 (1986); Hodel v. Irving,
481 U.S. 704, 718, 107 S. Ct. 2076, 2084 (1987); First English Evangelical Lutheran
Church v. Los Angeles County, 482 U.S. 304, 316, 318-19, 107 S. Ct. 2378, 2386, 2388
(1987); Bowen v. Gilliard, 483 U.S. 587, 608, 107 S. Ct. 3008, 3021 (1987); Nollan v.
California Coastal Com’n, 483 U.S. 825, 835 n. 4, 107 S. Ct. 3141, 3148 n. 4 (1987);
Pennell v. San Jose, 485 U.S. 1, 9, 108 S. Ct. 849, 856 (1988); Yee v. Escondido, 503
U.S. 519, 529, 112 S. Ct. 1522, 1529 (1992); Lucas, 505 U.S. at 1014-15, 112 S. Ct. at
2893; Dolan v. City of Tigard, 512 U.S. 374, 384, 114 S. Ct. 2309, 2316 (1994); Suitum
v. Tahoe Regional Planning Agency, 520 U.S. 725, 734, 117 S. Ct. 1659, 1665 (1997);
Monterey v. Del Monte Dunes at Monterey, Ltd., 526 U.S. 687, 702, 119 S. Ct. 1624,
1635 (1999); Palazzolo v. Rhode Island, 533 U.S. 606, 617-18, 121 S. Ct. 2448, 2457-58
(2001); Lingle, 544 U.S. at 537, 125 S. Ct. at 2080, 2081.
46
S. Ct. 1465, 1481 (2002) (quoting Lucas, 505 U.S. at 1015, 112 S. Ct. at 2893, in turn
quoting Penn Central, 438 U.S. at 124, 98 S. Ct. at 2659).
¶174 Nevertheless, in Penn Central, the Supreme Court identified “several factors that
have particular significance” in conducting these “ad hoc, factual inquiries.” Penn
Central, 438 U.S. at 124, 98 S. Ct. at 2659. The factors include “[t]he economic impact
of the regulation on the claimant,” “the extent to which the regulation has interfered with
distinct investment-backed expectations,” and “the character of the governmental action.”
Penn Central, 438 U.S. at 124, 98 S. Ct. at 2659. The Supreme Court reaffirmed the
Penn Central test in Lingle.5 See Lingle, 544 U.S. at 538-39, 548, 125 S. Ct. at 2081-82,
2087.
¶175 In applying these factors, we must remain cognizant of the object of this exercise.
Thus, it is useful to reiterate some of the clarifications made by the Supreme Court in
Lingle and discussed in Part II-D-4 of this Dissent. In particular, the ultimate question in
a Fifth Amendment regulatory takings analysis is whether the regulation is “so onerous
that its effect is tantamount to a direct appropriation or ouster.” Lingle, 544 U.S. at 537,
125 S. Ct. at 2081. To answer this question, each of the Supreme Court’s regulatory
takings tests “focuses directly upon the severity of the burden that government imposes
upon private property rights.” Lingle, 544 U.S. at 539, 125 S. Ct. at 2082; see also
5
Incidentally, it is puzzling that the Lingle Court, on one hand, unequivocally
rejected the due process inquiry articulated in Agins but, on the other hand, reaffirmed
Penn Central’s takings test, which itself is steeped in due process doctrine (see Penn
Central, 438 U.S. at 125-27, 138, 98 S. Ct. at 2659-61, 2666). It is marginally reassuring
that in explaining the Penn Central test, the Lingle Court emphasized the economic
impact of the regulation on the plaintiff as one of the “[p]rimary” factors of the test. See
Lingle, 544 U.S. at 538-39, 125 S. Ct. at 2081-82.
47
Lingle, 544 U.S. at 542, 125 S. Ct. at 2084 (emphasizing “the magnitude or character of
the burden a particular regulation imposes upon private property rights”). For example, a
permanent physical invasion, however minimal the economic cost it entails, must be
compensated because it “eviscerates the owner’s right to exclude others from entering
and using her property—perhaps the most fundamental of all property interests.” Lingle,
544 U.S. at 539, 125 S. Ct. at 2082. In the Lucas context, compensation is required for
the complete elimination of a property’s value because “ ‘total deprivation of beneficial
use is, from the landowner’s point of view, the equivalent of a physical appropriation.’ ”
Lingle, 544 U.S. at 539-40, 125 S. Ct. at 2082 (quoting Lucas, 505 U.S. at 1017, 112
S. Ct. at 2894). And the Penn Central inquiry “turns in large part, albeit not exclusively,
upon the magnitude of a regulation’s economic impact and the degree to which it
interferes with legitimate property interests.” Lingle, 544 U.S. at 540, 125 S. Ct. at 2082.
¶176 With this framework in mind, I proceed with a Fifth Amendment analysis of the
Ranchers’ takings claims.
D. Analysis of the Ranchers’ Claims under the Fifth Amendment
¶177 The Court divides the Ranchers’ assets into four categories: alternative livestock
ranch licenses, intangible business assets, real estate interests and fixtures, and alternative
livestock. The Court explains that “[i]n cases where there is a ‘mix’ of property interests,
i t is appropriate, if warranted under the circumstances, to consider those interests
separately in a takings analysis.” Opinion, ¶ 37. Apparently, separate consideration of
property interests is “warranted” in this case because “[t]hat was the approach applied by
the District Court.” Opinion, ¶ 37. I question whether this is a legally authoritative
48
rationale for the Court’s approach. But, for the sake of argument, and because it
facilitates a comparison between the Court’s reasoning and my own, I will consider each
of the Ranchers’ assets under the categories proffered by the Court.
1. The Alternative Livestock Ranch Licenses
¶178 At the outset of discussing the Ranchers’ alternative livestock ranch licenses, it
must be pointed out that the Court’s discussion at ¶¶ 38-54 is largely off point. These
paragraphs are dedicated to the question of whether a “government-issued license” is a
compensable property interest. The Court ultimately answers this question in the
negative, at least as far as the Ranchers’ licenses are concerned. Opinion, ¶ 54. Yet,
I-143 did not revoke the Ranchers’ licenses. Indeed, the Ranchers still possess and use
their licenses, and they may continue to do so, so long as they pay the annual renewal fee,
comply with all recording and reporting requirements, and do not engage in misconduct
in operating their ranches. Sections 87-4-412(1), -423(1), -427(1), MCA (2001).
¶179 Thus, since the Ranchers still have their licenses, they obviously are not claiming
that I-143 took the licenses themselves. What the Ranchers claim, rather, is that I-143
took a particular property interest associated with the licenses—namely, the right to
transfer them and, more generally, their businesses. See Laws of Montana 2001, 2000
Ballot Issues, Initiative No. 143, § 4 (amending § 87-4-412(2), MCA); § 87-4-412(2),
MCA (2001) (“An alternative livestock ranch license for a specific facility is not
transferable.”). There can be no doubt that the right to transfer is a compensable property
interest. See Keystone Bituminous Coal Ass’n v. DeBenedictis, 480 U.S. 470, 500, 107
S. Ct. 1232, 1250 (1987) (“[T]he right to sell property [is] . . . one element of the owner’s
49
property interest.”); Andrus v. Allard, 444 U.S. 51, 65-66, 100 S. Ct. 318, 327 (1979)
(labeling the right to dispose of property—e.g., through commercial transactions—as
“one traditional property right” and one “strand” of the “bundle” of property rights an
owner possesses); Conti v. United States, 291 F.3d 1334, 1341 (Fed. Cir. 2002) (“The
rights to sell, assign, or otherwise transfer are traditional hallmarks of property.”);
Thompson v. Lincoln Nat. Life Ins. Co., 114 Mont. 521, 533, 138 P.2d 951, 957 (1943)
(“[A]n essential element of the right of private property is the right to use or dispose of it
. . . .”); § 70-1-503, MCA (“Property of any kind may be transferred, . . . .”).
¶180 I-143 abrogated the Ranchers’ ability to sell, assign, or otherwise transfer their
businesses by amending § 87-4-412(2), MCA, to prohibit the transfer of their alternative
livestock ranch licenses. Accordingly, the actual question here is whether this revocation
of the right to transfer constitutes a taking under the Penn Central inquiry—an issue the
Court conveniently sidesteps by rewriting the Ranchers’ claim to be one based on loss of
the licenses themselves, rather than loss of the right to transfer the licenses.
¶181 In answering this question, the Supreme Court’s decision in Hodel v. Irving, 481
U.S. 704, 107 S. Ct. 2076 (1987), provides useful guidance. At issue in Irving was a
regulation requiring certain undivided fractional interests in Indian lands to escheat to the
tribe. In conducting its Penn Central inquiry, the Supreme Court first concluded that the
economic impact of this regulation “can be substantial,” given the value of the underlying
lands. Irving, 481 U.S. at 714, 107 S. Ct. at 2082. Furthermore, the Court observed that
“the right to pass on valuable property to one’s heirs is itself a valuable right.” Irving,
481 U.S. at 715, 107 S. Ct. at 2082-83. Thus, even though the owners of the escheatable
50
interests had full beneficial use of their property during their lifetimes, they had lost a
valuable right associated with those interests. On the other hand, while some of the
owners may have purchased their interests with the expectation that they might pass on
the remainder to their heirs at death, most of them had acquired their interests by gift,
descent, or devise. Thus, the extent to which they had investment-backed expectations in
passing on the property was “dubious.” Irving, 481 U.S. at 715, 107 S. Ct. at 2083. Also
weighing “weakly” in favor of the statute was the “average reciprocity of advantage”—
i.e., the fact that consolidation of Indian lands in the tribe benefitted the members of the
tribe. Irving, 481 U.S. at 715-16, 107 S. Ct. at 2083 (internal quotation marks omitted).
¶182 At this point, the Supreme Court noted that if it were to stop its analysis based on
the foregoing considerations, “we might well find [the regulation] constitutional. But the
character of the Government regulation here is extraordinary.” Irving, 481 U.S. at 716,
107 S. Ct. at 2083. With reasoning that is pertinent to the Ranchers’ loss of
transferability, the Court explained:
In Kaiser Aetna v. United States, [444 U.S. 164, 176, 100 S. Ct. 383,
391 (1979)], we emphasized that the regulation destroyed “one of the most
essential sticks in the bundle of rights that are commonly characterized as
property—the right to exclude others.” Similarly, the regulation here
amounts to virtually the abrogation of the right to pass on a certain type of
property—the small undivided interest—to one’s heirs. In one form or
another, the right to pass on property—to one’s family in particular—has
been part of the Anglo-American legal system since feudal times. . . . Even
the United States concedes that total abrogation of the right to pass property
is unprecedented and likely unconstitutional. . . . Since the escheatable
interests are not, as the United States argues, necessarily de minimis, nor, as
it also argues, does the availability of inter vivos transfer obviate the need
for descent and devise, a total abrogation of these rights cannot be upheld.
Irving, 481 U.S. at 716-17, 107 S. Ct. at 2083-84.
51
¶183 Thus, the Supreme Court held that the escheat regulation “ ‘goes too far.’ ” Irving,
481 U.S. at 718, 107 S. Ct. at 2084 (quoting Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon, 260 U.S.
393, 415, 43 S. Ct. 158, 160 (1922)). The Court acknowledged the government’s “broad
authority to adjust the rules governing the descent and devise of property without
implicating the guarantees of the Just Compensation Clause.” Irving, 481 U.S. at 717,
107 S. Ct. at 2084. “The difference in this case,” the Court explained, “is the fact that
both descent and devise are completely abolished.” Irving, 481 U.S. at 717, 107 S. Ct. at
2084.
¶184 Similarly, in the case at hand, the character of the government regulation is
extraordinary. I-143 abolished one of the traditional hallmarks of property: the right to
transfer. The economic impact of this total abrogation is substantial, given that an
alternative livestock ranch license is an integral component of an alternative livestock
business. No longer may the Ranchers sell, assign, or otherwise transfer their businesses.
In this connection, the Bridgewaters point out that prior to the passage of I-143, they
received an offer of $4 million to buy their operation. Following passage, however, the
offer was withdrawn, in large part because the license could not be transferred. Under
Irving, these factors alone dictate that the Ranchers’ right to transfer has been taken.
¶185 Notably, the State might have precluded this issue from arising had it continued to
prohibit the transfer of alternative livestock ranch licenses. In that scenario, a participant
in the industry would have been hard-pressed to claim an investment-backed expectation
in being able to transfer her license and business. But in 1993, the Legislature granted
the right to transfer the licenses. See Laws of Montana 1993, ch. 315, § 6 (substituting
52
“[a] game farm license for a specific facility is transferable” for “[a] game farm license is
nontransferable” in § 87-4-412, MCA, effective April 12, 1993). The Bridgewaters
entered into the alternative livestock business in 1992 and thereafter invested in
improvements uniquely designed for operating an alternative livestock business on their
property. The Kafkas and the Boumas began investing in their respective operations in
1996. All of the Ranchers had reasonable expectations that they would be able to sell,
assign, or otherwise transfer their businesses. These investment-backed expectations
bolster the conclusion that the Ranchers have suffered a taking.
¶186 Before concluding this discussion, I pause to address several facets of the Court’s
approach. Although I consider the Court’s analysis at ¶¶ 38-54 to be largely off point, I
believe there are fundamental flaws in that analysis and that it is important to point those
out, given the deleterious impact they will have on future takings cases.
¶187 As noted, the Court addresses the question of whether the alternative livestock
ranch licenses themselves are compensable property interests. The Supreme Court has
said that for purposes of the Fifth Amendment, “[property interests] are created and their
dimensions are defined by existing rules or understandings that stem from an independent
source such as state law.” Ruckelshaus v. Monsanto Co., 467 U.S. 986, 1001, 104 S. Ct.
2862, 2872 (1984) (internal quotation marks omitted). Thus, in Monsanto, the Supreme
Court looked to Missouri law to determine whether Monsanto’s trade secrets constituted
“property.” See Monsanto, 467 U.S. at 1001-04, 104 S. Ct. at 2872-73. In so doing, the
Supreme Court stated that “intangible property rights protected by state law are deserving
of the protection of the Taking Clause.” Monsanto, 467 U.S. at 1003, 104 S. Ct. at 2873.
53
Ultimately, the Supreme Court held that “to the extent that Monsanto has an interest in its
health, safety, and environmental data cognizable as a trade-secret property right under
Missouri law, that property right is protected by the Taking Clause of the Fifth
Amendment.” Monsanto, 467 U.S. at 1003-04, 104 S. Ct. at 2873.
¶188 In light of this approach, one would expect the Court, in the case at hand, to look
to Montana law to determine whether the Ranchers’ licenses constitute “property.” But
that is not what the Court does. Rather, the Court allows the United States Court of
Appeals for the Federal Circuit to dictate whether a license granted by the State of
Montana is protected “property.” See Opinion, ¶ 46 (“As stated in [Members of Peanut
Quota Holders Ass’n v. United States, 421 F.3d 1323 (Fed. Cir. 2005)], to qualify as
compensable property interests, the Licenses must be transferable, exclusive, and free of
any ‘express statutory language precluding the formation of a property right . . . .’
Members, 421 F.3d at 1331. We address each of these requirements in turn, as they apply
to the Licenses before us.” (ellipsis in original)); Opinion, ¶ 54 (“Accordingly, because
the Licenses did not meet the three required criteria for compensability under Members,
we conclude the District Court did not err when i t held the Licenses were not
compensable property interests under the Fifth Amendment of the U.S. Constitution, or
Article II, Section 29 of the Montana Constitution.”). I do not dispute the validity of the
Federal Circuit’s test vis-à-vis federally created property interests. Indeed, all of the
cases from which the Federal Circuit synthesized its test involved licenses or permits
granted by the federal government. See Members, 421 F.3d at 1330-31. But why should
the Federal Circuit’s test define what constitutes a compensable property interest under
54
Montana law? The Court offers no explanation, and I can conceive of no valid reason—
particularly when Montana law does provide the answer.
¶189 As explained in Part II-A of this Dissent, the “existing rules or understandings”
related to the Ranchers’ licenses, prior to I-143, were as follows. First, as the State
acknowledged during oral argument, “it was the policy of the political branches of
government to encourage people to look at game farming as an alternative to traditional
agriculture -- actually, to subsidize traditional agriculture so they could stay on the farms
and ranches.” See § 87-4-431, MCA (1999) (“The legislature recognizes that the
production of alternative livestock provides a viable economic opportunity for any
private property owner as well as the traditional livestock producers who are interested in
diversifying their ranch productivity.”). The licenses were issued and annually renewed
in facilitation of this “viable economic opportunity.” Second, renewal of the licenses was
a matter of right, upon payment of the renewal fee and compliance with all recording and
reporting requirements. Section 87-4-412(1), MCA. Third, the license could not be
revoked except if the licensee had violated the law or otherwise engaged in misconduct
related to the operation of the alternative livestock ranch. Sections 87-4-423(1), -427(1),
MCA. Fourth, the license was transferable. Section 87-4-412(2), MCA.
¶190 Given these rules and understandings, it is clear that the Ranchers’ licenses had
several traditional hallmarks of property, including “the right to possess, use and dispose
of [them].” PruneYard Shopping Center v. Robins, 447 U.S. 74, 82 n. 6, 100 S. Ct. 2035,
2041 n. 6 (1980) (internal quotation marks omitted). The Ranchers could—and did—use
their licenses in the furtherance of their businesses. The Ranchers could sell, assign, or
55
otherwise transfer their licenses. The Ranchers had statutorily guaranteed security in the
continued possession of their licenses and, correspondingly, their ability to pursue this
“viable economic opportunity.” It seems patently obvious to me that in their alternative
livestock ranch licenses, the Ranchers had property rights which were protected by
Montana law and, as such, are deserving of protection under the Takings Clause.
Monsanto, 467 U.S. at 1003-04, 104 S. Ct. at 2873.
¶191 Additional “background principles” of Montana property law further support the
conclusion that the Ranchers’ licenses are “property” for Takings Clause purposes. See
Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 1030, 112 S. Ct. 2886, 2901
(1992). For one thing, the Montana Code contains a provision actually categorizing
“licenses” as “property.” See § 15-6-218(2)(a), MCA. Notably, of the other items of
“property” set forth in § 15-6-218(2)(a), MCA (certificates of stock, bonds, promissory
notes, copyrights, patents, trademarks, contracts, software, and franchises), several have
already been recognized as “property” within the meaning of the Takings Clause. See
Boyle v. United States, 200 F.3d 1369, 1374 (Fed. Cir. 2000) (copyrights); Roth v.
Pritikin, 710 F.2d 934, 939 (2d Cir. 1983) (same); Leesona Corp. v. United States, 599
F.2d 958, 964 (Ct. Cl. 1979) (patents); Cienega Gardens v. United States, 331 F.3d 1319,
1329 (Fed. Cir. 2003) (contracts); Lynch v. United States, 292 U.S. 571, 579, 54 S. Ct.
840, 843 (1934) (same); City of Oakland v. Oakland Raiders, 646 P.2d 835, 839-40 (Cal.
1982) (patents, franchises, and contracts).
¶192 Our decision in Seven Up Pete Venture v. State, 2005 MT 146, 327 Mont. 306,
114 P.3d 1009, is also informative here. We held in Seven Up Pete that the enactment of
56
I-137 did not constitute an unconstitutional taking since the Venture had not acquired an
operating permit to mine using cyanide prior to I-137’s enactment and since the State
retained substantial contractual and regulatory discretion regarding the issuance of such a
permit. See Seven Up Pete, ¶¶ 32-33. Of particular relevance, we reasoned:
[T]he passage of I-137 did not take away any existing permits or halt any
on-going mine operations related to the Venture’s projects. Because the
Venture had not obtained the requisite operating permit, it likewise had not
obtained a right to mine. Moreover, it was not assured of ever obtaining
such a right. Therefore, we conclude that the enactment of I-137 did not
constitute an unconstitutional taking.
Seven Up Pete, ¶ 33 (emphases added). It follows logically from this reasoning that
under Montana law, the issuance of a permit or license is a significant act upon which a
taking may be premised. Indeed, we dismissed the Venture’s takings claim because it did
not have an “existing” permit and because I-137 did not halt any “on-going” mine
operations. In contrast, the Ranchers did have “existing” licenses; annual renewal of the
licenses was a matter of right; and I-143 did halt “on-going” alternative livestock
ranching operations—all of which indicates that the Ranchers had compensable property
interests in their licenses.
¶193 To all of this, I would simply note that, contrary to the Court’s recitation of the
law in this area, courts have found government-issued licenses to be compensable
property interests. See e.g. Redevelopment Authority of Philadelphia v. Lieberman, 336
A.2d 249 (Pa. 1975); State v. Saugen, 169 N.W.2d 37 (Minn. 1969). Notably, in
Stallinger v. Goss, 121 Mont. 437, 193 P.2d 810 (1948), this Court observed: “Section
6672 of the Revised Codes of Montana 1935, defines personal property: ‘Every kind of
57
property that is not real is personal.’ A retail liquor license is saleable and is personal
property of value and subject to attachment.” Stallinger, 121 Mont. at 438, 193 P.2d at
810. It would be a peculiar proposition to hold that a government-issued license is
“personal property of value” for purposes of sale and attachment, but that it loses this
quality for purposes of governmental appropriation.
¶194 The Court concedes that the Ranchers’ licenses were transferrable. Opinion, ¶ 47.
The Court also concedes that neither Title 87, chapter 4, part 4, MCA, nor the licenses
themselves contained any express language precluding the formation of a compensable
property interest. Opinion, ¶ 48. Instead, the Court points out that a licensee was
required to comply with applicable laws and regulations and that the State retained the
power to amend the regulations or to revoke the license if the alternative livestock ranch
was being operated in violation of the law. Opinion, ¶¶ 49-50. The Court also points out
that at common law, wild animals were not subject to private ownership “ ‘except in so
far as the state may choose to make them so.’ ” Opinion, ¶ 50 (quoting Rosenfeld v.
Jakways, 67 Mont. 558, 562, 216 P. 776, 777 (1923)). These points, however, miss the
mark. Indeed, as the Court itself acknowledges in the very next breath, the government
does not have the right (absent just compensation) to withdraw benefits it has conveyed
or to qualify those benefits as i t chooses when “the statute itself or surrounding
circumstances” indicate that the conveyances were “intended to be irrevocable.”
Opinion, ¶ 50 (internal quotation marks omitted). Here, at the risk of belaboring the
point, the statutory scheme clearly provided that a license to “acquire, breed, grow, keep,
pursue, handle, harvest, use, sell, or dispose of the alternative livestock and their progeny
58
in any quantity and at any time of year” was intended to be irrevocable, except if the
licensee engaged in misconduct. Sections 87-4-412(1), -414(2), -423(1), -427(1), MCA
(1999). There is neither evidence nor argument in this case that the Ranchers engaged in
misconduct.
¶195 Lastly, the Court contends that the Ranchers did not have the right to exclude
others from entering the alternative livestock industry. Opinion, ¶¶ 51-53. On this basis,
the Court concludes that the Ranchers’ licenses “did not meet the three required criteria
for compensability under Members” and, thus, are not compensable property interests.
Opinion, ¶ 54. The Court never explains, however, why an inability to exclude others
from entering the industry is dispositive of the “property” question. The Ranchers do not
claim a property right in the alternative livestock industry, so why would they need to
exclude others from it? Rather, according to the Court, they claim a property right in
their licenses, and each Rancher obviously had title in his or her license to the exclusion
of all others. In any event, the Court is flat wrong in asserting that the right to exclude is
dispositive of the “property” question. “Precedent shows that the ability to exercise every
one of the ‘sticks’ (rights) in the ‘bundle’ of fee simple rights at the time of a taking is not
a prerequisite to establishing a valid property interest under the Fifth Amendment.”
Cienega Gardens v. United States, 331 F.3d 1319, 1329 (Fed. Cir. 2003).
¶196 In sum, I would hold that under the standards of Penn Central, I-143 took from the
Ranchers a traditional hallmark of property—the right to transfer their alternative
livestock ranch licenses and, correspondingly, their businesses—and that the Ranchers
are entitled to just compensation for this taking. Moreover, I disagree with the Court’s
59
contention that the licenses themselves are not property entitled to protection under the
Takings Clause.
2. The Intangible Business Assets
¶197 The Ranchers claim that I-143 took the goodwill and going-concern value of their
businesses. It is useful at the outset to define these terms.
¶198 “[A]n operating business can have a value in excess of the values of the separate
assets that compose the business.” Julius L. Sackman, Nichols on Eminent Domain
vol. 4, § 13.18[2], 13-169 (3d ed., Matthew Bender 2007). Indeed, in the same way that a
person is not just a collection of flesh, bones, and organs, a business is not just the sum of
its parts. A going business has value because of its vitality, because of its ability to
compete, and because of the synergy of its constituent parts which enable it efficiently to
manufacture a good, market a product, or provide a service. It cannot be gainsaid that the
value of a business assessed as a going concern is greater than the value of a business
which has been dismantled and sold for its constituent assets (to the extent the assets even
have value independent of the business). For instance, witness the difference in value of
a farm or ranch sold as a working operation and one whose assets are sold at auction.
¶199 This difference is known as “going-concern value,” which is “ ‘a term used to
explain that assets that are a part of a going concern have greater value than the sum of
the values of individual assets.’ ” Warnick v. Warnick, 133 P.3d 997, ¶ 15 n. 6 (Wyo.
2006) (quoting Donald J. Weidner & John W. Larson, The Revised Uniform Partnership
Act: The Reporters’ Overview, 49 Bus. Law. 1, 12 (1993)); see also Sackman, Nichols on
Eminent Domain § 13.18[2], 13-168 (“ ‘The term may be used to refer either to the total
60
value of a going concern or that portion of the total value that exceeds the value of the
other identifiable assets of the business.’ ” (quoting R. Miles, Basic Business Appraisal
19 (John Wiley & Sons 1984))). Going-concern value also represents “the many
advantages inherent in acquiring an operating business as compared to starting a new
business with only land, buildings and equipment in place,” Gray Line Bus Co. v. Greater
Bridgeport Transit Dist., 449 A.2d 1036, 1039 (Conn. 1982), such as the avoidance of
start-up costs and the ability to realize a higher rate of return than a newly established
firm due to greater efficiency in operations, marketing, and administration, see Lynda J.
Oswald, Goodwill and Going-Concern Value: Emerging Factors in the Just
Compensation Equation, 32 B.C. L. Rev. 283, 289 (1991).
¶200 In contrast, “goodwill” is “the expectation of continued public patronage.”
Section 30-13-121, MCA; Esselstyn v. Holmes, 42 Mont. 507, 516, 114 P. 118, 120
(1911). This expectation may be founded on reputation, regular customers, favorable
location, good service, high-quality merchandise, capable staff, good relations with
suppliers, and similar intangible concepts. See Baldwin v. Stuber, 182 Mont. 501,
506-07, 597 P.2d 1135, 1138 (1979); In re Marriage of Hull, 219 Mont. 480, 484, 712
P.2d 1317, 1320 (1986); BAA, PLC v. Acacia Mut. Life Ins. Co., 929 A.2d 1, 17 n. 24
(Md. 2007); Dugan v. Dugan, 457 A.2d 1, 4-5 (N.J. 1983); Sackman, Nichols on Eminent
Domain § 13.18[2], 13-167; 38 Am. Jur. 2d Good Will § 5 (1999). Thus, goodwill has
been defined as “the advantages a business has over competitors as a result of its name,
location and owner’s reputation.” Russell v. Jim Russell Supply, 558 N.E.2d 115, 121
(Ill. App. 5th Dist. 1990).
61
¶201 It is beyond dispute that goodwill and going-concern value are compensable
property interests; this fact is recognized under both federal and state law. See Huntleigh
USA Corp. v. United States, 525 F.3d 1370, 1382 n. 3 (Fed. Cir. 2008) (“[G]oing concern
value and goodwill are indeed compensable property interests.”); Kimball Laundry Co. v.
United States, 338 U.S. 1, 13, 69 S. Ct. 1434, 1441 (1949) (“[A]n exercise of the power
of eminent domain which has the inevitable effect of depriving the owner of the going-
concern value of his business is a compensable ‘taking’ of property.”); Los Angeles Gas
& Elec. Corp. v. Railroad Commission, 289 U.S. 287, 313, 53 S. Ct. 637, 647 (1933)
(“This Court has declared it to be self-evident that there is an element of value in an
assembled and established plant, doing business and earning money, over one not thus
advanced, and that this element of value is a property right which should be considered in
determining the value of the property, upon which the owner has a right to make a fair
return.” (internal quotation marks omitted)); §§ 70-1-101, -104(4), MCA (defining
“property” to include “such products of labor or skill as . . . the goodwill of a business”);
Esselstyn, 42 Mont. at 516, 114 P. at 120 (“The goodwill of a business . . . is property
capable of transfer, and the owner is entitled to the same protection in the exclusive
enjoyment of it as he is in that of his tangible possessions.” (citation omitted)).
¶202 The question, therefore, is whether I-143 effected a taking of the goodwill and
going-concern value of the Ranchers’ businesses. In my view, the answer to this question
is an obvious “Yes.” The District Court found—and I agree—that I-143 had “a
significant economic impact on [the Ranchers’] game farm businesses.” See also
Opinion, ¶ 62 (“[I-143] had a significant impact upon the value of their businesses.”).
62
Indeed, the Initiative effectively outlawed alternative livestock ranches. In this respect,
like the total abrogation of the right to transfer their licenses, the character of the
regulation vis-à-vis the Ranchers’ goodwill and going-concern value is “extraordinary.”
Hodel v. Irving, 481 U.S. 704, 716, 107 S. Ct. 2076, 2083 (1987). I-143 was designed to
shut down the Ranchers’ businesses; it accomplished that purpose; and, in so doing, it
fully devalued the goodwill and going-concern value of those businesses. As far as the
Ranchers’ goodwill and going-concern value are concerned, I-143 is “functionally
equivalent to the classic taking in which government directly appropriates private
property or ousts the owner from his domain.” Lingle v. Chevron U.S.A. Inc., 544 U.S.
528, 539, 125 S. Ct. 2074, 2082 (2005).
¶203 The Court points out repeatedly that the alternative livestock industry was “highly
regulated.” Notably, the Court does not disclose the legal standard by which an industry
may be judged “highly regulated” for purposes of takings analysis. More importantly, I
question whether this fact is entitled to the significance given it by the Court. Indeed,
the fact that the industry is regulated [is not] dispositive. A business that
operates in a heavily-regulated industry should reasonably expect certain
types of regulatory changes that may affect the value of its investments.
But that does not mean that all regulatory changes are reasonably
foreseeable or that regulated businesses can have no reasonable investment-
backed expectations whatsoever.
Cienega Gardens v. United States, 331 F.3d 1319, 1350 (Fed. Cir. 2003); see also Arctic
King Fisheries, Inc. v. United States, 59 Fed. Cl. 360, 379 (2004) (“[I]ndividuals
operating in highly regulated fields do not forfeit their rights under the Fifth Amendment
to the whim of whatever regulation the winds may bring.”). Here, the Ranchers’
63
investment-backed expectations certainly included the expectation that the regulatory
scheme would be adjusted over time, as had been the case over the preceding 75 years.
However, I-143 did not “adjust” the regulatory scheme; rather, it rendered the scheme’s
existence entirely pointless, since none of the businesses in the industry can survive after
I-143. I cannot agree with the Court’s fanciful suggestion that the Ranchers should have
expected the passage of such a regulation, i.e., one that would render all of the other
existing regulations moot. Cf. Cienega Gardens, 331 F.3d at 1350 (observing that “one
would not reasonably expect Congress to make legislative changes that would actually
discourage parties from participating in the programs in the future”).
¶204 In this connection, I-143 must be distinguished from typical regulations. The
Initiative did not directly address any of the concerns which led to its passage. I-143
prohibited fee shooting; yet, it cannot plausibly be maintained that the act of paying a fee
to shoot alternative livestock is itself the source of chronic wasting disease, the threat to
fair-chase hunting ethics, and the discontent over “European style” privatization of
wildlife. Rather, the prohibition on fee shooting was a means to an end—namely, to shut
down all alternative livestock ranches. Consequently, I-143 differs from regulations that
“adjust” the regulatory scheme in order to directly address a matter of public concern,
such as the new fencing requirements imposed on alternative livestock ranches over the
years and the moratorium placed on new applications for initial alternative livestock
ranch licenses until a test for chronic wasting disease is developed and approved. While
such regulations may incidentally impact the value of businesses in the industry, they are
not even remotely in the same league as I-143, which did not “regulate” alternative
64
livestock ranches in the usual sense, but instead deliberately wiped out the economic
viability of these businesses. A voter initiative prompted by dissatisfaction with
insurance companies and which permitted such companies to continue issuing policies
but prohibited them from charging premiums would achieve much the same result, as
would an initiative that permitted coal-fired generation plants to continue operating but
prohibited them from charging for the electricity they provided, or an initiative that
permitted oil companies to continue selling gasoline but prohibited them from charging
anything at the pump, or an initiative that permitted banks to continue loaning money but
prohibited them from charging interest, or an initiative that permitted grain farmers to
continue harvesting their crops but prohibited them from charging for their wheat.
Obviously, the list is endless.
¶205 This case, therefore, does not involve a new regulation that has made operation of
a business less profitable or has caused a slight diminution in a business’s value. It has
been said that “[g]overnment hardly could go on if to some extent values incident to
property could not be diminished without paying for every such change in the general
law.” Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon, 260 U.S. 393, 413, 43 S. Ct. 158, 159 (1922).
I-143, however, did not impose additional regulatory burdens on the business of
alternative livestock ranching. Rather, it deliberately and effectively legislated all such
businesses out of existence. As a result, the values incident to the Ranchers’ property
were not merely “diminished”; they were largely obliterated. Cf. Martin v. District of
Columbia, 205 U.S. 135, 139, 27 S. Ct. 440, 441 (1907) (“Constitutional rights like
others are matters of degree. To illustrate: Under the police power, in its strict sense, a
65
certain limit might be set to the height of buildings without compensation; but to make
that limit five feet would require compensation and a taking by eminent domain.”).
¶206 On one hand, the Court acknowledges that the changes in the regulatory scheme
brought about by I-143 were “radical.” Opinion, ¶ 6. I agree. On the other hand,
however, the Court suggests that the Ranchers should have reasonably anticipated such
changes given the “highly regulated” nature of the alternative livestock industry.
Opinion, ¶ 93. In so doing, the Court ignores several critical facts supporting the
Ranchers’ investment-backed expectations in that industry. For one, the Legislature told
the Ranchers that alternative livestock ranching was “a viable economic opportunity.”
Section 87-4-431, MCA (1999). The Ranchers were also assured that they would be
allowed to continue operating their alternative livestock businesses so long as they paid
the license renewal fees, complied with all recording and reporting requirements, and did
not engage in misconduct. Sections 87-4-412(1), -423(1), -427(1), MCA. Now, of
course, they are being told that they may continue operating, but that they must do so
without any income. The point here, however, is that the regulatory scheme itself
engendered reasonable investment-backed expectations. Those, combined with the
significant economic impact I-143 had on the Ranchers’ businesses and the extraordinary
character of the regulation, lead me to conclude that I-143 took the Ranchers’ goodwill
and going-concern value.
¶207 This conclusion is bolstered by precedents from other states, as well as a pre-Penn
Central decision of the Supreme Court. Under the business losses rule, when the
government condemns the real property upon which a business is operated, the owner
66
recovers only the value of the real property and the fixtures taken. There is no recovery
for loss of goodwill and going-concern value, loss of profits, and relocation or removal
expenses. See Lynda J. Oswald, Goodwill and Going-Concern Value: Emerging Factors
in the Just Compensation Equation, 32 B.C. L. Rev. 283, 286-87 (1991); see also e.g.
United States v. Petty Motor Co., 327 U.S. 372, 378-79, 66 S. Ct. 596, 599-600 (1946).
One of the justifications for this rule is that the business can still be carried on elsewhere,
the goodwill or going-concern value can be transferred with it to the new location without
loss of value, and nothing, therefore, has been taken. Oswald, 32 B.C. L. Rev. at 310.
Notably, the business losses rule has been subject to withering criticism and has been
rejected by a number of courts and legislatures. See Oswald, 32 B.C. L. Rev. at 319-75;
State v. Hammer, 550 P.2d 820, 823-26 (Alaska 1976); Bowers v. Fulton County, 146
S.E.2d 884, 889-91 (Ga. 1966); Michigan State Highway Commn. v. L & L Concession
Co., 187 N.W.2d 465, 468-69 (Mich. App. 1971); Luber v. Milwaukee County, 177
N.W.2d 380, 383-86 (Wis. 1970); City of Janesville v. CC Midwest, Inc., 734 N.W.2d
428, ¶ 80 (Wis. 2007) (Prosser, J., dissenting).
¶208 An exception to the business losses rule applies where the business was destroyed
or made otherwise unusable as a result of the governmental action. In Kimball Laundry
Co. v. United States, 338 U.S. 1, 69 S. Ct. 1434 (1949), for instance, the government took
temporary possession of a laundry, and the Laundry, having no other means of serving its
customers, suspended business for the duration of the government’s occupancy. Kimball
Laundry, 338 U.S. at 3, 69 S. Ct. at 1436-37. Thereafter, the Laundry claimed
entitlement to compensation for the loss of goodwill and going-concern value during the
67
occupancy. Kimball Laundry, 338 U.S. at 8, 69 S. Ct. at 1439. The Supreme Court
agreed. The Court first rejected the notion that the intangible nature of these assets
precluded recovery, observing that since the Fifth Amendment requires compensation for
the value of a business’s physical property, it also requires compensation for the value of
intangible assets. Kimball Laundry, 338 U.S. at 11, 69 S. Ct. at 1440. The Court then
discussed the rule that where an owner is free to move his business to a new location,
there is no compensation for going-concern value since this asset has not been “taken.”
Kimball Laundry, 338 U.S. at 11-12, 69 S. Ct. at 1440-41. Conversely, the Court
observed, this rule does not apply where the owner retains nothing of the going-concern
value that he formerly possessed. Kimball Laundry, 338 U.S. at 12-13, 69 S. Ct. at 1441.
Indeed, the Court stated that “an exercise of the power of eminent domain which has the
inevitable effect of depriving the owner of the going-concern value of his business is a
compensable ‘taking’ of property.” Kimball Laundry, 338 U.S. at 13, 69 S. Ct. at 1441.
Thus, for example, when the government condemns business property with the intention
of carrying on the business, “the going-concern value of the business is at the
Government’s disposal whether or not it chooses to avail itself of it. Since what the
owner had has transferable value, the situation is apt for the oft-quoted remark of Mr.
Justice Holmes, ‘the question is, What has the owner lost? not, What has the taker
gained?’ ” Kimball Laundry, 338 U.S. at 12, 13, 69 S. Ct. at 1441. The Court concluded
that the situation at hand came within this principle. See Kimball Laundry, 338 U.S. at
14, 69 S. Ct. at 1442.
68
¶209 The Minnesota Supreme Court reached a similar conclusion in State v. Saugen,
169 N.W.2d 37 (Minn. 1969). In that case, the government condemned property upon
which the condemnee had been operating a lounge. The condemnee had attempted to
transfer the going-concern value of the business to another location but could not do so
due to a restriction on the transfer of his liquor license. The issue on appeal, therefore,
was “whether the going-concern value of a liquor lounge, operating under a valid city
liquor license, is property taken, destroyed, or damaged by the state’s condemnation of
the premises for which compensation should be given.” Saugen, 169 N.W.2d at 39. The
court first held that neither the intangible character of going-concern value nor the fact
that the lounge was operated under the authority of a license precluded compensation for
a taking. Saugen, 169 N.W.2d at 39-42. The court then acknowledged “the general rule
that loss of going-concern value is not recoverable on condemnation.” Saugen, 169
N.W.2d at 42. However, the court held that this rule was inapplicable given that the
condemnee had been unable to relocate the business and, therefore, the going-concern
value had been effectively destroyed. See Saugen, 169 N.W.2d at 46; see also City of
Minneapolis v. Schutt, 256 N.W.2d 260, 265 (Minn. 1977) (stating that compensation for
the destruction of going-concern value is permitted where the business “either cannot be
relocated as a practical matter, or . . . relocation would result in irreparable harm to the
interest”).
¶210 In Detroit v. Michael’s Prescriptions, 373 N.W.2d 219 (Mich. App. 1985), the
court summarized the rule in Michigan as follows:
69
[R]ecovery of the going concern value of a business lost to condemnation
will depend on the transferability of that business to another location. If the
business can be transferred, nothing is taken and compensation is therefore
not required. . . . Generally, however, recovery will be allowed where the
business derives its success from a location not easily duplicated or where
relocation is foreclosed for reasons relating to the entire condemnation
project.
Michael’s Prescriptions, 373 N.W.2d at 224-25; see also L & L Concession, 187 N.W.2d
at 469.
¶211 Applying these principles here, the Ranchers’ businesses cannot be relocated as a
practical matter, since I-143 effectively “outlawed” alternative livestock ranches in this
State. Opinion, ¶ 92. Consequently, the goodwill and going-concern value of the
businesses cannot be transferred to a new location. To the contrary, the goodwill and
going-concern value have been destroyed by the passage of I-143. As a result, the
Ranchers have been completely deprived of these assets. A governmental action which
has “the inevitable effect of depriving the owner of the going-concern value of his
business is a compensable ‘taking’ of property.” Kimball Laundry, 338 U.S. at 13, 69
S. Ct. at 1441.
¶212 Before concluding, I again pause to address the Court’s approach. The Court
acknowledges at the outset that intangibles such as goodwill and going-concern value are
“property” under Montana law. Opinion, ¶ 55. The Court also acknowledges that
goodwill and going-concern value are compensable property interests under Kimball
Laundry. Opinion, ¶ 56. Yet, the Court adopts as “true” the District Court’s highly
questionable assertion that intangibles such as goodwill and going-concern value are
compensable only in eminent domain proceedings, and not in the regulatory takings
70
context. Opinion, ¶ 55. I am aware of no authority—and the Court cites none—standing
for the proposition that a property interest, for which the owner is entitled to
compensation in a direct condemnation action, is not also compensable in a regulatory
takings action. I must also confess that the rationale for such a distinction escapes me,
particularly given the lack of any textual support for it in the Takings Clause, which
simply states: “nor shall private property be taken for public use, without just
compensation.” U.S. Const. amend. V.
¶213 Next, the Court attempts to avoid the rule of Kimball Laundry by limiting that case
to “those rare circumstances where the government actually intends to take over the
claimant’s business and thereby appropriate the goodwill and going-concern value for its
own use.” Opinion, ¶ 56. Nothing in Kimball Laundry supports this narrow reading of
the opinion. To the contrary, the Supreme Court stated:
[A]n exercise of the power of eminent domain which has the inevitable
effect of depriving the owner of the going-concern value of his business is a
compensable “taking” of property. If such a deprivation has occurred, the
going-concern value of the business is at the Government’s disposal
whether or not it chooses to avail itself of it.
Kimball Laundry, 338 U.S. at 13, 69 S. Ct. at 1441 (emphasis added, citations omitted).
¶214 The critical fact in Kimball Laundry was not the government’s “intent” (Opinion,
¶ 56) or “actual physical occupation” of the laundry (Opinion, ¶ 57). Rather, it was the
inability of the Laundry to transfer its going-concern value to another location. Kimball
Laundry, 338 U.S. at 14-16, 69 S. Ct. at 1442-43. Moreover, the Court should take note
that “ ‘the Constitution measures a taking of property not by what a State says, or by what
it intends, but by what it does.’ ” San Diego Gas & Elec. Co. v. San Diego, 450 U.S.
71
621, 652-53, 101 S. Ct. 1287, 1304 (1981) (Brennan, Stewart, Marshall, & Powell, JJ.,
dissenting) (quoting Hughes v. Washington, 389 U.S. 290, 298, 88 S. Ct. 438, 443 (1967)
(Stewart, J., concurring) (emphasis in Hughes), and citing Davis v. Newton Coal Co., 267
U.S. 292, 301, 45 S. Ct. 305, 306 (1925)). Notably, in attempting to limit Kimball
Laundry, the Court places the focus of the analysis on what the State gained. This
approach is contrary to the rule that our focus must be on what the property owner lost.
Kimball Laundry, 338 U.S. at 13, 69 S. Ct. at 1441 (“ ‘[T]he question is, What has the
owner lost? not, What has the taker gained?’ ”); see also United States v. Causby, 328
U.S. 256, 261, 66 S. Ct. 1062, 1065-66 (1946). From the Ranchers’ perspective, there is
no difference between the State’s taking over their businesses, thereby appropriating the
goodwill and going-concern value for its own use, and the State’s shutting down the
businesses through a regulatory enactment so that no one can operate them at all. The
Court’s attempt to distinguish the two is pure sophistry.
¶215 Lastly, the Court posits that “taking of goodwill or going-concern value differs
markedly from other types of taking.” Opinion, ¶ 57. The Court speculates that “[t]his is
likely because what the claimant alleges has been ‘taken’ is an expectation of future
profitability.” Opinion, ¶ 57. Proceeding on this assumption, the Court cites and
discusses a number of cases for the proposition that an expectation of future profitability
is not a compensable property interest. Opinion, ¶¶ 57-62. At the conclusion of these
citations, the Court baldly rewrites the Ranchers’ claim that I-143 took their “intangible
business assets” as a claim that I-143 took their “ability to profit from fee-shooting.”
Opinion, ¶ 63. Having thus transformed the Ranchers’ claim, the Court reaches the
72
conclusion that the Ranchers’ “ability to profit from fee-shooting” is not compensable
“because there has been no physical condemnation or occupation of [the Ranchers’]
property by the State.” Opinion, ¶ 63.
¶216 This conclusion is truly perplexing. For one thing, the Court expends several
pages arguing that an expectation of future profitability is not a compensable property
interest, only to reach the conclusion that an ability to profit is compensable if the State
physically condemns or occupies the business. Moreover, I am not persuaded that an
“ability to profit from fee-shooting” is compensable if the State “physically condemns or
occupies” the Ranchers’ property but is not compensable if the State simply passes a
regulation putting the Ranchers out of business. That the Court treats these two scenarios
as constitutionally distinct, without a shred of authority for support, is troubling.
¶217 Ultimately, however, the distinction is irrelevant because the Ranchers do not
claim a taking of their “ability to profit from fee-shooting.” What they claim, rather, is
that I-143 took the goodwill and going-concern value of their businesses. These are
existing, quantifiable, and compensable property interests, recognized as such in the cases
cited above. Where the government deprives an owner of the goodwill and going-
concern value of his business, it is a compensable taking of property. Kimball Laundry,
338 U.S. at 13, 69 S. Ct. at 1441. In my view, that proposition is sufficient to resolve the
Ranchers’ claims with respect to their intangible business assets.
¶218 In sum, I would hold that I-143 took the goodwill and going-concern value of the
Ranchers’ businesses and that the Ranchers are entitled to just compensation for this
taking. Moreover, I disagree with the Court’s entire discussion at ¶¶ 55-64. In order to
73
reject the Ranchers’ legitimate takings claims, the Court manufactures a novel new rule:
Although a business owner may be deprived of the goodwill and going-concern value of
his business by either regulation or direct appropriation, he is entitled to compensation
only in the latter circumstance. There is no logical reason, no persuasive justification,
and no legal authority offered in support of this incongruous rule. What the Court fails to
recognize is that the ultimate question in a Fifth Amendment regulatory takings analysis
is whether the regulation is “so onerous that its effect is tantamount to a direct
appropriation or ouster.” Lingle v. Chevron U.S.A. Inc., 544 U.S. 528, 537, 125 S. Ct.
2074, 2081 (2005). Certainly, if a regulation is so onerous that its effect is tantamount to
a direct appropriation of goodwill or going-concern value—and I-143 is such a
regulation—then just compensation is required.
3. The Real Estate Interests and Fixtures
¶219 Given the prolonged discussions under the two preceding categories, only a brief
discussion is necessary here. First, I tend to agree with the Court’s conclusion that I-143
did not take the Ranchers’ real estate. Opinion, ¶ 80. However, there is a glaring
omission from the Court’s discussion: an analysis of the fixtures. The Court’s heading
reads, “Appellants’ Real Estate Interests and Fixtures,” and the Court mentions fixtures
several times in ¶¶ 80-83. Yet, nowhere is there a discrete analysis of the fixtures.
Rather, the Court seems to lump them together with the land. This, in my view, is error.
The Ranchers installed a number of fixtures on their property specifically designed for
the purpose of operating alternative livestock ranches, including fences and certain
outbuildings. To the extent I-143 has rendered these fixtures valueless, I conclude that
74
the Ranchers are entitled to just compensation for essentially the same reasons I
concluded above that they are entitled to just compensation for the loss of their right to
transfer their alternative livestock ranch licenses and businesses and for the loss of their
intangible business assets.
4. The Alternative Livestock
¶220 The last category is the Ranchers’ alternative livestock. Everyone agrees that the
alternative livestock is a compensable property interest. See Opinion, ¶ 66. Thus, the
question is whether this property was “taken” under the Penn Central standards.
¶221 The Court observes that the Ranchers’ alternative livestock suffered “significant
devaluation” as a result of I-143 and that the diminished value was insufficient even to
cover the cost of raising and maintaining the livestock. Opinion, ¶¶ 84, 85. As a matter
of fact, the Ranchers can sell their alternative livestock only at a loss. Opinion, ¶ 85. The
Court concludes, therefore, that the economic-impact factor “weighs in favor of finding a
compensable taking” of the alternative livestock. Opinion, ¶ 85. I generally agree with
these observations; however, given that I-143 devalued the alternative livestock by 70 to
95 percent, Opinion, ¶ 84, and given that the primary focus of our analysis is on “the
severity of the burden that [I-143] imposes upon private property rights,” Lingle, 544
U.S. at 539, 125 S. Ct. at 2082, I conclude that the economic-impact factor weighs very
heavily in favor of the Ranchers’ claims.
¶222 The Court next addresses the character of the governmental action. Opinion,
¶¶ 86-88. The Court acknowledges that I-143 placed the economic burden of eliminating
alternative livestock ranches “squarely on the shoulders” of the individuals in the industry
75
and that “individuals like [the Ranchers], and not the public as a whole, are being asked
to bear the burden.” Opinion, ¶ 86. This, the Court recognizes, “seems to run afoul” of
the rule that the State may not “ ‘forc[e] some people alone to bear public burdens which,
in all fairness and justice, should be borne by the public as a whole.’ ” Opinion, ¶ 86
(quoting Armstrong v. United States, 364 U.S. 40, 49, 80 S. Ct. 1563, 1569 (1960)). On
all of these points, I agree.
¶223 I do not agree, however, with the Court’s subsequent attempt to downplay I-143’s
intrusion on the Ranchers’ property rights as “slight” and “minimal.” Opinion, ¶¶ 87, 88.
The Court points out that the State has not seized the Ranchers’ alternative livestock.
True, but the alternative livestock no longer have any economically viable use, as the
Court itself acknowledges in ¶ 85 (noting that the value of the livestock is “insufficient to
even cover the cost of raising and maintaining [them]” and that the Ranchers “could only
sell the alternative livestock at a loss”). That is tantamount to seizing the alternative
livestock. Cf. Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003, 1017, 112 S. Ct.
2886, 2894 (1992) (“[T]otal deprivation of beneficial use is, from the landowner’s point
of view, the equivalent of a physical appropriation.”). The Court also contends that I-143
merely prohibited one use of the Ranchers’ alternative livestock and left them open to
exploit other uses of the livestock. For instance, the Court proposes that the Ranchers
could sell the alternative livestock (admittedly, at a loss) to out-of-state markets or “allow
others to shoot [the alternative livestock] in Montana, so long as no fee is charged.”
Opinion, ¶ 87. However, these entirely unprofitable (not to mention implausible) uses of
76
the alternative livestock only persuade me further that I-143’s impact is far from “slight”
and “minimal.”
¶224 The Court’s attempt to analogize this case to Andrus v. Allard, 444 U.S. 51, 100
S. Ct. 318 (1979), is similarly unpersuasive. Andrus involved federal regulations
promulgated pursuant to the Eagle Protection Act and the Migratory Bird Treaty Act.
The regulations prohibited commercial transactions in parts of birds that had been legally
killed before the birds came under the protection of the Acts. The appellees were
engaged in the trade of Indian artifacts composed partly of the feathers of protected birds,
and these artifacts existed before the regulations went into effect. One of the issues on
appeal, therefore, was whether “the Eagle Protection and Migratory Bird Treaty Acts
violate appellees’ Fifth Amendment property rights because the prohibition [on
commercial transactions in preexisting avian artifacts] wholly deprives them of the
opportunity to earn a profit from those relics.” See Andrus, 444 U.S. at 52-55, 64, 100
S. Ct. at 320-21, 326.
¶225 In answering this question, the Supreme Court observed that the challenged
regulations neither compelled the surrender of, nor imposed a physical restraint on, the
artifacts; rather, they imposed a restriction on one means of disposing of the artifacts.
Andrus, 444 U.S. at 65, 100 S. Ct. at 327. The Court acknowledged that the regulations
prevented “the most profitable use” of the appellees’ property; at the same time, however,
it was “not clear that appellees will be unable to derive economic benefit from the
artifacts.” Andrus, 444 U.S. at 66, 100 S. Ct. at 327. The Court ultimately concluded
that in the absence of any physical property restriction, the reduction in profits—i.e., the
77
difference between the most profitable use of the property pre-regulation and the most
profitable use of the property post-regulation—was too speculative and, thus, “a slender
reed upon which to rest a takings claim.” Andrus, 444 U.S. at 66, 100 S. Ct. at 327.
Hence, the Court held that the prohibition on the sale of the bird feathers did not amount
to a taking. Andrus, 444 U.S. at 67-68, 100 S. Ct. at 328.
¶226 As an initial matter, the extent to which the holding of Andrus may be extended
beyond the specific facts of that case is questionable. See Hodel v. Irving, 481 U.S. 704,
719, 107 S. Ct. 2076, 2085 (1987) (Scalia, J., Rehnquist, C.J., & Powell, J., concurring)
(concluding that “in finding a taking today our decision effectively limits Allard to its
facts”); but see Irving, 481 U.S. at 718, 107 S. Ct. at 2084 (Brennan, Marshall, &
Blackmun, JJ., concurring) (“I find nothing in today’s opinion that would limit Andrus v.
Allard, 444 U.S. 51, 100 S.Ct. 318 (1979), to its facts.”). But, setting that question aside,
the character of the governmental action in Andrus is, in any event, totally distinguishable
from the character of the governmental action here.
¶227 The regulations at issue in Andrus were designed to prevent the destruction of
certain species of birds, which in turn caused an incidental reduction in profits for those
engaged in the trade of Indian artifacts. But the appellees still had the opportunity to use
their property in other economically viable ways. Andrus, 444 U.S. at 66, 100 S. Ct. at
327. I-143, by contrast, was not designed to regulate the use, care, or disposal of
alternative livestock. Rather, it was designed to regulate the price of penned hunts so as
to eliminate the alternative livestock’s value completely. It is important, in this regard, to
recall that the Sportsmen’s concerns in drafting I-143 were with chronic wasting disease
78
(“CWD”), unethical hunting, and private ownership of game animals. Obviously, all of
these concerns could be resolved in one fell swoop by simply seizing the alternative
livestock and prohibiting private ownership of game animals, but such action clearly
would require the payment of compensation. Alternatively, the Sportsmen’s goals could
be achieved if the Ranchers were left with no choice but to get rid of their alternative
livestock, but that would not likely occur if the Ranchers were able to derive economic
benefit from them. Thus, the Sportsmen “carefully crafted” I-143 to eliminate all
economically beneficial use of the alternative livestock.
¶228 Ironically, in so doing, and in spite of their concern with diseases, the Sportsmen
gave the Ranchers an incentive to neglect their alternative livestock and allow them to
become diseased. That way, the government would destroy the animals and pay the
Ranchers for the loss. Compare 9 C.F.R. § 55.2 (“The Administrator is authorized to pay
for the purchase and destruction of CWD positive animals, CWD exposed animals, and
CWD suspect animals. Subject to available funding, the amount of the Federal payment
for any such animals will be 95 percent of the appraised value established in accordance
with § 55.3 of this part, but the Federal payment shall not exceed $3,000 per animal.”),
with Opinion, ¶ 84 (observing that the Ranchers were getting between $500 and $1,800
per animal selling them on the market). I-143 and this Court’s decision, therefore, create
the perverse result that good stewards of animals whose healthy herds are devalued by
way of a “carefully crafted” political ploy receive nothing, while those whose herds have
become diseased due to careless management receive compensation. One has to wonder
where there is “fairness and justice” in such a scheme.
79
¶229 In any event, given that I-143 specifically targets the Ranchers to bear the entire
burden of eliminating alternative livestock ranches, and given that I-143, for all intents
and purposes, caused “the complete elimination of [the alternative livestock’s] value,”
Lingle, 544 U.S. at 539, 125 S. Ct. at 2082 (citing Lucas, 505 U.S. at 1017, 112 S. Ct. at
2894); cf. Yancey v. United States, 915 F.2d 1534, 1541-42 (Fed. Cir. 1990) (finding a
compensable taking where “the Yanceys had no choice but to sell their birds for
substantially less than their value”), I conclude that the character of the governmental
action weighs heavily in favor of the conclusion that I-143 effected a taking of the
Ranchers’ alternative livestock.
¶230 Lastly, the Court addresses the Ranchers’ investment-backed expectations.
Opinion, ¶¶ 89-93. The Court acknowledges that the whole reason the Ranchers
expended “significant financial resources” on their respective operations was to offer
penned hunts. Opinion, ¶ 89. Yet, the Court then asserts that it was unreasonable for the
Ranchers “to maintain an investment-backed expectation that they would always be able
to charge a fee to shoot alternative livestock in Montana.” Opinion, ¶ 89. The Court
points out that “the State never assured [the Ranchers] they would always be permitted to
charge a fee to shoot alternative livestock in Montana.” Opinion, ¶ 92.
¶231 With all due respect, the foregoing proposition is preposterous. The right to
receive remuneration, in one form or another, for one’s lawful goods and services has
always been a part of this country’s economic system. It is one thing to regulate the
prices at which goods and services may be sold, but it is quite another to impose a price
ceiling of $0.00. No business would, or should, ever expect that the State may require it
80
to offer its goods and services for free. Cf. Stone v. Farmers’ Loan & Trust Co.
(Railroad Commission Cases), 116 U.S. 307, 331, 6 S. Ct. 334, 345 (1886) (“This power
to regulate is not a power to destroy, and limitation is not the equivalent of confiscation.
Under pretense of regulating fares and freights, the state cannot require a railroad
corporation to carry persons or property without reward; neither can it do that which in
law amounts to a taking of private property for public use without just compensation, or
without due process of law.”).
¶232 The Court offers a second theory that is only slightly more plausible than the first.
Specifically, the Court asserts that due to “significant public unrest,” the Ranchers
“knew, or should have known,” that alternative livestock ranches were “highly
controversial” and that initiative measures could be passed which would outlaw such
operations entirely. Opinion, ¶ 92. The Court thus reasons that the Ranchers “could not
maintain a reasonable investment-backed expectation” that the industry would not
someday be “completely abolished.” Opinion, ¶ 93.
¶233 There are several flaws—factual as well as legal—with this theory. First, the
history of alternative livestock ranching does not support the expectations the Court
attributes to the Ranchers. The “public unrest” that led to I-143 was not new. As a
matter of fact, the 1982 Game Farm Task Force was created specifically to address then-
existing public concerns and controversy surrounding alternative livestock ranching. See
Part II-A, supra. But that controversy did not lead to the out-and-out elimination of the
industry. To the contrary, it resulted in a compromise involving, on one hand, the
imposition of new requirements on alternative livestock ranch operations and, on the
81
other hand, the codification of certain “rights” designed to protect the interests of
participants in the alternative livestock industry. Thus, if the Ranchers should have
expected a change due to the “public unrest” existing in the 1990s, additional safety and
testing requirements are far more plausible than a regulation designed to put them out of
business by prohibiting remuneration for penned hunts. Indeed, the Court acknowledges
that the changes in the regulatory scheme brought about by I-143 were “radical.”
Opinion, ¶ 6.
¶234 Second, and along these same lines, it is important to recall that nothing in the
“public unrest” prior to I-143 had anything to do with the size of the fees the Ranchers
were charging for penned hunts or the fact that fees were being charged. Therefore, even
if the Ranchers should have anticipated some adjustments to the regulatory scheme, a
prohibition on charging a fee to shoot alternative livestock cannot fairly be categorized as
one such adjustment—especially since penned hunts are still perfectly legal, as long as
they are conducted for free.
¶235 Third, notwithstanding the “public unrest” to which the Court refers, the 1999
Legislature passed a statute which read: “The legislature recognizes that the production
of alternative livestock provides a viable economic opportunity for any private property
owner as well as the traditional livestock producers who are interested in diversifying
their ranch productivity.” Section 87-4-431, MCA. It is quite far-fetched to assert, as the
Court does, that the Ranchers should have anticipated the State was on the verge of
abolishing alternative livestock ranching when the Legislature, meanwhile, was passing a
statute characterizing the activity as “a viable economic opportunity.” Given that
82
alternative livestock ranching had been a lawful “business or occupation” in this State for
over 75 years, and given that an alternative livestock ranch license was renewable as a
matter of right and could not be revoked unless the licensee engaged in misconduct,
§§ 87-4-412(1), -423(1), -427(1), MCA, it was far more reasonable for the Ranchers to
maintain investment-backed expectations that their ability to continue operating their
alternative livestock ranches was secure.
¶236 Lastly, at a more fundamental level, I question the Court’s reliance on what the
Ranchers “knew, or should have known.” The Court opines that a regulation does not
take property if it was “reasonably anticipated.” Opinion, ¶ 93. But if the notion of a
“regulatory taking” is to have any vitality, then the Court’s theory must be roundly
rejected. It is unlikely in today’s world, where regulations of property are prevalent, that
any property owner could ever argue that a particular regulation was unexpected or not
reasonably anticipated. “[E]xcept for a regulation of almost unimaginable abruptness, all
regulation will build on prior regulation and hence be said to defeat any expectations.
Thus regulation begets regulation.” District Intown Properties v. District of Columbia,
198 F.3d 874, 887 (D.C. Cir. 1999) (Williams, J., concurring in the judgment). If the
meaning of “taking” may be qualified by the degree to which a regulation is “reasonably
anticipated,” then “the natural tendency of human nature is to extend the qualification
more and more until at last private property disappears.” Pennsylvania Coal Co. v.
Mahon, 260 U.S. 393, 415, 43 S. Ct. 158, 160 (1922).
¶237 That is exactly the untenable result under the Court’s approach: A business that
operates in an industry with a history of regulation must expect that the regulations may
83
be strengthened to achieve public needs, and this expectation, in turn, negates any
entitlement the business might otherwise have to compensation for a taking. Indeed, this
expectation, according to the Court, outweighs even a “significant devaluation” of
property disproportionately placed on the business. Such an approach drains the doctrine
of “regulatory takings” of all force and purpose. There is no basis in logic or in the
Takings Clause for distinguishing between two equally burdened property owners on the
ground that one of them had advance notice of the regulation while the other was caught
completely off guard. Either private property rights were taken, or they were not. If the
former, just compensation must be paid, irrespective of the amount of notice the property
owner had of the regulation’s enactment.
¶238 In my view, the Ranchers’ had reasonable investment-backed expectations related
to their alternative livestock, given the long history of alternative livestock ranching, the
statutory provisions designed to protect the interests of participants in the industry, and
the Legislature’s pronouncement that this activity was “a viable economic opportunity.”
I conclude that this factor weighs in favor of the Ranchers’ claims.
¶239 Having analyzed the three Penn Central factors, I would hold that the Ranchers
are entitled to just compensation for the “substantial devaluation” of their alternative
livestock. While we may disagree as to the reasonableness of the Ranchers’ investment-
backed expectations in light of the “significant public unrest,” I believe that the three
factors, taken together, mandate the conclusion that I-143 effected a taking of the
Ranchers’ alternative livestock. Both the economic impact of I-143 on the value of the
84
alternative livestock and the character of the regulation weigh heavily in favor of this
conclusion.
5. Conclusion of Fifth Amendment Analysis
¶240 In conclusion, based on the foregoing Penn Central analysis, I would hold that
I-143 effected a taking of the Ranchers’ right to transfer their alternative livestock ranch
licenses and businesses, of the goodwill and going-concern value of their businesses, of
the fixtures related to their alternative livestock operations, and of their alternative
livestock. I would further hold that the Ranchers are entitled to just compensation for
these takings. I would reverse the District Court’s judgment and remand for further
proceedings related to the issue of just compensation.
IV. CONCLUSION
¶241 You take my house, when you do take the prop
That doth sustain my house; you take my life,
When you do take the means whereby I live.6
¶242 Arguably, I-143 was a fraud on the voters. It purported to address a number of
“problems” associated with alternative livestock ranching, but it did not actually address
any of those problems—at least, not directly. Instead, it eliminated the means whereby
the Ranchers businesses existed, thereby destroying those businesses. The voters were
not told that the Initiative was a “carefully crafted” end-around the Constitution that
could lead to a decision from this Court holding that the State may destroy the goodwill
and going-concern value of a Montana business, substantially (if not completely) devalue
6
William Shakespeare, The Merchant of Venice, Act IV, Scene 1, lines 375-77.
85
the business’s assets, and deprive the business owner of her right to sell, assign, or
otherwise transfer the business—all without having to pay just compensation.
¶243 The Court invokes notions of “fairness and justice” to deny the Ranchers any
compensation for the out-and-out obliteration of their businesses. I-143 was designed to
shut down an industry that the State had facilitated, and even encouraged, for 83 years
and to place the entire economic burden of doing so on the participants in that industry.
It is difficult to see any fairness or justice in this bait and switch, particularly since the
Initiative was promoted as addressing legitimate public concerns shared not only by the
Sportsmen, but by the public as a whole. A majority of voters—specifically, 204,282 of
them—believed that the concerns cited by I-143’s Proponents warranted “game farm
reform.” Given the severity of the burden this “reform” entailed, and given that the
“reform” was intended to benefit all of Montana, fairness and justice require that the
burden be spread among taxpayers through the payment of compensation, not
disproportionately placed on the shoulders of the alternative livestock ranchers.
¶244 The economic impact on the Ranchers’ various assets as a result of I-143 is
unquestionably substantial. The character of the governmental action—total abrogation
of property rights in and related to the Ranchers’ businesses—is extraordinary. And the
Ranchers’ distinct investment-backed expectations in their ability to continue operating
their businesses were quite reasonable in light of the history of alternative livestock
ranching and the various assurances set out in the statutory scheme. “[W]hile property
may be regulated to a certain extent, if regulation goes too far it will be recognized as a
86
taking.” Mahon, 260 U.S. at 415, 43 S. Ct. at 160. In light of the foregoing, I-143 went
too far, and just compensation is due.
¶245 Aside from the immediate impact of the Court’s decision on the Ranchers, the
Opinion will, obviously, serve as precedent in future Montana takings cases. This
Dissent is long—and will, no doubt, be criticized by some for that. However, I believe
that the important issues implicated by the Ranchers’ takings claims justified setting out,
in detail, the reasons why federal takings jurisprudence is confused, often inconsistent,
certainly not bulletproof, and not necessarily worthy of this Court’s “marching lockstep”
with it. I hope this Dissent will give some future takings litigant the impetus and
ammunition to challenge federal caselaw in arguing that her facially broader fundamental
rights under Article II, Section 29 should be upheld.
¶246 Additionally, I am very concerned that the Court’s decision here will be used—
and, more likely, misused—in government’s ever-expanding reach to regulate—and,
ultimately, take—Montanans’ broadly-defined property rights, without having to assume
and spread amongst all taxpayers the economic burdens of that regulation and taking.
Similarly, I am concerned that today’s decision will encourage more “carefully crafted”
initiatives and legislation which end-run constitutional guarantees and mislead voters
with smoke and mirrors. Finally, I am concerned that, recognizing “If they can do it to
them, they can do it to me,” citizens will propose and enact initiatives of the recent I-154
ilk—poorly drafted, overbroad, and underinclusive. Indeed, we invite the Legislature to
enact laws to protect constitutional rights when this Court refuses to define and enforce
those rights.
87
¶247 It is for all of these reasons I would hold that the Ranchers have established
compensable property interests and have demonstrated that those property interests were
“taken” under the Fifth Amendment. I would reverse the District Court’s judgment and
remand this case for further proceedings on the issue of just compensation.
¶248 Therefore, I respectfully dissent from the Court’s contrary decision.
/S/ JAMES C. NELSON
Justice Jim Rice and District Court Judge Wm. Nels Swandal, sitting for Justice Brian
Morris, join the Dissent of Justice James C. Nelson.
/S/ JIM RICE
/S/WM. NELS SWANDAL
88