dissenting.
The constitutional issue in this case, if not very vital in its present application, surely is a debatable one. Two state courts of last resort, the only ones to consider similar legislation, have held it unconstitutional.1 Only unreviewed decisions of intermediate courts2 can be cited in support of the Court’s holding.
*426Appellant employed one Grotemeyer', under a union contract, on an hourly basis at $1.60 per hour for each hour worked. He demanded a four-hour leave of absence, with full pay, on election day to do campaigning and to get out the vote. It is stipulated that his residence was 200 feet from the polling place and that it actually took him about five minutes to vote. Appellant closed the day’s work for all employees one and one-half hours earlier than usual, which gave them the statutory four hours before the polls closed.. For failure to pay something less than $3 for this hour and a half which Grotemeyer did not work and for which his contract did not provide that he should be paid, the employer is convicted of crime under the statute set forth in the Court’s opinion.
To sustain this statute by resort to the analogy of minimum wage laws seems so farfetched and unconvincing as to demonstrate its weakness rather than its strength. Because a State may require payment of a minimum wage for hoürs that are worked it does not follow that it may compel payment for time that is not worked. To overlook a distinction so fundamental is to confuse the point in issue.
The Court, by speaking of the statute as though it applies only to industry, sinister and big, further obscures the real .principle involved. The statute plainly requires farmers, small service enterprises, professional offices, housewives with domestic help, and all other employers, not only to allow their employees time to vote, but to pay them for time to do so. It does not, however, require the employee to use any part of such time for that purpose. Such legislation stands in a class by itself and should not be uncritically commended as a mere regulation of “practices in the business-labor, field.”
Obtaining a full and free expression from all qualified voters at the polls is so fundamental to a successful representative government that a State rightly concerns it*427self with the removal of every obstruction to the right and opportunity to vote freely. Courts should go far to sustain legislation designed to relieve employees from obligations to private employers which would stand in the way of their duty as citizens.
But there must be some limit to the power to shift the whole voting burden from the voter to someone else who happens to stand in some economic relationship to him. Getting out the vote is not the business of employers; indeed, I have regarded it as a political abuse when employers concerned themselves with their employees’ voting. It is either the voter’s own business or the State’s business. I do not question that the incentive which this statute offers will help swell the'vote; to require that .employees be paid time-and-a-half would swell it still more, and double-time would do even better. But does the success of an enticement to vote justify putting its cost on some other citizen?
The discriminatory character of this statute is flagrant. It is obvious that not everybody will be paid for voting and the “rational basis” on which the State has ordered that some be paid while others are not eludes me. If there is a need for a subsidy to get out the vote, no reason is ápparent to me why it should go to one who lives 200 feet from his polling place but not to a self-employed farmer who may have to lay down his work and let his equipment idle for several hours while he travels several miles over bad fall roads to do his duty as a citizen. If he has a hired man, he must also lose his hand’s time and his pay. Perhaps some plan will be forthcoming to pay the farmer by requiring his iñortgagee to rebate some proportion of the interest on the farm mortgage if he will vote; It would not differ in principle. But no way occurs to me by which the doctor can charge some patient of. the lawyer some client for the call he could not receive while he was voting.
*428I suppose a State itself has considerable latitude to offer inducements to voters who do not value their franchise enough to vote on their own time, even if they seem to me corrupting or discriminating ones. Perhaps my difficulty with today’s decision is that I cannot rise above an old-fashioned valuation of American citizenship which makes a state-imposed pay-for-voting system appear to be a confession of failure of popular representative government.
It undoubtedly is the right of every union negotiating with an employer to bargain for voting time without loss of pay. It is equally the right of any individual employee to make that part of his hire. I have no reason to doubt that a large number of voters already have voluntary arrangements which make their absence for voting without cost. But a constitutional philosophy which sanctions intervention by the State to fix terms of pay without work may be available tomorrow to give constitutional sanction to state-imposed terms of employment less benevolent.
Illinois Central R. Co. v. Commonwealth, 305 Ky. 632, 204 S. W. 2d 973; People v. Chicago, M. & St. P. R. Co., 306 Ill. 486, 138 N. E. 155. Cf. Zelney v. Murphy, 387 Ill. 492, 56 N. E. 2d 754.
People v. Ford Motor Co., 271 App. Div. 141, 63 N. Y. S. 2d 697; Ballarini v. Schlage Lock Co., 100 Cal. App. 2d 859, 226 P. 2d 771.