Consumers Union of the United States, Inc. v. Sawhill

TAMM, Chief Judge:

This case was previously before a division of the court, which held, with one member dissenting, that the Federal Energy Administration’s (FEA) “new oil” regulation, allowing that oil to be sold without regard to the ceiling price, was invalid under the Emergency Petroleum Allocation Act (the Act). The division also held that FEA’s “released oil” regulation, allowing that oil to be sold at a price determined by a formula, was valid under the Act because “[njothing in the language of § 4(a) suggests that prices cannot be prescribed or determined in part with reference to or in relation to market price.” Consumers Union of United States, Inc. v. Sawhill, 512 F.2d 1112, at 1118 (Em.App.1975). We granted rehearing en bane because of the exceptional importance of the case in relation to FEA’s regulatory scheme and, having thoroughly considered the arguments proffered by the parties, are constrained to vacate the judgment of the division majority for the reasons set forth in the concurring and dissenting opinion, attached hereto as an appendix, which we adopt together with the modification herein.

Although the background and regulatory framework are adequately described in the attached appendix, there remains one point that was only recently brought to the attention of the court, which requires further explication. Effective August 29, 1974, FEA amended its released oil regulation to provide that released oil, like new oil, be sold without regard to the ceiling price. 39 Fed.Reg. 31622-24 (Aug. 30, 1974). Since the released oil formula as discussed in the opinions of the division is no longer applicable, the amended released oil regulation must stand or fall with the new oil regulation. Our reasoning upholding it is twofold. First, both parties agree that the amended released oil regulation does not effectuate a change in the substance of its predecessor. See id. at 31622 — 23; Appellant’s Supp.Mem. on Rehearing at 3-A. Thus, by amending the released oil regulation, FEA has only clarified an aspect of the two-tier system “expressly contemplated” by Congress when it passed the Act. App. at 4, 9-10. Second, the most recent statistics indicate that new and released oil account for approximately 22 percent of domestic crude production. Thus, as stated in the division dissenting opinion, “FEA’s utilization of free market price for a maximum of [22] percent of all crude production (excluding stripper wells) is a statutorily permissible means of accomplishing the necessary balancing of objectives.” App. at 14. Of course, this is not to say that FEA may, consistent with its statutory responsibilities, unilaterally implement changes in its regulatory scheme not contemplated by Congress and not reflective of a balancing approach.

*1072Unfortunately, Judge Anderson, with all due respect, apparently misperceives several fundamental aspects of our opinion. After thorough study of the opinion, he arrives at the conclusion that we “construe ‘the grant of such broad regulatory discretion’ to empower the FEA to free any category of crude oil from all regulation without complying with the required exemption procedure.” Judge Anderson’s Dissent at 1083 — 1084. To allay any subsequent misunderstanding, we categorically state that this characterization of our holding today is simply incorrect; our decision concerns new and released oil — old oil is unquestionably quite another matter. The dissent further suggests that we somehow heavily rely upon the goal of section 4(b)(1)(I) as “a justification for finding such a grant of the unlimited power as the majority would accord to FEA.” Id. at 1084. This too is incorrect — we recognize that section 4(b)(1)(I) is but one of nine equally important goals and, certainly would not even attempt our dissenting colleague’s leap of faith to elevate any one of those goals to the level of a mandatory duty as the dissent does with the goal of equitable prices. Id. at 1082 (“mandatory duty to establish equitable prices”), 1088 (“statutory prescription ” and “equitable price requirement ”). Notably, the dissent again makes no mention of the import-export oil problem. App. at 1085 — 1086. Finally, we are pleased that the dissent recognizes that (1) FPC v. Texaco “differed critically from the present case,” Dissent at 1086 and (2) the present regulatory scheme provides “a strong incentive to drill wells which were not active during the base period,” id. at 1087, thus illustrating FEA’s effective balancing approach to the overall problem.

The judgment of the division is vacated and the district court is affirmed for the reasons stated in the division concurring and dissenting opinion and herein.

So ordered.

APPENDIX

TAMM, Chief Judge (concurring and dissenting):

While I agree with that portion of the majority opinion which upholds FEA’s “released” oil regulation, 10 C.F.R. § 212.74(b), I would also uphold the “new” oil regulation, 10 C.F.R. § 212.-74(a).

I

I begin with an analysis of the relevant portions of the Act, their legislative history and the regulations promulgated thereunder. In response to widespread shortages of petroleum and petroleum products, Congress enacted the Emergency Petroleum Allocation Act, with its avowed purpose “to grant to the President of the United States and direct him to exercise specific temporary authority to deal with shortages of crude oil, residual fuel oil, and refined petroleum products or dislocations in their national distribution system.” 15 U.S.C. § 751(b) (Supp. III, 1973). Hence, section 4(a) of the Act, 15 U.S.C. § 753(a), requires the President to “promulgate a regulation providing for the mandatory allocation of crude oil, residual fuel oil, and each refined petroleum product, in amounts and at prices specified in (or determined in a manner prescribed by) such regulation.” While unequivocally directing pervasive regulation, the Conference Report opined that “the clear and firm understanding on the part of the Managers of both Houses [is] that the mandatory allocation program shall not be designed or implemented in a manner which would have the net effect of occasioning a substantial reduction in the total supply of crude oil, residual fuel oil or refined petroleum products. It is expected that the President in applying the mandatory controls will assiduously avoid that result.” 1

*1073Regardless of their specific terms, Congress also directed that, “to the maximum extent practicable,” the regulations so promulgated provide for the following objectives:

(A) protection of public health, safety, and welfare (including maintenance of residential heating, such as individual homes, apartments, and similar occupied dwelling units), and the national defense;
(B) maintenance of all public services (including facilities and services provided by municipally, cooperatively, or investor owned utilities or by any State or local government or authority, and including transportation facilities and services which serve the public at large);
(C) maintenance of agricultural operations, including farming, ranching, dairy, and fishing activities, and services directly related thereto;
(D) preservation of an economically sound and competitive petroleum industry; including the priority needs to restore and foster competition in the producing, refining, distribution, marketing, and petrochemical sectors of such industry, and to preserve the competitive viability of independent refiners, small refiners, nonbranded independent marketers, and branded independent marketers;
(E) the allocation of suitable types, grades, and quality of crude oil to refineries in the United States to permit such refineries to operate at full capacity;
(F) equitable distribution of crude oil, residual fuel oil, and refined petroleum products at equitable prices among all regions and areas of the United States and sectors of the petroleum industry, including independent refiners, small refiners, nonbranded independent markets, branded independent marketers, and among all users;
(G) allocation of residual fuel oil and refined petroleum products in such amounts and in such manner as may be necessary for the maintenance of exploration for, and production or extraction of, fuels, and for required transportation related thereto;
(H) economic efficiency; and
(I) minimization of economic distortion, inflexibility, and unnecessary interference with market mechanisms.

15 U.S.C. § 753(b)(1) (Supp. III, 1973). The qualifying language, “to the maximum extent practicable,” was “intended to give the President administrative flexibility in marshalling short supplies and equitably assigning them to particular needs.”2 A cursory reading of the objectives clearly indicates frequently competing interests; thus, “to the maximum extent practicable” also foreshadowed the necessity for a “balancing” approach to achieve maximization of the legislative goals.3

Regarding price controls, the Conference Report emphasized

that the pricing controls called for in this legislation may, in those circumstances where pricing controls established pursuant to other federal authority are consistent with the requirements and objectives of this Act, merely confirm those controls in the regulation to be promulgated under authority of section 4 of this Act. It is expressly contemplated, for example, that the price controls established by Phase IV under authority of the Economic Stabilization Act would continue in effect unless and until required to be modified by the price regulation required to carry out the purposes of this Act. As a matter of administrative convenience, the President may wish to continue to exercise federal pricing controls through the Cost of Living Council and may, pursuant to section 5(b), assign to that agency responsibility for administering *1074the price controls called for in this Act.

H.R.Rep.No.93—628 at 26, U.S.Code Cong. & Admin.News 1973, p. 2702. Furthermore, the Report stated that the Act’s reference to equitable prices (15 U.S.C. § 753(b)(1)(F))

is specifically intended to emphasize that one of the objectives of the mandatory allocation program is to prevent price gouging or price discrimination which might otherwise occur on the basis of current shortages. On the other hand, it is contemplated that prices for allocated fuels will be set at levels or pursuant to methods which will permit adequate compensation to assure that private property is not implicitly confiscated by the government. Most importantly, the President must, in exercising this authority, strike an equitable balance between the sometimes conflicting needs of providing adequate inducement for the production of an adequate supply of product and of holding down spiraling consumer costs.

Id.

Accoutered with this legislative ordnance the President established the Federal Energy Office (FEO) and delegated to it his authority under section 203(a)(3) of the Economic Stabilization Act of 1970,4 the Emergency Petroleum Allocation Act, supra, and the Defense Production Act of 19505 as it relates to production, conservation, use, control, distribution and allocation of energy. Exec. Order No. 11, 748, 3 C.F.R. 376 (1974).-Centralization of petroleum allocation and pricing was completed when the Cost of Living Council (CLC) delegated its crude oil and petroleum products price stabilization authority under the Economic Stabilization Act to FEO. CLC Order No. 47, 39 Fed.Reg. 24 (Jan. 2, 1974). Shortly thereafter, FEO issued its Petroleum Allocation and Price Regulations, 39 Fed.Reg. 1924-61 (1974), effective January 15, 1974, which constitute the gravamen of this case. Pendente lite, FEA, created by the Federal Energy Administration Act of 1974, Pub.L. No.93 — 275 (May 7, 1974), assumed the functions of the now defunct FEO. See Exec.Order No. 11, 790, 39 Fed.Reg. 23185 (June 27, 1974).

The regulations at issue adopted, essentially unchanged, the so-called “two-tier” price system originally implemented by CLC as part of its Economic Stabilization Program.6 As both parties agree, “old” oil — oil from properties producing at, or less than, their 1972 production level — is subject to the “ceiling price rule,”7 and accounts for approximately 60 percent of domestic crude production.8 Although accounting for approximately 13 percent of domestic crude production, stripper wells, those producing less than ten barrels per day, are specifically exempt from allocation and price controls. 15 U.S.C. § 753(e)(2). FEA’s regulation of the remaining oil, “new” and “released,” which account for 16 and 11 percent respectively of domestic crude production,9 is at the heart of this dispute.

*1075The price of both new and released crude oil is determined pursuant to the “special release rule.”10 Thus, new crude oil, equal to the amount of domestic crude produced and sold from a property in a specific month above the amount produced and sold from that property during a base month in 1972, may be *1076sold without regard to the ceiling price, i. e., at the market price.11 If a particular property did not produce at all in 1972, the base year, then all of its current production is new oil and accordingly, may be sold at the market price.

For released oil the special release rule presents a more complicated situation. Where a property is now producing in excess of its 1972 production level, that oil produced up to the 1972 level is released oil; of course, the excess is new oil.12 The maximum allowable price for released oil is the lesser of the current market price or the price derived pursuant to a formula established by the special release rule.13 The formula engenders a price for released oil that is a function of the base period production level, the May 15, 1973 posted price, the current market price, and the amount by which current production exceeds base period production.14 The result is that when a producer’s revenues from a sale of new and released oil from a particular property are averaged, the weighted average price may be well below the current market price.15 Most importantly, *1077FEA’s analysis of the formula at work vividly illustrates its inherent production , incentive.16

II

Against this background, I now proceed to analyze the issues raised and argued by the parties. Both parties, the District Court Judge and the majority agree that the Emergency Petroleum Allocation Act imposes upon FEA a mandatory duty to “regulate” the price of new and released crude oil. I also agree, and hence, the ultimate question to be resolved is whether the challenged regulation adequately implements this Congressional mandate. Consumers Union’s argument is twofold. First, it argues that FEA’s use of “free market price” in its regulatory scheme for new and released oil violates the mandate of section 4(a) to specify or prescribe a manner for determining price of all crude oil and thus creates a prohibited non-statutory exemption to the Act. Consumers Union’s Br. at 9-10. Second, Consumers Union maintains that FEA, by permitting new and released crude oil to be sold at the free market price, violates its mandatory duty to establish “equitable” prices for such oil. Consumers Union’s Br. at 13 — 25. These contentions are addressed seriatim.

Section 4(a) of the Act provides that “the President shall promulgate a regulation providing for the mandatory allocation of crude oil, ... at prices specified in (or determined in a manner prescribed by) such regulation” and that “[ejxcept as provided in subsection (e) [the stripper well exception] such regulation shall apply to all crude oil, produced in or imported into the United States.” (Emphasis added.) I read this language as obviously condoning a regulation which prescribes a manner for determining prices of all crude oil. Quite literally, FEA has done so. However, Consumers Union asserts, and the majority agrees, that FEA’s regulation, which utilizes free market price, does not prescribe a manner for determining all crude oil prices within the meaning of the Act and thereby creates a prohibited non-statutory exemption to it. I cannot agree.

It is appropriate at this juncture to digress momentarily to elaborate on the breadth of FEA’s regulatory discretion under the Act. A starting point is the proposition that “the width of administrative authority must be measured in part by the purposes for which it was conferred.” Permian Basin Area Rate Cases, 390 U.S. 747, 776, 88 S.Ct. 1344, 20 L.Ed.2d 312 (1968). Nowhere could this oft-repeated rubric be more relevant than where Congress acts in a crisis situation. The Emergency Petroleum Allocation Act is Congress’ response to precisely such a situation. The regulations mandated by section 4(a) are to provide, for, to the maximum extent practicable, the broad objectives of section 4(b)(1), supra part I. One would be at great pains to characterize this legislation as pervasively filling every interstice, leaving only mandatory duties to the administrative body charged with its implementation. To the contrary, I think the Congressional intent was to hew a sphere of responsibility within which FEA could decide how to proceed against the crisis. The grant of such broad regulatory discretion is inconsist*1078ent with Consumers Union’s and the majority’s view of FEA’s statutory responsibilities.

Aside from the breadth of FEA’s regulatory authority, it is abundantly clear that Congress specifically contemplated the use of free market prices in the regulatory scheme. The Conference Report emphasized that “[i]t is expressly contemplated, for example, that the price controls established by Phase IV under authority of the Economic Stabilization Act would continue in effect unless and until required to be modified by the price regulation required to carry out the purposes of this Act.” 17 As mentioned in part I, the Phase IV price controls were originally promulgated by CLC and adopted, essentially unchanged, by FEO, FEA’s predecessor. Those Phase IV controls utilized free market price to precisely the same extent as the regulation challenged here. I think the above-quoted language establishes, beyond peradventure, Congressional recognition and approval of FEA’s utilization of the “two-tier” system. Consumers Union, contrariwise, asserts that this language, “far from simply authorizing a continuation of [CLC] regulations explicitly recognized that certain [CLC price controls] would be inconsistent with the mandatory pricing controls required by the new Allocation Act.”18 This position is belied by the clear import of the clause “unless and until required to be modified by the price regulation,” which manifestly refers to a determination made when and if the implementing agency discerns a necessity for such action. If Consumers Union’s assertion were correct, Congress, at the least, would have mentioned such a major “inconsistency” as utilization of free market prices in the regulatory scheme.

Having found that Congress legislated broad regulatory discretion to implement the Act and specifically contemplated free market price a permissible ingredient of the regulatory scheme, I must reject Consumers Union’s argument and the majority’s holding that FEA’s utilization of free market price does not meet the legislative mandate to prescribe a manner for determining prices within the meaning of the Act. A fortiori, Consumers Union’s argument that utilization of free market price creates a non-statutory exemption to the Act must also fall because the price of all crude oil is in fact regulated within the meaning of the Act.

The majority opinion on this issue is particularly disturbing. The majority reasons that “[n]ew crude oil . would sell at the market price even in the absence of such administrative regulation [10 C.F.R. § 212.74(a)]” and thus, “because Congress will not be presumed to have done a useless, ineffective, or absurd thing, see e. g., Pennsylvania v. Nelson, 350 U.S. 497, 509—510, 76 S.Ct. 477, 100 L.Ed. 640 (1956), the presumption arises that § 4(a) cannot be satisfied by an administrative scheme which necessarily results in the same price which would prevail in its absence.” 512 F.2d at 1118. Several aspects of this reasoning merit further analysis. First, the admittedly true fact that new crude oil would sell at the market price in the absence of regulation overlooks the even more basic fact that in the absence of regulation there simply would be no such thing as “new” oil, or, for that matter, “old” or “released” oil, all of which are administrative creations. The point is that these categories of oil, each with a price determined by different regulations, represents precisely the balancing of competing objectives contemplated by Congress. Second, the majority states that “Congress will not be presumed to have done a useless, ineffective, or absurd thing . . . .” Aside from the implicit notion here that the new oil regulation is “useless, ineffective, or absurd,”' which I find without basis when viewed in context of the en*1079tire administrative scheme, this case is not one which calls for presumptions. The majority need not presume what Congress intended when the legislative history clearly resolves statutory ambiguities. See supra, part I. If presumptions are the order of the day, the majority should also note this court’s recognition of “a strong presumption in favor of administrative decisions by those agencies charged with immediate administration of a new federal statute.” Reeves v. Simon, 507 F.2d 455 (Em.App. 1974).19 Finally, the majority’s presumption that “an administrative scheme which necessarily results in the same price which would prevail in its absence,” which leads to its conclusion that utilization of market price here will not do, raises an interesting dilemma. When Consumers Union initiated this action it also challenged FEA’s regulations regarding the price of exported and imported oil. 10 C.F.R. §§ 212.53(a) and 212.53(b). Those regulations, also upheld by the district court, utilize free market price to the same extent as FEA’s new oil regulation. Although Consumers Union has not challenged the district court’s ruling regarding the export-import oil regulations, Consumers Union’s Br. at 5 n. 1, the clear import of the majority’s opinion today is that those regulations too must fall. It will be interesting to observe exactly how FEA will either indirectly or through price ceilings regulate, with the “precept” of equitable prices in mind, imported oil from the international cartel of OPEC nations. However, perhaps the majority has provided for this contingency in its statement that “Congress will not be presumed to have done a useless, ineffective or absurd thing tf

I turn now to Consumers Union’s second argument, that FEA, by permitting new and released crude oil to be sold at the free market price, violated its mandatory duty to establish “equitable” prices. In this regard, it appears that the majority has adopted Consumers Union’s woeful misconstruction of the statutory language. Equitable prices are mentioned in section 4(b)(1)(F) as one of nine separate objectives which Congress directed the regulation promulgated under section 4(a) should provide for to the maximum extent practicable. The Conference Report specifically states that the objectives “are collective goals, and the conferees have not attempted to discern an order of precedence or value one against another. It is fully recognized that, in some instances, it may be impossible to satisfy one objective without sacrificing the accomplishment of another.” H.R.Rep.No.93—628 at 11-12, U.S.Code Cong. & Admin.News 1973, p. 2688 (emphasis added). I am convinced that the objectives necessitate a balancing approach by FEA to effectuate maximum achievement of their competing interests. See Union Oil Co. v. FEA, Civil No. 74r-1943 — MML (C.D.Cal., July 25, 1974), FEA’s Br. at App. C; Trans World Airlines, Inc. v. FEO, 380 F.Supp. 560 (D.D.C.1974), FEA’s Br. at App. D. Moreover, FEA’s utilization of free market price for a maximum of 27 percent of all crude petroleum production (excluding stripper wells) is, to me, a statutorily permissible means of accomplishing the necessary balancing of objectives. The majority’s elevation of one of the nine Congressional objectives to the level of a “precept” is absolutely without support in the Act or its legislative history-

Finally, Consumers Union places substantial weight on the Supreme *1080Court’s recent decision in FPC v. Texaco, 417 U.S. 380, 94 S.Ct. 2315, 41 L.Ed.2d 141 (1974). Having examined that case in detail, I must agree with FEA that Consumers Union’s reliance thereon is misplaced. Texaco concerned a Commission order which, utilizing a “two-tier” ratemaking system, exempted natural gas sales by small producers from direct rate regulation. However, the Commission asserted that those rates would in fact be regulated indirectly by its regulation of rates of pipelines and large producers, customers of the small producers. The Court held that, while the two-tier system was not per se unlawful, id. at 386-93, 94 S.Ct. 2315, the order in question was so ambiguous that the Court could not say that FPC proposed to rely on only “free market price,” which the Court had condemned, or “other factors,” which the Court, while not specifically condoning such factors, stated that the case would be “far different” had the Commission verbalized in its order its appellate counsel’s post hoc rationalizations. Id. at 393-97, 94 S.Ct. 2315. Finally, the Court stressed its view that “the prevailing price in the market place cannot be the final measure of ‘just and reasonable’ rates mandated by the [Natural Gas] Act.” Id. at 397, 94 S.Ct. at 2326.

Consumers Union has proceeded to draw “closely analogous” parallels between Texaco and the instant case. To the extent the majority adopts this analysis, I think it has overly simplified the situation in that it erroneously ignores fundamental differences between the purpose and operative terms of the Natural Gas Act, 15 U.S.C. § 717 et seq., and the Emergency Petroleum Allocation Act, supra.

To begin with, mere juxtaposition of the two acts elicits strikingly obvious differences in the “rate-making” authority conferred upon the respective implementing agencies. The Gas Act’s rate-making sections encompass such items as rates and charges, cost of production or transportation, costs of property, accounting systems, and rates of depreciation. 15 U.S.C. §§ 717c, 717d, 717e, 717g and 717h (1970), respectively. Contrast this ubiquitous and detailed rate-making authority with the “price regulation” mandated by the Allocation Act as previously discussed. The Gas Act, pervasively regulates all facets of natural gas company rates while the Allocation Act requires price regulation “to prevent price gouging or price discrimination which might otherwise occur on the basis of the current shortages.” H.R.Rep.No. 93-628 at 26, U.S.Code Cong. & Admin. News 1973, p. 2702. In short, the upshot of the Gas Act is to create a permanently regulated industry; whereas, the upshot of the Allocation Act is to establish temporary regulation of some aspects of an industry, most particularly distribution.

One remaining aspect of the Texaco decision merits discussion. Consumers Union and the majority seem to read the equitable price objective of the Allocation Act as synonymous with the Gas Act’s mandate that natural gas rates be “just and reasonable,” 15 U.S.C. § 717c(a), concluding that Texaco would prohibit FEA’s regulations’ partial acquiescence in a free market price. I think that Texaco is simply inapposite on this point. As previously discussed, “equitable price” as used in the Allocation Act is merely one of many objectives that FEA is to provide for to the maximum extent practicable. “Just and reasonable” as used in the Gas Act is mandatory; rather than being one objective among many, it is the objective. The majority, to my mind, does not give proper weight to these fundamental distinctions.

On the basis of the aforementioned reasons, I would affirm the ruling of the district court in its entirety.

. Conference Report, H.R.Rep.No.93-628, 93d Cong., 1st Sess. 14, U.S.Code Cong. & Admin. News 1973, p. 2691 (1973) (emphasis added) [hereinafter H.R.Rep.No.93-628].

. H.R.Rep.No.93-628 at 12, U.S.Code Cong. & Admin.News 1973, p. 2689.

. See, e. g., H.R.Rep.No.93-628 at 11-12.

. 12 U.S.C. § 1904 (note) (1970), as amended, (Supp. III, 1973).

. 50 U.S.C.App. § 2601 et seq. (1970), as amended, (Supp. III, 1973).

. Compare 6 C.F.R. §§ 150.353, 150.354 (1974) with 10 C.F.R. §§ 212.73, 212.74, 39 Fed.Reg. 1952 (1974).

. 10 C.F.R. § 212.73, 39 Fed.Reg. 1952 (1974), ceiling price rule reads:

(a) Rule. Except as provided in section 212.74, no producer may charge a price higher than the ceiling price for the first sale of domestic crude petroleum.
(b) Ceiling price determination. The ceiling price for a particular grade of domestic crude petroleum in a particular field is the sum of (1) the highest posted price at 6 a. m., local time, May 15, 1973, for that grade of crude petroleum at that field, or if there are no posted prices in that field, the related price for that grade of domestic crude petroleum which is most similar in kind and quality at the nearest field for which prices are posted; and (2) a maximum of $1.35 per barrel.

. App. at 239.

. Id.

. 10 C.F.R. § 212.74, 39 Fed.Reg. 1952 (1974), special release rule reads:

(a) Notwithstanding the provisions of § 212.73(a), a producer of new crude petroleum produced and sold from a property may in the month produced, beginning with the month of September 1973, or in any subsequent month, sell that new crude petroleum without respect to the ceiling price. However, if the amount of crude petroleum produced and sold in any month subsequent to the first month in which new crude petroleum was produced and sold, is less than the base production control level for that property for that month, any new crude petroleum produced from that property during any subsequent month may not be sold pursuant to this paragraph until an amount of the new crude petroleum equal to the difference between the amount of crude petroleum actually produced from that produced from that property during the earlier month and the base production control level for that property for the earlier month has been sold at or below its ceiling price.

(b) Released crude. Notwithstanding paragraph (a) of this section, if during a particular month new crude petroleum which could be sold at other than the ceiling price pursuant to paragraph (a) of this section is produced from a property, the entire base production control level crude petroleum for that month may be sold at a price which exceeds the ceiling price: Provided, That the maximum price charged per barrel of that base production control level crude petroleum does not exceed the lesser of (1) the current free market price for the particular quality or grade of crude petroleum or (2) the price derived pursuant to the following:

P max= Maximum price that may be charged for the crude petroleum (other than new crude) purchased from the property (dollars per barrel);

P = Ceiling price of the crude petroleum (dollars per barrel);

C = Base production control level for property (barrels); bpcl

C = Total amount of crude petroleum produced from the property pr during the month (barrels); and

P = Current free market price of the particular quality and grade m of crude petroleum (dollars per barrel).

Application of this formula may be illustrated by the following example:

Example. During September 1973, Firm X produces 8,170 barrels of a single grade of crude, petroleum from a particular property. During September 1972, 6,420 barrels of crude petroleum were produced from the same property. The ceiling price for the September 1973 crude petroleum is $4.10 per barrel, and its free market price (i. e., the price X can get on the market for the 1,750 barrels of new crude) is $4.95 per barrel. The maximum price that X may charge for the 6,420 barrels of other than new crude petroleum (i. e., old plus released crude) produced in September 1973 is:

P = $4.10 + (8,170/6, 420 - 1) ($4.95 - $4.10) max

P = $4.10+ (.27) ($0.85) max

P = $4.10+ $0.23 max

P = $4.33/barrel. max

*1076(c) Certification. Each producer of domestic crude petroleum which charges a price above the ceiling price pursuant to the provisions of tnis section must, with respect to each sale of domestic crude petroleum, certify in writing to the purchaser: (1) the ceiling price of domestic crude petroleum, (2) the amount of the new crude petroleum and (3) the amount of the base production control level crude petroleum. The certification shall also contain a statement that the price charged for the domestic crude petroleum is no greater than permitted pursuant to this subpart.

“Base production control level,” “property,” and “new crude petroleum” are defined by 10 C.F.R. § 212.72, 39 Fed.Reg. 1952 (1974) as follows:

“Base production control level” for a particular month for a particular property means:

(1) if crude petroleum was produced and sold from that property in every month of 1972, the total number of barrels of domestic crude petroleum produced and sold from that property in the same month of 1972;

(2) if domestic crude petroleum was not produced and sold from that property in every month of 1972, the total number of barrels of domestic crude petroleum produced and sold from that property in 1972 divided by 12.

“Property” is the right which arises from a lease or from a fee interest to produce domestic crude petroleum.

“New crude petroleum” means the total number of barrels of domestic crude petroleum produced and sold from a property in a specific month less the base production control level for that property.

. 10 C.F.R. § 212.74(a), 39 Fed.Reg. 1952, supra, note 10. Note especially the “however” clause of this section, providing for sale at or below ceiling price of certain crude in situations where the amount of crude oil produced and sold in any month subsequent to the first month in which new crude oil was produced and sold is less than the base production control level for that property for that month.

. 10 C.F.R. § 212.74(b), 39 Fed.Reg. 1952, supra, note 10.

. Id. There is disagreement between the parties as to whether the formula in fact permits released oil to be sold at market price. Compare App. 108-12 with App. 219-20. While there is some support for Consumers Union’s analysis of the pricing effect of the regulation, deference must be accorded to FEA’s expertise in interpreting its own regulation. Power Reactor Co. v. Electricians, 367 U.S. 396, 408, 81 S.Ct. 1529, 6 L.Ed.2d 920 (1961); Pacific Coast Meat Jobbers Ass’n, Inc. v. Cost of Living Council, 481 F.2d 1388, 1392 (Em.App.1973) and cases cited therein. This is especially sound judicial policy where, as here, Consumers Union does not contend that FEA enforces the regulation contrary to its interpretation. Absent such representations, I presume that FEA in fact enforces the regulation as it has represented to this court.

. FEA’s Br. at 11; App. at 109.

. App. at 108-12. Even under Consumers Union’s released oil formula calculations, App. at 219-20, the weighted average price per barrel of new, released and old oil is substantially less than the given market price.

*1077The majority dismisses the average weighted price per barrel as “merely a mathematical construct with no moderating effect on the price of new crude oil . .” 512 F.2d at 1120. The majority reaches this conclusion even in view of FEA’s unquestioned representation that “[n]ew crude oil normally constitutes only a portion of the total output of each oil-producing property so that the average of the prices charged by each producer for all his oil is lower than it would be in the absence of the regulations at issue . . . At 1119. Thus, FEA has quite properly infused its regulations with the realities of the petroleum industry and, indeed, while the average weighted price per barrel is a mathematical construct, it nevertheless plainly reflects the effect of FEA’s regulations on the price of all crude oil.

. App. at 111. Consumers Union has not disputed this effect.

. H.R.Rep.No.93—628 at 26, U.S.Code Cong. & Admin.News 1973, p. 2702 (emphasis added). See supra, part I text.

. Consumers Union’s Reply Br. at 8-9 (emphasis in original).

. Citing University of Southern California v. Cost of Living Council, 472 F.2d 1065, 1068-69 (Em.App.1972); Pacific Coast Meat Jobbers Ass’n v. Cost of Living Council, 481 F.2d 1388, 1391-92 (Em.App. 1973); Mandel v. Simon, 493 F.2d 1239, 1240 (Em.App. 1974). The division in Reeves, quoting Mandel, at 1240, stated: “The Federal Energy Office must have great flexibility during the formative period of regulation. Judicial interference at this time may delay rather than advance effective regulation of this area.” Moreover, the deference due agency interpretation of a statute it is charged with administering is by no means unique to this court. See, e. g., Udall v. Tallman, 380 U.S. 1, 16, 85 S.Ct. 792, 13 L.Ed.2d 616 (1965); Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc. v. Train, 510 F.2d 692 (D.C.Cir.1974).