Coastal Fuels of Puerto Rico, Inc. v. Caribbean Petroleum Corp.

                  UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
                      FOR THE FIRST CIRCUIT
                                           

No. 95-1460

               COASTAL FUELS OF PUERTO RICO, INC.,

                      Plaintiff - Appellee,

                                v.

                 CARIBBEAN PETROLEUM CORPORATION,

                      Defendant - Appellant.

                                           

           APPEAL FROM THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT

                 FOR THE DISTRICT OF PUERTO RICO

        [Hon. Juan M. P rez-Gim nez, U.S. District Judge]
                                                                  

                                           

                              Before

                     Torruella, Chief Judge,
                                                     

                      Watson,* Senior Judge,
                                                     

                    and Lynch, Circuit Judge.
                                                      

                                           

     William L.  Patton, with  whom Thomas B.  Smith, Kenneth  A.
                                                                           
Galton, Ropes  & Gray, Rub n  T. Nigaglioni and Ledesma,  Palou &
                                                                           
Miranda were on brief for appellant.
                 
     Michael S. Yauch, with whom  Neil O. Bowman, Roberto  Boneta
                                                                           
and Mu oz  Boneta Gonz lez Arbona  Ben tez & Peral were  on brief
                                                            
for appellee.

                                           

                          March 12, 1996
                                           
                    
                              

*  Of the United States Court of International Trade.


          TORRUELLA, Chief Judge.  This appeal involves claims of
                    TORRUELLA, Chief Judge.
                                          

price discrimination, 15 U.S.C.   13(a) (1994); 10 L.P.R.A.   263

(1976), monopolization, 15  U.S.C.   2 (1994); 10  L.P.R.A.   260

(1976),  and Puerto  Rico law  tort, 31  L.P.R.A.    5141 (1976),

brought  against appellant Caribbean  Petroleum Corp. by appellee

Coastal  Fuels of  Puerto Rico,  Inc.   After  a jury  trial, the

district court entered judgment for $5,000,000 -- $1.5 million in

antitrust damages trebled plus $500,000  in tort damages.  CAPECO

seeks that  the judgment  of the district  court be  reversed and

judgment be  granted to CAPECO  on all counts,  or alternatively,

that the  judgment be reversed  and the case  remanded for  a new

trial.   We affirm the  price discrimination and Puerto  Rico law

tort verdicts, as  well as the tort damage verdict.   However, we

reverse  the monopolization verdict, vacate the antitrust damages

verdict,  and accordingly remand for further proceedings on price

discrimination damages.

                            BACKGROUND
                                      BACKGROUND
                                                

          We  relate the evidentiary background in the light most

favorable  to the  jury verdicts.   See  Kerr-Selgas v.  American
                                                                           

Airlines, Inc., 69 F.3d 1205, 1206 (1st Cir. 1995).
                        

          Coastal  Fuels  of Puerto  Rico,  Inc. ("Coastal")  was

formed in  1989  as a  wholly-owned subsidiary  of Coastal  Fuels

Marketing,   Inc.  ("CFMI"),  a  company  that  ran  marine  fuel

operations in  numerous ports  using a staff  of sales  agents in

Miami,  Florida.  Caribbean  Petroleum Corp. ("CAPECO")  owns and

operates a  refinery in  Bayam n, Puerto  Rico, which  produces a

                               -2-
                                         -2-


number of fuel products, as  well as residual fuel.   A principal

use of residual fuel is in the production of "bunker fuel," which

is  used by cruise ships  and other ocean-going vessels outfitted

with internal combustion or steam engines.

          At trial,  Coastal  introduced  testimony  and  letters

showing that CAPECO  had committed to supply Coastal  on the same

terms and conditions as other resellers in San Juan, Puerto Rico,

in 1990, but Coastal deferred the start of its operations because

of uncertainty  due to the  Gulf War.  Eventually,  Coastal began

business operations in Puerto Rico in October 1991, buying bunker

fuel in San Juan and reselling it to ocean-going  liners at berth

in San Juan  Harbor.  Based on CFMI's  experience and reputation,

Coastal produced a business plan  which shows that it expected to

reach a  sales volume of  100,000 barrels a  month, approximately

25-30% of the  sales volume in  San Juan Harbor.   The plan  also

shows that  Coastal  assumed it  could  obtain an  average  gross

margin (sales revenues less product costs) of $1.65 a barrel.

          In  September  1991, CAPECO  agreed  to  charge Coastal

prices  based on a formula involving the previous Thursday/Friday

New York market postings, minus discounts that varied  by volume.

These prices were to cover the six month period from October 1991

to   March  1992.     Unknown  to  Coastal,   CAPECO  was  almost

simultaneously  offering Coastal's  two competitors  in San  Juan

Harbor, Caribbean Fuel Oil Trading, Inc. ("Caribbean") and Harbor

Fuel Services, Inc. ("Harbor"), new contracts that gave Caribbean

                               -3-
                                         -3-


and Harbor bigger  discounts from the formula  price than Coastal

received.1   Trial  evidence introduced  by  CAPECO's own  expert

witness quantified  the total  price discrimination  in favor  of

Caribbean and Harbor as $682,451.78  for the period from  October

1991 to April 1992.

          Coastal filed this suit in  May of 1992 when it learned

of CAPECO's price discrimination against it.  This court affirmed

the district court's denial of a preliminary injunction requiring

that CAPECO end  its price discrimination.  See  Coastal Fuels of
                                                                           

Puerto Rico, Inc.  v. Caribbean Petroleum Corp., 990  F.2d 25, 26
                                                         

(1st Cir. 1993).  After Coastal filed suit, CAPECO proposed a new

price  formula  to   Coastal.    According  to   trial  testimony

introduced by Coastal, CAPECO basically  made a "take it or leave

it" offer,  which Coastal took.  Expert testimony Coastal offered

at   trial   contended  that   competitively   significant  price

discrimination  continued until Spring  of 1993, when  CAPECO cut

Coastal off entirely.

          Additionally,  Coastal presented  evidence that,  while

throughout  this period  CAPECO would  from time  to time  inform

Coastal  that it  had  no  fuel available,  in  fact, CAPECO  had

available  fuel.   Coastal also  presented evidence  that  it was
                    
                              

1  CAPECO  tried to argue below  and again argues here,  that the
contracts   it   executed   with  Caribbean   and   Harbor   were
qualitatively different  in their non-price  terms and conditions
from CAPECO's arrangement with Coastal, justifying the discounts.
Coastal  responds  that  it  was  never  offered  the  terms  and
conditions that Caribbean  and Harbor received.  In  light of the
jury's verdict  for Coastal  on the  price discrimination  claim,
from conflicting evidence such as  this, we draw the (reasonable)
conclusion in Coastal's favor.

                               -4-
                                         -4-


discriminated against  in terms  of the quality  of fuel  that it

received  from  CAPECO.    Finally,  on  March  31, 1993,  CAPECO

informed  Coastal in  writing that  it  would not  sell any  more

product to Coastal, and shortly  thereafter, Coastal went out  of

business.

          The case was tried to a jury on claims (1) that  CAPECO

discriminated  in  price in  violation  of  Section  2(a) of  the

Clayton Act, 38 Stat. 730 (1914) (current version  at 15 U.S.C.  

13(a)), as  amended by  the  Robinson-Patman Act,  49 Stat.  1526

(1936), and  in violation of  Section 263(a)  of Title 10  of the

Laws  of  Puerto  Rico;  (2)  that  CAPECO  monopolized trade  or

commerce in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act and Section

260 of  Title 10  of the  Laws of  Puerto Rico;  (3) that  CAPECO

violated Section  5141 of Title 31 of  the Puerto Rico Civil Code

by engaging in  tortious conduct  that injured  Coastal; and  (4)

that  CAPECO  committed a  breach  of  contract  in violation  of

Sections 3371 et  seq. of Title 31 of the Puerto Rico Civil Code.
                                

As   reflected   in   the   jury's   answers   to   the   Special

Interrogatories, the jury found for Coastal on the first three of

these  claims, but  found for  CAPECO on  the breach  of contract

claim.  The jury awarded  damages of $1,500,000 for the antitrust

violations  combined  and  $500,000  for  the  Puerto  Rico  tort

violation.   The  antitrust damages  were trebled, see  15 U.S.C.
                                                                

  15(a), bringing the total award to $5,000,000.

                            DISCUSSION
                                      DISCUSSION
                                                

                               -5-
                                         -5-


          CAPECO  argues for a  reversal of the  district court's

judgment,  or alternatively,  for a  new trial.   We  address the

arguments for reversal first.

                               -6-
                                         -6-


                    I.  Arguments for Reversal
                              I.  Arguments for Reversal

          The first set  of issues involves the  district court's

denial of CAPECO's motions for judgment as a matter of  law under

Fed. R. Civ. P. 50.   With respect to matters of  law, our review

is de novo.  Sandy River Nursing Care v. Aetna Casualty, 985 F.2d
                                                                 

1138, 1141 (1st Cir. 1993).

          Seeking  judgment as a matter of law, CAPECO has raised

a set of issues on appeal that concern the application of federal

and Puerto Rico law on price discrimination and monopoly, as well

as Puerto Rico tort law, to the facts of this case.  With respect

to these  issues, we review  the court's decision de  novo, using
                                                                    

the  same  stringent  decisional  standards  that controlled  the

district  court.  See  Sullivan v.  National Football  League, 34
                                                                       

F.3d 1091, 1096 (1st Cir. 1994); Gallagher v. Wilton Enterprises,
                                                                           

Inc.,  962 F.2d 120, 125 (1st Cir. 1992).  Under these standards,
              

judgment for CAPECO  can only be ordered if  the evidence, viewed

in the  light most favorable  to Coastal, points so  strongly and

overwhelmingly in  favor of CAPECO, that a  reasonable jury could

not have arrived at a verdict for Coastal.  See Sullivan, 34 F.3d
                                                                  

at 1096; Gallagher, 962 F.2d at 124-25.
                            

                     A.  Price Discrimination
                               A.  Price Discrimination

          Section 2(a) of the Clayton Act, amended in 1936 by the

Robinson-Patman Act, makes it

            unlawful   for   any  person   . . .   to
            discriminate in  price between  different
            purchasers of  commodities of  like grade
            and quality, where either  or any of  the
            purchases involved in such discrimination
            are in commerce,  . . . where  the effect

                               -7-
                                         -7-


            of    such    discrimination    may    be
            substantially  to  lessen  competition or
            tend  to create a monopoly in any line of
            commerce,  or  to   injure,  destroy,  or
            prevent competition  with any  person who
            either grants  or knowingly  receives the
            benefit of such discrimination . . . .

15 U.S.C.   13(a).  A pair of sales at different prices makes out

a  prima  facie  case.   See  Falls City  Indus.,  Inc.  v. Vanco
                                                                           

Beverage, Inc., 460  U.S. 428, 444 n.10 (1983);  FTC v. Anheuser-
                                                                           

Busch, Inc., 363 U.S. 536,  549 (1960) ("[A] price discrimination
                     

within  the  meaning   of  [the  statute]   is  merely  a   price

difference.").

          Section  2(a)   includes  two   offenses  that   differ

substantially, but are covered by the same statutory language.  A

"primary-line" violation occurs where the discriminating seller's

price  discrimination  adversely  impacts  competition  with  the

seller's direct competitors.   See,  e.g., Brooke  Group Ltd.  v.
                                                                       

Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp.,     U.S.     , 113 S. Ct. 2578,
                                          

2586, reh'g denied, 114 S. Ct. 13 (1993).   See generally Herbert
                                                                   

Hovenkamp, Federal Antitrust  Policy: The Law of  Competition and
                                                                           

its  Practice    8.8  (1994).   In  contrast, a  "secondary-line"
                       

violation  occurs   where  the   discriminating  seller's   price

discrimination  injures competition among his customers, that is,

purchasers from  the seller.  See, e.g., FTC  v. Sun Oil Co., 371
                                                                      

U.S. 505,  519 (1963);  Caribe BMW,  Inc.  v. Bayerische  Motoren
                                                                           

Werke, A.G., 19 F.3d 745, 748  (1st Cir. 1994); J.F. Feeser, Inc.
                                                                           

v. Serv-A-Portion, Inc.,  909 F.2d 1524, 1535-38 (3d  Cir. 1990),
                                 

cert. denied, 499  U.S. 921 (1991).    See generally  Hovenkamp  
                                                              

                               -8-
                                         -8-


14.6.   The theory  of injury is  generally that  the defendant's

lower  price sales  to the  plaintiff's  competitor (the  favored

purchaser) placed the plaintiff at a competitive disadvantage and

caused it to lose business.  Id.
                                          

          We address first CAPECO's contention that  the district

court erred in treating this  case as one of secondary-line price

discrimination  rather  than primary-line  price  discrimination.

Specifically, CAPECO protests the district court's instruction to

the  jury that injury  to competition among  competing purchaser-

resellers  may  be  inferred  from  proof  of  substantial  price

discrimination by a producer among competing purchaser-resellers,

an  inference appropriate to  secondary-line discrimination.  See
                                                                           

FTC v. Morton Salt Co., 334 U.S. 37, 50-51 (1948).  CAPECO argues
                                

that Coastal  is affiliated  with an  organization that  competes

with CAPECO,  and therefore  this was a  primary-line case;  as a

result, the Morton Salt inference would not apply.
                                 

          We do not consider the argument that this is a primary-

line case,  because CAPECO has  chosen to make this  argument for

the first time on appeal.  While CAPECO did object to  the Morton
                                                                           

Salt  instruction at  the  district  court,  that  objection  was
              

directed at the use of the  word "infer" couched in a generalized

attack on the instruction as  suggesting a presumption not  borne

out by case law.2  We have noted before that "Rule 513 means what

                    
                              

2  We address this distinct argument below.

3  Fed. R. Civ. P. 51 states, in pertinent part, that

                               -9-
                                         -9-


it says:   the grounds for objection must  be stated 'distinctly'

after the charge to give the  judge an opportunity to correct his

[or  her] error."   Linn  v. Andover  Newton  Theological School,
                                                                           

Inc., 874 F.2d  1, 5 (1st Cir.  1989); see also Jordan  v. United
                                                                           

States Lines, Inc.,  738 F.2d 48,  51 (1st  Cir. 1984).   Leaving
                            

aside  whether the  district court  in fact  erred in  making the

questioned  instruction, it seems  clear that CAPECO  did not set

forth  the argument  it  now  advances when  it  objected to  the

instruction at issue.   And if CAPECO did intend  to express this

argument, it  neither advised  the district  court judge  of this

problem in  a manner that  would allow him to  make a correction,

nor informed  him what a satisfactory  cure would be.   Linn, 874
                                                                      

F.2d at 5.  Because the argument was thus not preserved,  we will

reverse or  award a new  trial only if  the error "resulted  in a

miscarriage  of justice  or  'seriously  affected  the  fairness,

integrity  or public  reputation of  the judicial  proceedings.'"

Scarfo v.  Cabletron Systems,  Inc., 54 F.3d  931, 945  (1st Cir.
                                             

1995) (quoting Lash v. Cutts, 943 F.2d 147, 152 (1st Cir. 1991)).
                                      

We fail  to find such  concerns of judicial  propriety implicated

here.4
                    
                              

            [n]o party  shall  assign  as  error  the
            giving   or  the   failure  to   give  an
            instruction  unless  that  party  objects
            thereto  before   the  jury   retires  to
            consider its verdict,  stating distinctly
            the matter objected to and the grounds of
            the objection.

4  While  this court has admitted "occasional"  exceptions to the
"raise-or-waive" principle, see National Assoc. of Social Workers
                                                                           
v.  Harwood, 69  F.3d at  627-28,  the concerns  that justify  an
                     

                               -10-
                                         -10-


          As a result, we analyze  this case as one of secondary-

line discrimination.   Thus, the theory of injury  is that CAPECO

sold bunker fuel  to Coastal at an unfavorable  price relative to

Harbor  and  Caribbean,  and  consequently,  competition  between

Coastal, Harbor  and Caribbean was  thereby injured.   On appeal,

CAPECO  makes three  arguments based  on what  it purports  to be

required  elements  for  Coastal's price  discrimination  damages

claim:  first, that the sales in question  were not "in commerce"

and  so section  2(a)'s prohibitions do  not apply;  second, that

Coastal  failed  to  make the  requisite  showing  of competitive

injury to  prevail; and third,  that Coastal failed to  carry its

burden  of proving  actual injury in  order to be  entitled to an

award of money damages.

                        1.  "In Commerce"
                                  1.  "In Commerce"

          CAPECO argues, correctly we conclude, that section 2(a)

of the Clayton  Act does not apply  because in the instant  case,

neither of the two transactions  which evidence the alleged price

discrimination  crossed a  state line.   Gulf  Oil Corp.  v. Copp
                                                                           

Paving Co.,  419  U.S. 186,  200-201,  200 n.17  (1974).   For  a
                    

transaction  to qualify,  the product  at  issue must  physically

cross a state boundary in either the sale to the favored buyer or

the sale  to  the buyer  allegedly discriminated  against.   See,
                                                                          

e.g., Misco, Inc. v. United States Steel Corp., 784 F.2d 198, 202
                                                        
                    
                              

exception are  not implicated  here, see id.,  69 F.3d  at 627-28
                                                      
(finding exception given certain circumstances including the fact
that failure to raise  issue did not deprive court  of appeals of
useful  factfinding, and  the  fact that  the  issue in  question
raises constitutional concerns).

                               -11-
                                         -11-


(6th Cir.  1986); Black Gold  Ltd. v. Rockwool  Industries, Inc.,
                                                                          

729 F.2d 676, 683 (10th Cir.), cert. denied, 469 U.S. 854 (1984);
                                                     

William Inglis &  Sons Baking Co. v. ITT  Continental Baking Co.,
                                                                          

668 F.2d  1014, 1043-44 (9th  Cir. 1981), cert. denied,  459 U.S.
                                                                

825 (1982);  S&M Materials  Co. v. Southern  Stone Co.,  612 F.2d
                                                                

198, 200 (5th Cir.), cert. denied, 449 U.S. 832 (1980); Rio Vista
                                                                           

Oil, Ltd.  v. Southland  Corp., 667  F. Supp.  757, 763 (D.  Utah
                                        

1987).

          However,  this issue  is not  dispositive, because  the

jury  found   that  CAPECO   violated  the   Puerto  Rico   price

discrimination statute, which is identical to Section 2(a) except

that it contains no interstate commerce requirement.5  CAPECO has

not  challenged the  district  court's supplemental  jurisdiction

stemming from Coastal's Sherman Act claims.  The relevant statute

states that "in  any civil action over which  the district courts
                    
                              

5  The relevant language is as follows:

            It  shall  be  unlawful for  any  person,
            either   directly   or   indirectly,   to
            discriminate in  price between  different
            purchasers of  commodities of  like grade
            and quality,  where such  commodities are
            sold for  use, consumption, or  resale in
            Puerto Rico, and where the effect of such
            discrimination  may  be  substantially to
            lessen competition  or tend  to create  a
            monopoly  in  any  line  of  commerce  in
            Puerto Rico,  or to  injure, destroy,  or
            prevent competition  with any  person who
            either grants  or knowingly  receives the
            benefit of  such discrimination,  or with
            customers of either of them.

10 L.P.R.A. 263 (1976).   Furthermore, Puerto Rico law includes a
counterpart for the section 4  of the Clayton Act's authorization
of treble damages.  See 10 L.P.R.A. 268 (1976).
                                 

                               -12-
                                         -12-


have  original  jurisdiction,  the  district  courts  shall  have

supplemental  jurisdiction  over  all other  claims  that  are so

related to claims in the action . . . that they form part of  the

same  case  or  controversy."    28 U.S.C.     1367  (1994).   In

application, "[i]f, considered without regard to their federal or

state character, a  plaintiff's claims are  such that [it]  would

ordinarily  be  expected   to  try  them  all  in   one  judicial

proceeding, then,  assuming substantiality of the federal issues,

there is power in federal courts to hear the whole."  United Mine
                                                                           

Workers of America v. Gibbs,  383 U.S. 715, (1966); see Rodr guez
                                                                           

v. Doral  Mortgage Corp., 57  F.3d 1168, 1175-76 (1st  Cir. 1995)
                                  

(interpreting and  applying 28  U.S.C.   1367).   In  the instant

case, the price discrimination claims flow out of the same set of

facts and  require the same  evidence as the Sherman  Act claims.

Because  we uphold  the district  court's  jurisdiction over  the

Sherman Act  claims, see 15  U.S.C.   4 (1994)  (investing "[t]he
                                  

several  district  courts  of  the  United  States  .  .  .  with

jurisdiction to  prevent and  restrain violations  of [Title  15]

sections 1 to 7[,]" which includes the Sherman Act), we also must

conclude that the district court properly exercised supplementary

jurisdiction over the price discrimination claims.

          Thus,  we conclude  that the  district  court erred  in

applying section 2(a) of the Clayton Act to the conduct at issue,

and accordingly  reverse that part  of its opinion.   However, we

find applicable section 263 of the Puerto Rico Anti-Monopoly Act,

10 L.P.R.A.   263.  Because  section 263 was patterned after  and

                               -13-
                                         -13-


is  almost identical  to  section  2(a) of  the  Clayton Act,  as

amended by the Robinson-Patman Act, we look to  the jurisprudence

interpreting federal  law as  a guide  in applying the  statute.6

Given that the one key  difference between the federal and Puerto

Rico statutes is the lack of an  "in commerce" requirement in the

Puerto  Rico analogue,  we  conclude  that  we  should  interpret

section 263 as intended to  extend the provisions of section 2(a)

of the  Clayton Act to  price discrimination within  Puerto Rico,

the situation which we  confront in the instant case.   Given the

relative lack  of applicable section  263 case law and  the well-

developed jurisprudence concerning  Clayton Act section 2(a),  we

will focus on  the latter in  assessing the price  discrimination

claims.

                    2.  Injury to Competition
                              2.  Injury to Competition

          CAPECO's second  argument in  support of reversing  the

price  discrimination portion  of the  judgment  is that  Coastal

failed to demonstrate injury to  competition.  As noted above, we

analyze  this case as one of secondary-line price discrimination,

                    
                              

6   See  Caribe  BMW,  Inc.,  19 F.3d  at  753  (1st  Cir.  1994)
                                     
(interpreting "Puerto  Rico's laws  as essentially  embodying the
jurisprudence  relevant  to  the  parallel  federal  law,"  where
antitrust plaintiff asserted claims under a Puerto Rico antitrust
law that paralleled  its federal antitrust law  claim); Whirlpool
                                                                           
Corp. v. U.M.C.O. Int'l Corp., 748 F. Supp. 1557, 1565 n.4  (S.D.
                                       
Fla.  1990)  (noting  that  "federal  precedents  construing  the
[Clayton   Act,  as  amended  by  the]  Robinson-Patman  Act  are
applicable to the  interpretation of Section  263" of the  Puerto
Rico Anti-Monopoly Act); see also Diario de Sesiones,  1964, Vol.
                                           
18,  Part 4, pp.  1425-26, 1509, 1512,  1707-09; Arturo Estrella,
Antitrust Law in Puerto Rico, 28 Rev.  Jur. del Col. Ab. P.R. 615
                                      
(stating that interpretations of the Federal  Robinson-Patman Act
are to be looked to in construing section 263).

                               -14-
                                         -14-


and  thus  Coastal   bears  the  burden  of   showing  injury  to

competition  between Coastal and its rival bunker fuel resellers,

Harbor and Caribbean.   Addressing the  burden of the  secondary-

line plaintiff, the Supreme Court has stated that 

            [i]t  would  greatly  handicap  effective
            enforcement   of  the   Act  to   require
            testimony to show  that which we  believe
            to be self-evident, namely, that there is
            a    "reasonable     possibility"    that
            competition may be  adversely affected by
            a practice under  which manufacturers and
            producers  sell   their  goods   to  some
            customers substantially cheaper than they
            sell  like goods  to  the competitors  of
            these customers.

Morton Salt Co., 334 U.S. at 50.  As a result, the Supreme  Court
                         

has  held that  "for  the  purposes of  section  2(a), injury  to

competition is established prima facie by proof  of a substantial

price  discrimination between  competing  purchasers over  time."

Falls City, 460 U.S. at 435 (citing  Morton Salt, 334 U.S. at 46,
                                                          

50-51); see  also Texaco,  Inc. v. Hasbrouck,  496 U.S.  543, 559
                                                      

(1990); Monahan's Marine,  Inc. v. Boston Whaler,  Inc., 866 F.2d
                                                                 

525, 528-529  (1st Cir. 1989) (noting lower  burden for antitrust

plaintiff  under Clayton Act,  as amended by  the Robinson-Patman

Act, than  under Sherman  Act); Boise Cascade  Corp. v.  FTC, 837
                                                                      

F.2d 1127, 1139 (D.C. Cir. 1988).

          CAPECO  challenges  the  district  court's  finding  of

competitive injury in two ways, arguing that the Morton Salt rule
                                                                      

is no  longer good  law, or alternatively,  that the  Morton Salt
                                                                           

rule  was incorrectly  applied in  this case.   We  first address

CAPECO's  direct challenge  to the  vitality of  the Morton  Salt
                                                                           

                               -15-
                                         -15-


rule, a challenge based on  the Supreme Court's opinion in Brooke
                                                                           

Group, 113 S.  Ct. 2578.  In  that case, the Supreme  Court ruled
               

that,  because primary-line price discrimination injury is of the

"same general character" as predatory  pricing schemes actionable

under Sherman Act section  2, Brooke Group,     U.S.    ,  113 S.
                                                    

Ct.  at  2587, a  primary-line  injury plaintiff  bears  the same

substantive burden  as  under  the  Sherman  Act,  that  is,  the

plaintiff  must show  that  the predator  stands  some chance  of

recouping his losses,  id.     U.S. at     , 113 S. Ct.  at 2588.
                                    

In so deciding,  the Supreme Court implicitly  overruled Utah Pie
                                                                           

Co. v. Continental Baking Co., 386 U.S. 685 (1967),  in which the
                                       

Supreme  Court had set forth different standards for primary-line

injury.   Brooke  Group,      U.S.  at    ,  113 S.  Ct.  at 2587
                                 

(explaining  that  Utah   Pie  was  merely  an   "early  judicial
                                       

inquiry").

          According  to   CAPECO,  the  Supreme   Court's  recent

emphasis  in  Brooke  Group  on reconciling  the  area  of  price
                                     

discrimination with  other antitrust  law requires  that we  find

that the Morton  Salt rule no longer  is good law.   CAPECO notes
                               

that both  primary-line and  secondary-line price  discrimination

are prohibited by the same language of section 2(a) as amended by

the Robinson-Patman Act.   Furthermore, CAPECO contends  that the

Supreme Court in Brooke Group apparently undercut any reliance on
                                       

a principled  distinction between  the aims of  section 2  of the

Clayton  Act  and  other antitrust  laws'  purported  emphasis on

protecting  "competition, not competitors,"  Brooke Group, 113 S.
                                                                   

                               -16-
                                         -16-


Ct. at 2588  (emphasis in original) (citation  omitted); see also
                                                                           

Monahan's Marine,  Inc., 866 F.2d  at 528-29 (not  discussing the
                                 

Morton Salt rule, but noting  that "unlike the Sherman Act, which
                     

protects  'competition not  competitors,' .  .  . the  [Robinson-
                                                 

Patman] Act protects those who compete with a favored seller, not
                                                

just the  overall competitive process."  (emphasis in original)).

Thus,  according to CAPECO, precedent that pre-dates Brooke Group
                                                                           

and applies the Morton Salt rule must be  reexamined.  See, e.g.,
                                                                          

496 U.S. at  544; Falls City, 460  U.S. at 436; Boise  Cascade v.
                                                                        

FTC, 837 F.2d 1127, 1153 (D.C. Cir. 1988).
             

          While  CAPECO's argument  has merit,  we  join the  two

other   circuits  that  have   addressed  competitive  injury  in

secondary-line  cases since Brooke Group in refusing to disregard
                                                  

the rule the  Supreme Court formulated in Morton  Salt, for three
                                                                

reasons.7  First, the statutory structure that prohibits primary-

line  price  discrimination  "stands  on  an  entirely  different

footing" than the statutory scheme that proscribes secondary-line

discrimination.  See Rebel  Oil Co., 51 F.3d  at 1446.   Congress
                                             

first forbade primary-line price discrimination with  the Clayton
                    
                              

7   See Stelwagon  Manufacturing Co. v.  Tarmac Roofing  Systems,
                                                                           
Inc., 63  F.3d 1267,  1271 (3d Cir.  1995) (applying  Morton Salt
                                                                           
rule  without  discussion of  Brooke  Group);  Rebel Oil  Co.  v.
                                                                       
Atlantic  Richfield  Co.,  51  F.3d 1421,  1446  (9th  Cir. 1995)
                                  
(noting in  dicta that "in holding that  a primary-line plaintiff
must  demonstrate  an  injury  flowing  from  an  aspect  of  the
defendant's conduct injurious  to consumer welfare, we  intend in
no way to affect the  standard for antitrust injury in secondary-
line  cases").   But see  also Bob  Nicholson Appliance,  Inc. v.
                                                                        
Maytag Co., 883 F. Supp. 321, 326 (S.D. Ind. 1994)  (holding that
                    
"we  are  persuaded that  the  Seventh Circuit  would  extend the
reasoning   of  Brooke  Group   and  require  actual   injury  to
                                       
competition").

                               -17-
                                         -17-


Act of 1914, which originally condemned discrimination that might

"substantially   . .  . lessen  competition or  tend to  create a

monopoly in  any line  of commerce."   Clayton Antitrust  Act, 38

Stat.  730 (1914)  (codified  as  amended at  15  U.S.C.    13(a)

(1994)).  The statute was  intended to prevent large corporations

from  invading  markets  of small  firms  and  charging predatory

prices  for the purpose of destroying marketwide competition, and

thus specifically applied only to  primary-line injury.  See H.R.
                                                                      

Rep. No. 627, 63rd Cong., 2d Sess.   8 (1914); E. Thomas Sullivan

& Jeffrey L. Harrison, Understanding  Antitrust and Its  Economic
                                                                           

Implications   8.03 (1988).
                      

          By   contrast,    secondary-line   discrimination    is

forbidden  by the Robinson-Patman  Act, 49 Stat.  1526 (1936), 15

U.S.C.     13-13b, 21a (1988), which amended the original Clayton

Act's  price  discrimination  proscriptions.    Congress  clearly

intended the  Robinson-Patman Act's  provision to  apply only  to

secondary-line cases, not  to primary-line cases.   See H.R. Rep.
                                                                 

No. 2287, 74th  Cong., 2d Sess.    8 (1936),8 cited in  Rebel Oil
                                                                           

Co., 51 F.3d at  1446.  In  contrast to the  Sherman Act and  the
             

Clayton  Act, which were intended to  proscribe only conduct that

threatens  consumer  welfare, the  Robinson-Patman  Act's framers

"intended  to  punish  perceived economic  evils  not necessarily

                    
                              

8   The Robinson-Patman  Act "attaches  to competitive  relations
between a  given seller and  his several customers.   It concerns
discrimination  between customers  of the  same  seller.   It has
nothing to  do with  . .  .  requir[ing] the  maintenance of  any
relationship in prices charged by a competing seller."  H.R. Rep.
No. 2287, 74th Cong., 2d Sess.   8 (1936).

                               -18-
                                         -18-


threatening to  consumer welfare per se."  Rebel Oil Co., 51 F.3d
                                                                  

at 1445.    See generally  Hovenkamp   2.1a.  In  particular, the
                                   

Robinson-Patman  Act's amendments to the Clayton Act stemmed from

dissatisfaction  with  the original  Clayton  Act's  inability to

prevent  large retail chains from obtaining volume discounts from

big  suppliers,  at  the  disadvantage  of  small  retailers  who

competed with  the chains.  See S. Rep.  No. 1502, 74th Cong., 2d
                                         

Sess.   4 (1936); H.R. Rep. No. 2287, 74th Cong., 2d Sess.    3-4

(1936); see also Morton Salt,  334 U.S. at 49 ("Congress intended
                                      

to protect  a merchant  from competitive  injury attributable  to

discriminatory  prices");  Rebel  Oil Co.,  51  F.3d  1421, 1446;
                                                   

Monahan's Marine, Inc., 866 F.2d at 528-29.
                                

          Second, we are persuaded by the reasoning  of the Ninth

Circuit's  opinion in  Rebel Oil  Co. that  the amendment  to the
                                               

Clayton  Act effected  by the  Robinson-Patman  Act supports  the

continued vitality of the  Morton Salt rule, even in the  face of
                                                

Brooke  Group's alteration  of standards  for primary-line  price
                       

discrimination.   While the  Clayton Act only  proscribed conduct

that may  "substantially lessen competition  or tend to  create a

monopoly[,]" the  new law  added the following  passage:   "or to

injure,  destroy,  or  prevent competition  with  any  person who

either  grants  or   knowingly  receives  the  benefit   of  such

discrimination, or with customers of  either of them."  See Rebel
                                                                           

Oil Co., 51 F.3d   at 1447.  The purpose  of this passage was  to
                 

relieve  secondary-line  plaintiffs --  small  retailers  who are

disfavored  by discriminating suppliers  -- from having  to prove

                               -19-
                                         -19-


harm to competition  marketwide, allowing them instead  to impose

liability simply  by proving  effects on  individual competitors.

See id.; H.R.  Rep. No. 2287,  74th Cong., 2d  Sess.   8  (1936).
                 

Such legislative intent directly supports  maintaining the Morton
                                                                           

Salt  rule, which  puts  into  practice  Congress'  concern  with
              

placing the same  burden on secondary-line plaintiffs  that other

antitrust plaintiffs face.  Thus, the comparison that the Supreme

Court  drew   between  primary-line   price  discrimination   and

predatory pricing  in Brooke  Group  stands on  a different,  and
                                             

stronger, footing than any comparison  that could be made between

secondary-line price discrimination  and other area of  antitrust

law, including, but not only, predatory pricing. 

          Third, and  finally, the  holding of  the Brooke  Group
                                                                           

opinion  on its  face  applies only  to  primary-line cases,  not

secondary-line cases.  As a result, given the legislative history

and statutory language distinctions, we will not presume, without

more guidance, that the Supreme Court intended in Brooke Group to
                                                                        

alter the well-established rule that it adopted in Morton  Salt.9
                                                                         

Thus,  we hold that  the Morton Salt  rule continues  to apply to
                                              

secondary-line injury cases such as the present one.
                    
                              

9   While concerns about overenforcement harming overall consumer
welfare may  be valid,  the Supreme Court  retains the  option of
speaking  further  on this  issue.   See  generally  Paul Larule,
                                                             
Robinson-Patman Act in the Twenty-First Century:  Will the Morton
                                                                           
Salt  Rule  Be Retired?  48  S.M.U.  L.  Rev. 1917,  1927  (1995)
                                 
(concluding that "[w]hen an appropriate case comes before it, the
[Supreme]  Court  may  well  decide  to  make  the  final  cut");
Hovenkamp     14.6a   (arguing  that,  after  Brooke   Group,  "a
                                                                      
reinterpretation of  Robinson-Patman so  as to permit  secondary-
line injury  only when competition  itself is threatened  is long
overdue").

                               -20-
                                         -20-


          The Morton Salt rule provides that, for the purposes of
                                   

secondary-line claims under section  2(a), "injury to competition

is established  prima  facie  by proof  of  a  substantial  price

discrimination between competing  purchasers over  time."   Falls
                                                                           

Cities Industries  v. Vanco  Beverage, Inc.,  460  U.S. 428,  435
                                                     

(1983)  (citing Morton  Salt, 334  U.S.  at 46,  50-51).   If the
                                      

plaintiff makes  such a  showing, then "[t]his  inference may  be

overcome by  evidence breaking  the causal  connection between  a

price differential and  lost sales or profits."   Falls City, 460
                                                                      

U.S. at 435.  Barring evidence breaking that connection, however,

"for  a[] plaintiff to  prove competitive injury  under Robinson-

Patman,  he [or  she] need  only  show that  a substantial  price

discrimination  existed as between  himself [or herself]  and his

[or her]  competitors   over  a period  of time."   Hasbrouck  v.
                                                                       

Texaco, Inc.,  842 F.2d  1034, 1041 (9th  Cir. 1987),  aff'd, 496
                                                                      

U.S. 543 (1990).

          Here the jury  properly inferred prima facie  injury to
                                                                

competition since Coastal produced sufficient evidence before the

jury  to conclude  (1) that  the discrimination  in question  was

continuous  and  substantial  and  (2)  that  the  discrimination

occurred  in  a  business  where  profit  margins  were  low  and

competition was keen.  4 Von Kalinowski, Antitrust Laws and Trade
                                                                           

Regulation   31.04(1).   First, the discrimination lasted  all 18
                    

months that Coastal was in business, and always exceeded the five

cents  per  barrel  that  witnesses testified  was  competitively

significant.   Additionally, there  was ample testimony  that the

                               -21-
                                         -21-


marine  fuel  oil  business, in  which  Coastal  competed against

Caribbean  and  Harbor,  was characterized  by  thin  margins and

intense competition.   At  any rate, on  appeal, CAPECO  does not

make  the  argument  that  Coastal  failed  to  produce  evidence

required for a prima facie showing of injury to competition under
                                    

the Morton Salt rule.
                         

          However, CAPECO argues  that the Morton  Salt inference
                                                                 

was undercut by evidence "breaking the causal connection" between

CAPECO's  price  discrimination  and   Coastal's  lost  sales  or

profits, Falls City,  460 U.S. at 435, and showing  an absence of
                             

competitive injury,  Boise Cascade Corp.  v. FTC, 837  F.2d 1144,
                                                          

1146  (D.C.  Cir. 1988).    According to  CAPECO,  overall market

forces depressed the  price for bunker fuel more  than 30 percent

between late 1991  and early 1992,  and it was this  fact, rather

than CAPECO's price discrimination, that led to Coastal's demise.

CAPECO  points to the  admission of Coastal's  CEO that Coastal's

sales  agents based  their price  quotes to  ships on  the prices

being charged by  competitors in San Juan and  other ports, often

without  even  knowing  the  cost of  the  fuel  that  was  to be

delivered.   According to CAPECO,  if prices were set  when costs

were unknown,  then discounts from  CAPECO could not have  been a

material factor in setting prices.

          We  reject  the  argument  that  this  evidence  rebuts

Coastal's  prima facie  showing  of  price  discrimination.    In
                                

reviewing the  jury verdict, "[w]e are compelled .  . . even in a

close  case,  to   uphold  the  verdict  unless   the  facts  and

                               -22-
                                         -22-


inferences, when  viewed in a  light most favorable to  the party

for whom the  jury held, point so strongly  and overwhelmingly in

favor of the movant that a reasonable jury could not have arrived

at  this  conclusion."    Chedd-Angier  Production  Co.  v.  Omni
                                                                           

Publications Int'l Ltd.,  756 F.2d 930, 934 (1st  Cir. 1985); see
                                                                           

also Rodr guez  v. Montalvo, 871  F.2d 163, 165 (1st  Cir. 1989);
                                     

Castro v. Stanley Works, 864 F.2d 961, 963 (1st Cir. 1989); Brown
                                                                           

v. Freedman Baking Co., 810 F.2d 6, 12 (1st Cir. 1987).  Thus, in
                                

this case,  the appellants  must "persuade us  that the  facts of

this case  so conclusively  point to a  verdict in  [their] favor

that  fair-minded people could  not disagree about  the outcome."

Chedd-Angier Production Co., 756 F.2d at 934.
                                     

          Here,  neither section  2(a),  section 263,  nor  their

attendant case  law, requires  that the  price discrimination  in

question be directly  factored into the  prices that favored  and

disfavored  purchaser-resellers   offered  to   their  customers.

Presumably,  regardless  of  whether these  costs  were  factored

directly into  the prices  that  Coastal offered,  or were  later

calculated  into  Coastal's  bottom  line,  these costs  affected

Coastal's pricing.  Certainly, no  argument can be made from this

evidence  alone that bunker fuel  costs, no matter when accounted

for, were not causally connected to Coastal's lost profits.  See,
                                                                          

e.g., Hasbrouck v. Texaco, Inc., 842 F.2d 1034, 1039-41 (9th Cir.
                                         

1987), aff'd, 496  U.S. 543  (1990) (finding  that evidence  that
                      

"some portion" of small extra  discounts of 2 -5  on gasoline was

passed on  by  favored customers  sufficient,  particularly  when

                               -23-
                                         -23-


retail   gasoline  market   was   "strongly  price   sensitive").

Additionally,  the  fact  that Coastal's  sales  agents  operated

without  complete knowledge of the  prices at which other Coastal

agents  were  purchasing  the  bunker fuel  that  would  later be

delivered does  not, without more, show an absence of competitive

injury.

                        3.  Actual Injury
                                  3.  Actual Injury

          CAPECO  also contends  that Coastal  failed  to present

adequate evidence  of actual injury  to support the verdict.   On

appeal, CAPECO does not complain that the court's instructions to

the jury on the actual  injury requirement were erroneous.  Thus,

the only question  regarding this issue  is whether the  evidence

that  Coastal presented  to the  jury  was adequate  to permit  a

reasonable inference of actual injury.

          Although  we  have  concluded that  Coastal  has proved

competitive injury  under Title  10, Section 263  of the  Laws of

Puerto Rico, in order to  collect damages as a private plaintiff,

Coastal must show that CAPECO's offense was a "material cause" of

injury.  See  Zenith Radio Corp. v. Hazeltine  Research, 395 U.S.
                                                                 

100, 114 n.9 (1969);  Hasbrouck, 842 F.2d at 1042;  Allen Pen Co.
                                                                           

v.  Springfield Photo  Mount Co.,  653 F.2d  17, 21-22  (1st Cir.
                                          

1981).   Coastal  was  required to  show  that,  as a  result  of

CAPECO's  price  discrimination,  it "lost  sales  and  profits."

Hasbrouck, 842 F.2d at 1042; see Allen  Pen Co., 653 F.2d 17, 21-
                                                         

22 (1st Cir. 1981).  CAPECO contends that, to do so,  Coastal was

required  to "indicate and  document specific losses  of business

                               -24-
                                         -24-


[for Coastal] and corresponding  gains by [favored  competitors],

or   otherwise  show  that  [Coastal's]  losses  were  caused  by

[CAPECO's]    practices."        Foremost-McKesson,    Inc.    v.
                                                                     

Instrumentation Laboratory,  Inc., 527  F.2d 417,  420 (5th  Cir.
                                           

1976);  see also  Falls City,  460  U.S. at  437-38 (ruling  that
                                      

findings based on "direct evidence of  diverted sales" "more than

established the  competitive injury  required for  a prima  facie

case under section 2(a)").

          Assuming  arguendo  that CAPECO  correctly  claims that

Coastal  needed to  show specific  losses  of business,  CAPECO's

argument fails to persuade us.10   CAPECO concedes that a Coastal

employee, Andrew McIntosh ("McIntosh") testified that Coastal was

getting  "feedback" from its  customers that its  prices were not

competitive.   Whether  or  not  to credit  such  testimony is  a

decision best left to the factfinder.  See Wytrwal v. Saco School
                                                                           

Bd., 70 F.3d 165, 171 (1st Cir.  1995); Flanders & Medeiros, Inc.
                                                                           

v. Begosian, 65 F.3d  198, 204 n.4  (1st Cir. 1995).   McIntosh's
                     

testimony,  if believed,  could lead a  jury to  reasonably infer

actual injury in the form of lost sales.

          CAPECO also contends that because McIntosh's  testimony

was based on statements other  Coastal employees had made to him,

                    
                              

10   There is  conflicting authority for  the proposition  that a
jury may infer  actual injury from circumstantial  evidence.  See
                                                                           
Continental Ore Co. v. Union Carbide Corp., 370 U.S. 690, 697-700
                                                    
(1962).    However,  we  need  not  consider  here  whether  this
standard, which is more favorable to Coastal, applies rather than
the  standard that CAPECO  advocates, since Coastal  actually did
proffer evidence, albeit only employee testimony, that its prices
were causing it to lose business.

                               -25-
                                         -25-


it was both inadmissible hearsay evidence, see Fed. R. Evid. 802,
                                                        

and even if admissible, legally insufficient to support a finding

of  actual injury.   In  making this  argument, CAPECO  cites two

cases,  Stelwagon  Manufacturing Co.  v. Tarmac  Roofing Systems,
                                                                           

Inc., 63 F.3d  1267, 1275-76 (3d Cir. 1995),  and Chrysler Credit
                                                                           

Corp. v. J. Truett Payne Co., 670  F.2d 575, 581 (5th Cir. 1982).
                                      

However, the  two cases  are inapposite.   Apparently unlike  the

defendant in Stelwagon, CAPECO did not make a lower court hearsay
                                

objection to the testimony in  question.  See Stelwagon Mfg. Co.,
                                                                          

63 F.3d at 1275, n.17.

          Additionally, the Fifth Circuit's opinion  in J. Truett
                                                                           

Payne is distinguishable in a significant manner from the instant
               

case.  In a preceding Supreme Court opinion, the Court noted that

            [a]lthough [Payne  Co.'s owner]  asserted
            that his salesmen  and customers told him
            that the dealership  was being undersold,
            he admitted that  he did not know  if his
            competitors  did in  fact  pass on  their
            lower costs to their customers.

J. Truett  Payne, Co. v. Chrysler Motors Corp., 451 U.S. 557, 564
                                                        

(1981).   Likewise,  Payne Co.'s  expert witness did  not testify

that the lower  costs were passed  on in the  retail price.   Id.
                                                                           

The Court found  important the lack of evidence  that competitors

passed on discounts to customers.   Id. at 564, n.4.  On  remand,
                                                 

the  Fifth Circuit noted,  in finding the  evidence insufficient,

that Payne Co.'s witnesses only  "spoke to either the supposed or

hypothesized effect of the programs."   J. Truett Payne, 670 F.2d
                                                                 

at 581.  By contrast,  while Coastal offered similar testimony of

feedback   about  being  undersold,  it  also  put  forth  expert

                               -26-
                                         -26-


testimony that  Caribbean and  Harbor had  fully passed  on their

lower  costs to  the  ships purchasing  marine  fuel.   Coastal's

expert testified that  "CAPECO gave discriminatory low  prices to

Harbor and Caribbean . .  . [that] were fully passed on .  . . to

the  ships  purchasing  marine  fuel."    Thus,  because  Coastal

proffered evidence linking  the discounts in question  to actual,

not hypothetical, effects, J. Truett Payne is inapposite.
                                                    

          We conclude  that, once  admitted, this evidence  could

have  led   the  jury  to  reasonably  infer   actual  injury  to

competition.

                        B.  Monopolization
                                  B.  Monopolization

          Section 2 of  the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C.    2, condemns

"every person who shall monopolize,  or attempt to monopolize . .

. any part  of the trade  or commerce among the  several States."

Similarly,  Title 10,  Section 260  of  the Laws  of Puerto  Rico

tracks this language.  Claims under this Puerto Rico analogue are

to be analyzed  in the same manner  as claims under section  2 of

the Sherman Act.  See R.W. Intern.  Corp. v. Welch Food, Inc., 13
                                                                       

F.3d  478, 486-88  (1st  Cir. 1994);  Americana  Indus., Inc.  v.
                                                                       

Wometco de Puerto Rico, 556 F.2d 625, 626-28 (1st Cir. 1977); see
                                                                           

also  Pressure Vessels  of Puerto  Rico v.  Empire Gas  of Puerto
                                                                           

Rico, 94  JTS 144, *432  (P.R. 1994).   To  successfully prove  a
              

monopolization  offense, a  plaintiff  must  show  that  (1)  the

defendant has monopoly power  and (2) the defendant  "has engaged

in  impermissible  'exclusionary' practices  with  the  design or

effect  of  protecting  or  enhancing  its   monopoly  position."

                               -27-
                                         -27-


Hovenkamp     6.4a.   On  appeal,  CAPECO challenges  the  jury's

verdict that it had monopoly power, and also contends that it did

not  engage in impermissible 'exclusionary' practices in order to

protect or gain a monopoly.

          To  determine  whether  a party  has  or  could acquire

monopoly power  in a market,  "courts have found it  necessary to

consider  the  relevant  market and  the  defendant's  ability to

lessen or destroy  competition in that market."   Spectrum Sports
                                                                           

v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447, 456 (1993).  CAPECO's  first argument
                      

is that the jury erred in finding San Juan Harbor as the relevant

geographic  market for  bunker  fuel.   In general,  the relevant

geographic  market consists of "the  geographic area in which the

defendant   faces  competition   and   to  which   consumers  can

practically   turn  for  alternative  sources  of  the  product."

Baxley-DeLamar v. American Cemetary Assn., 938 F.2d 846, 850 (8th
                                                   

Cir. 1991);  see also Tampa  Electric Co. v. Nashville  Coal Co.,
                                                                          

365 U.S. 320, 327 (1961).

          In its monopolization claim, Coastal argued that CAPECO

took steps to drive it out of San Juan Harbor because  Coastal is

affiliated with a refinery in  Aruba.  Coastal apparently had the

capacity to import the residual oil and diesel into San Juan from

Aruba.   Coastal also  had storage capacity.   CAPECO  feared, so

Coastal's theory  went, that  this would  allow  the refinery  in

Aruba to compete  with CAPECO  and threaten  CAPECO's ability  to

sell  its targeted  10,000 barrels  of  residual oil  per day  to

dealers.    Coastal's  argument  is  that  CAPECO,  fearing  that

                               -28-
                                         -28-


Coastal's  affiliate posed a competitive threat, decided to drive

Coastal  out  by  (1) engaging  in  price  discrimination against

Coastal, (2) discriminating in the provision of residual oil, (3)

discriminating in the quality of the residual  oil available, and

(4) threatening to  cut off plaintiff entirely,  eventually doing

so.

          Coastal  successfully  argued  to  the  jury  that  the

relevant geographic market was San  Juan Harbor, since neither it

nor  its competitors,  Caribbean  and  Harbor, could  practicably

obtain supplies in San Juan Harbor from anyone other than CAPECO.

Coastal produced  evidence that CAPECO  made 90% of the  sales of

bunker  fuel to  resellers in the  San Juan Harbor  market -- and

CAPECO does not dispute this figure on appeal.

          CAPECO's main argument regarding monopoly power is that

the  choice  of  San  Juan  Harbor as  the  relevant  market  was

incorrect.  Instead, it maintains that because the broader market

for bunker fuel  among cruise ships and other  vessels plying the

waters  of the  Caribbean  and  the  southeastern  United  States

constrains the  prices CAPECO  can charge  resellers in  San Juan

Harbor, the proper geographic market should have been  defined to

include a much  wider area.  A larger geographic  market would of

course lead to a lower figure for the percentage of sales  in the

market made  by CAPECO, likely defeating the monopoly power prong

of the monopolization offense.

          In  assessing CAPECO's argument,  we must bear  in mind

that "market definition is a  question of fact" and "we therefore

                               -29-
                                         -29-


must affirm the jury's conclusion  unless the record is devoid of

evidence   upon  which  the   jury  might  reasonably   base  its

conclusion."  Weiss v. York Hospital, 745 F.2d 786, 825  (3d Cir.
                                              

1984);  see also  Rebel Oil  Co., 51  F.3d at 1435  (stating that
                                          

standard   upon    motion   for   directed    verdict,   judgment

notwithstanding the verdict, and summary judgment is "whether the

jury, drawing  all inferences  in favor of  the nonmoving  party,

could reasonably render a verdict in favor of the nonmoving party

in  light of  the substantive law")  (citing Anderson  v. Liberty
                                                                           

Lobby, Inc., 477 U.S. 242, 249-52 (1986)).
                     

          In  order to  show  that  CAPECO  had  monopoly  power,

Coastal was required  to show that  CAPECO had sufficient  market

power  to raise  price by  restricting  output.   IIA Phillip  E.

Areeda et al., Antitrust Law   501 (1995).  "[S]ubstantial market
                                      

power that concerns antitrust  law arises when the  defendant (1)

can profitably  set prices  well above its  costs and  (2) enjoys

some protection against [a] rival's entry or expansion that would

erode  such supracompetitive  prices and profits."   Id.   Market
                                                                  

power can  be shown through two types of  proof.  A plaintiff can

either  show direct evidence of market  power (perhaps by showing

actual  supracompetitive   prices  and   restricted  output)   or

circumstantial evidence of market power.   Rebel Oil Co., Inc. v.
                                                                        

Atlantic Richfield  Co., 51  F.3d 1421,  1434  (9th Cir.),  cert.
                                                                           

denied,  116 S.  Ct.  515 (1995).   Market  power  may be  proved
                

circumstantially by  showing that  the defendant  has a  dominant

share  in  a well-defined  relevant  market  and that  there  are

                               -30-
                                         -30-


significant barriers  to entry in  that market and  that existing

competitors lack  the capacity to  increase their  output in  the

short  run.    Id.    Coastal's  evidence  at  trial  was of  the
                            

circumstantial  type and  thus  the  question  the  parties  have

presented  on  appeal  is  whether  Coastal  supplied  sufficient

evidence for  that CAPECO  had a dominant  share in  the relevant

market.

          Before determining market share, however, the  relevant

geographic  market must be  defined.11  Although,  "[f]inding the

relevant market  and its structure is not a  goal in itself but a

surrogate of market power," see Areeda, supra,    531a, "[m]arket
                                                       

definition  is  crucial."    Rebel  Oil Co.,  51  F.3d  at  1434.
                                                     

"Without a definition of the relevant market, it is impossible to

determine market share."   Id.  Proving market  definition is the
                                        

plaintiff's burden.  See H.J., Inc.  v. Int'l Tel. & Tel.  Corp.,
                                                                          

867 F.2d 1531 (8th Cir.  1989) ("The plaintiff carries the burden

of describing a well-defined relevant market, both geographically

and by product,  which the defendants monopolized.");  Neumann v.
                                                                        

Reinforced Earth  Co., 786 F.2d  424 (D.C. Cir.)  ("The plaintiff
                               

bears  the burden of  establishing the relevant  market."), cert.
                                                                           

denied, 107  S. Ct. 181 (1986);  M.A.P. Oil Co., Inc.  v. Texaco,
                                                                           

Inc., 691 F.2d 1303, 1306 (9th Cir. 1982) ("the proponent of [the
              

monopolization]  theory must  identify the  relevant product  and
                    
                              

11  The  plaintiff must also define the  relevant product market.
H.J., Inc.  v. Int'l Tel. & Tel. Corp.,  867 F.2d 1531, 1537 (8th
                                                
Cir. 1989).   The parties agree that the  relevant product market
is residual  fuel oil  sold by all  refineries for use  as bunker
fuel for ocean-going vessels.

                               -31-
                                         -31-


geographic  markets  as  a  threshold  requirement").    Although

Coastal  has properly  pointed  out that  the question  of market

definition is one of fact for the jury, a plaintiff  must present

sufficient evidence from which a  reasonable jury could find  the

existence of the proposed relevant market.  Cf.
                                                         

Flegel  v. Christian Hosp.  Northeast-Northwest, 4 F.3d  682 (8th
                                                         

Cir. 1993) (affirming  grant of summary judgment on  grounds that

there was insufficient evidence  to support plaintiffs'  proposed

market definition).

          A market may be any grouping of sales whose sellers, if

unified  by a  hypothetical cartel  or  merger, could  profitably

raise  prices significantly above the  competitive level.  If the

sales  of  other  producers  substantially  constrain  the price-

increasing ability of  the hypothetical cartel, these  others are

part of the  market.  Areeda, supra,    533b; see also  Rebel Oil
                                                                           

Co., 51 F.3d  at 1434 (relying on Professor  Areeda's formulation
             

of  the  test for  the  relevant  market).   "The  definition  of

relevant market depends  upon economic  restraints which  prevent

sellers from  raising prices  above competitive  levels."   H.J.,
                                                                           

Inc., 867 F.2d at 1537.
              

          Coastal  and  CAPECO   have  presented  two   competing

conceptions of the relevant market.  Coastal argues, and the jury

found,12 that the relevant market was the market for residual oil
                    
                              

12  The  jury answered "yes" to the  special interrogatory asking
"Did Coastal establish that there is a relevant market comprising
of the  sale  of  residual fuel  oil  or diesel  to  bunker  fuel
resellers in the  port of San Juan  and that CAPECO  has monopoly
power in the relevant market?"

                               -32-
                                         -32-


for bunker  fuel in  San Juan.   Coastal presented  evidence that

resellers in San  Juan (Harbor, Caribbean and  Coastal) purchased

90% of their  supplies for bunker  fuel from CAPECO.   CAPECO, in

contrast,  has  argued  that  the  relevant  market  is  broader,

consisting of all  sales of residual oil  for bunker fuel in  the

Caribbean  and  Southeastern United  States.   Our review  of the

issue leads us to  conclude that it would  be unreasonable for  a

juror  to infer  from the  evidence presented  that the  sales of

residual  oil for  bunker  fuel  outside of  San  Juan should  be

excluded from the relevant market.

          The  residual oil CAPECO  sells is blended  with diesel

into bunker fuel  and sold by resellers like  Coastal, Harbor and

Caribbean  to large ocean-going  vessels.  Residual  oil refiners

and  bunker fuel  resellers exist  throughout  the Caribbean  and

Southeastern United States.   The parties  agree that the  ocean-

going vessels can choose to  refuel from whatever supplier in the

Caribbean and Southeastern United States offers the best terms as

to price, quality and dependability.   The market for bunker fuel

is  therefore extremely  fluid and  competitive,  as the  parties

agree.

          Coastal  argues  that,  because  of  this  competition,

margins  for  resellers  are  razor  thin  and  it  is  virtually

impossible for  a reseller in  San Juan, like Coastal,  to obtain

residual  oil  from  anyone  other  than  CAPECO.    Transporting

supplies from other  refineries, such as the refinery  Coastal is

affiliated with in  Aruba, would increase the cost of the fuel to

                               -33-
                                         -33-


such an extent (transportation costs, import taxes, risk of price

changes, and storage costs) that it is not an economically viable

alternative.  (Of course, this is, it might be observed, somewhat

inconsistent with  the theory  that CAPECO was  so afraid  of the

'threat' from  Coastal and  its Aruba  affiliate,  that it  drove

Coastal  out   of  business.)     Consequently,  Coastal  argues,

resellers of bunker  fuel must purchase from CAPECO  when they do

business in San Juan.  In Coastal's view, the San Juan resellers'

inability to purchase  from suppliers outside  of San Juan  makes

San Juan the relevant market.

          We  do not agree.  The  touchstone of market definition

is whether  a hypothetical  monopolist could  raise prices.   See
                                                                           

Rebel Oil Co., 51 F.3d at 1434.  Although a reseller based in San
                       

Juan  may have nowhere else to turn  to in San Juan for its fuel,

Coastal  did  not  produce sufficient  evidence  that  this meant

CAPECO has the ability to restrict supply and raise prices in San

Juan to supracompetitive levels.   Indeed, the evidence points in

the other  direction.   CAPECO cannot sell  its residual  oil for

bunker fuel  unless it does so at a  price at which the resellers

will  be able  to sell  the fuel to  its ultimate  consumers, the

ocean-going vessels.   Those ocean-going vessels can  go anywhere

in the  Caribbean  and Southeastern  United States  to get  their

bunker  fuel.   If  CAPECO  were  to  raise  its  prices  to  the

resellers, the resellers  could not offer the bunker  fuel to the

ocean-going  vessels  at competitive  prices and  the ocean-going

vessels would simply get their fuel at another port.

                               -34-
                                         -34-


          Given these facts, the immobility of the resellers does

not mean  that CAPECO could  maximize profits  by raising  prices

significantly above the competitive level.  Raising prices in San

Juan  would repel the  ultimate consumers,  who would  seek other

suppliers.  The  resellers would either stop  purchasing residual

fuel or  cease business,  or both.   CAPECO would  then lose  its

ability  to sell its residual oil for  bunker fuel and this would

redound to the benefit of CAPECO's competitors.  While under most

circumstances  the  immobility  of  the  resellers  would  be  of

considerable  importance  in  defining the  market,  it  does not

control  here  where  the  mobility  of  the  ultimate  consumers

protects  the immobile resellers.   Cf. Ball Memorial Hosp., Inc.
                                                                           

v.  Mutual  Hosp. Ins.,  Inc.,  784  F.2d  1325 (7th  Cir.  1986)
                                       

(Easterbrook,   J.)  (relevant  market  for  purposes  of  health

insurance  coverage  to  Indiana   consumers  was  "regional   or

national" not simply Indiana, even though Indiana consumers could

not  get insurance  from any  source other  than defendant  doing

business in  Indiana; the  mobility  of potential  rivals to  the

defendant protected the consumers whose mobility was restricted).

Under the circumstances here,  defining the market as San Juan is

too narrow.  It does not capture the likelihood of expanded sales

by CAPECO's rivals in the event that CAPECO were  to raise prices

in San Juan.

          Once  the relevant  market  is  defined  to  include  a

geographic region larger  than San Juan (i.e., the  Caribbean and
                                                       

Southeastern United States), Coastal has not satisfied its burden

                               -35-
                                         -35-


of  showing that  CAPECO  had  a dominant  market  share.   While

Coastal might, at least in theory, have shown that all refineries

throughout  the  Caribbean  and the  Southeastern  United  States

behaved like  a cartel and  priced their residual oil  to capture

the transportation  and other costs  of getting oil  from sources

outside the  local ports,  it has  not done  so here  and it  has

failed  to produce evidence  sufficient for a  reasonable jury to

infer that such  was the case.   In short, Coastal has  not shown

that CAPECO  had monopoly  power over the  relevant market.   Cf.
                                                                           

Zoslaw  v. MCA  Distrib. Corp.,  693 F.2d  870, 886-87  (9th Cir.
                                        

1982) (secondary-line price  discrimination under Robinson-Patman

Act does not  necessarily violate Sherman Act), cert. denied, 103
                                                                      

S. Ct. 1777 (1983).  Accordingly, Coastal's monopolization claims

fail  under  both section  2  of the  Sherman  Act and  Title 10,

Section  260  of the  Laws  of  Puerto Rico  and  we reverse  the

monopolization  verdicts.   We note  that  because we  affirm the

price discrimination verdict, the  reversal on the monopolization

theory, by  itself, leaves    unchanged the  amount of  antitrust

damages  awarded, subject to our discussion on damage evidentiary

sufficiency in Part I.D., infra.
                                         

                               -36-
                                         -36-


                     C.  Puerto Rico Law Tort
                               C.  Puerto Rico Law Tort

          CAPECO also challenges the  judgment on Coastal's claim

under 31 L.P.R.A.  5141 ("Article 1802").13   CAPECO claims  that

Coastal  was required  to  allege  and prove  the  elements of  a

recognized  tort, and  failed to  do  so.   According to  CAPECO,

because the Supreme Court of Puerto Rico has recently declined to

rule that violation of an antitrust statute will also necessarily

give  rise to a  violation of Article  1802, the  violation of an

antitrust statute  does not give  rise to a  per se violation  of
                                                             

Article 1802.   See Pressure Vessels of Puerto Rico,  94 JTS 144,
                                                             

*438-39.   Additionally, CAPECO challenges the sufficiency of the

evidence supporting the judgment on  this issue.  CAPECO asks for

a reversal of the verdict on these grounds.

          CAPECO's  arguments may well  have merit.   However, we

need  express no opinion  regarding CAPECO's arguments  as CAPECO

waived them  by  failing  to  object  to  the  jury  instructions

regarding the  Article 1802  claim.  See  Linn v.  Andover Newton
                                                                           

Theological School, Inc., 874  F.2d 1, 5.   These are not  simply
                                  

technical  requirements.    By  failing to  object  to  the  jury

instructions,  CAPECO denied "the judge an opportunity to correct

his  error," assuming that CAPECO  rightly contends that an error

                    
                              

13  Article 1802 states, in pertinent part, that:

            [a]  person who  by  an  act or  omission
            causes damage to another through fault or
            negligence shall be obliged to repair the
            damage so done.

Id.
             

                               -37-
                                         -37-


was made.  Id.  While CAPECO may correctly contend that antitrust
                        

violations  do not  fall within  the scope  of Article  1802, the

district court's jury  instructions were not strictly  limited to

antitrust  offenses.    It  is  entirely  possible that,  had  an

objection been  made, the district  court could have  charged the

jury with antitrust offenses as an Article 1802 ground separately

from  other Article  1802 grounds  that may  have applied  in the

present case.  For example,  it could have charged the jury  with

tortious interference  with contractual  relations, since  CAPECO

may well have intentionally complicated, via its refusal to deal,

Coastal's efforts to meet its obligations to deliver bunker fuel.

See General Office Products Corp. v. A.M. Capen's Sons, Inc., 780
                                                                      

F.2d 1077, 1081 (1st Cir. 1986)  (noting that even in the absence

of  a contract,  liability may  be incurred under  other judicial

principles) (citing General Office Products Corp. v. A.M. Capen's
                                                                           

Sons,  Inc.,  No. 0-84-278,  Trans.  Op.  at  6-7 (P.R.  June 29,
                     

1984)).   By failing to  object to the instructions  in question,

CAPECO has deprived us  of factual findings that would aid in the

resolution of  these issues.   Because of  the generality  of the

instruction,  we  conclude  that  evidence  existed  of  CAPECO's

possibly tortious conduct  sufficient for the jury  to reasonably

reach the verdict that it did.

          CAPECO also challenges the  sufficiency of the evidence

supporting the Article 1802 findings.  However, CAPECO has waived

review here  of this argument too by failing  to move at any time

for a judgment  as a matter of  law on this ground  under Fed. R.

                               -38-
                                         -38-


Civ.  P. 50(a),  see Wells  Real Estate,  Inc. v.  Greater Lowell
                                                                           

Board  of   Realtors,  850  F.2d   803,  810   (1st  Cir.   1988)
                              

("[a]ppellate review may  be obtained only on the specific ground

stated in the motion for directed verdict").14

          As  a  result  of  CAPECO's  failure  to  preserve  its

arguments for  review on  appeal, we affirm  the judgment  on the

Article 1802 claim.

                D.  Sufficient Evidence on Damages
                          D.  Sufficient Evidence on Damages

          CAPECO also  argues that Coastal's evidence  on damages

was  inadequate as  a matter  of law,  and therefore,  the jury's

verdict  on damages  must  be reversed.    In particular,  CAPECO

argues that, as a new market entrant, Coastal was required to use

the "yardstick" method of estimating damages.

          With respect  to the  issue of  how accurately  damages

must  be  measured, "there  is  a clear  distinction  between the

[relatively high] measure of proof necessary to establish that [a

plaintiff] has  sustained some  damage and  the [relatively  low]

measure of proof necessary to enable the jury to fix the amount."

Story Parchment  Co. v.  Paterson Parchment  Paper Co.,  282 U.S.
                                                                

555, 562 (1931).  In  the antitrust context, "the most elementary

conceptions  of  justice  and  public  policy  require  that  the

wrongdoer shall  bear the risk  of the uncertainty which  his own

                    
                              

14   In 1991, Rule  50 was amended,  and the term  "judgment as a
matter of  law" was adopted  "to refer  to preverdict"  (directed
verdict) and "postverdict" (judgment notwithstanding the verdict)
"motions  with a  terminology that  does not  conceal  the common
identity  of  two   motions  made  at  different   times  in  the
proceeding."  See Fed. R. Civ. P. 50 advisory committee's note.
                           

                               -39-
                                         -39-


wrong has created."  Bigelow v. RKO Radio Pictures, 327 U.S. 251,
                                                            

256  (1946).   Nonetheless,  the  plaintiff  must  still  produce

evidence  from which  the jury  can  make a  just and  reasonable

inference.   Wells Real Estate,  Inc. v. Greater Lowell  Board of
                                                                           

Realtors, 850  F.2d 803, 816  (1st Cir.), cert. denied,  488 U.S.
                                                                

955 (1988).

          Citing Home Placement Service v. The Providence Journal
                                                                           

Co., 819  F.2d 1199 (1st  Cir. 1987), CAPECO argues  that Coastal
             

was  required to  use the yardstick  method for  calculating lost

profits, rather than the "before-and-after" method.  Id. at 1205-
                                                                  

06.   Under  the  yardstick approach,  the plaintiff  attempts to

identify a  firm similar to the plaintiff in all respects but for

the impact of  the antitrust violation.  Hovenkamp    17.6b2.  By

contrast, under the "before-and-after" method, the court looks at

the plaintiff's  business before  the violation occurred,  during

the   violation  period,  and  after  the  violation  ended,  and

estimates  the  amount   by  which  the  violation   reduced  the

plaintiff's profits.  Id.   17.6b1.
                                   

          We conclude  that whether  a yardstick  record must  be

used ultimately  requires an appraisal  of the  reliability of  a

firm's track record,  and the length of that track  record is one

factor to consider.  The plaintiff in Home Placement Services had
                                                                       

operated  as planned  only weeks  before  the alleged  violations

began.  Home Placement Services can best be read as demonstrating
                                         

both  the  type of  situation  in  which  a yardstick  method  is

preferable,  and  the  factors  that should  go  into  a  court's

                               -40-
                                         -40-


evaluation of  the comparability of  the yardstick firm  or firms

with the plaintiff.15

          Ultimately, the  proper method should be  determined by

the district court in accord with the facts of the situation.  In

this case, the district court will have exactly that opportunity,

since  we  must vacate  the  district court's  damages  award and

remand for further  proceedings.  The district court  charged the

jury  with  an  instruction  to find  an  amount  for  "antitrust

damages,"  comprising awards  for both  price discrimination  and

monopolization claims.16   Because we reverse  the monopolization

verdict, if  left to stand,  the jury's  antitrust damages  award

would likely constitute an excessive  recovery.  In coming to its

conclusion, the jury may well  have weighed harms resulting  from

conduct  that  was  pleaded with  respect  to  the monopolization

offense (e.g. refusal  to deal with a customer,  lying, etc.) but
                       

would   have  been  additional  to  harms  resulting  from  price

discrimination, the  claim we  uphold.   Furthermore, were  we to
                    
                              

15   We  note in  passing  that the  plaintiff-appellant in  Home
                                                                           
Placement  Services was challenging the district court's award of
                             
nominal damages and instead  sought damages based on  a yardstick
analysis;  the appeals court  upheld the nominal  damages finding
because the evidence was "not 'sufficient to get the Court beyond
the  guessing  stage.'"   Id.  at 1209  (quoting  William Goldman
                                                                           
Theatres, Inc. v.  Loew's, Inc., 69 F.  Supp. 103, 106 (E.D.  Pa.
                                         
1946), aff'd, 164  F.2d 1021, 1022 (3d Cir.  1947), cert. denied,
                                                                          
334 U.S. 811 (1948)).

16   We understand the  difficult choice that the  district court
faced.   As a  practical matter,  it would  be difficult,  if not
impossible, for a  juror to segregate antitrust damages  due to a
monopolization   offense   but   not   due   to   illegal   price
discrimination  from   antitrust  damages   due  only  to   price
discrimination, where as here, the  facts and conduct involved in
both allegations greatly overlap.  

                               -41-
                                         -41-


allow  the  verdict   to  stand  despite  our   reversal  of  the

monopolization verdict,  there would exist the  strong likelihood

that the jury  had granted Coastal  a duplicative recovery  under

monopolization  and  tort  law,  for injury  caused  by  the same

conduct, such as  refusal to  deal and  lying.   The law  "abhors

duplicative recoveries."   Dopp v.  HTP Corp., 947 F.2d  506, 517
                                                       

(1st  Cir. 1991) (vacating damage award for, among other reasons,

"a  strong  likelihood  that  the  remedies  thus  far  conferred

overlap").  Thus,  we find that the district  court's award rests

on an error  of law.  See  Adams v. Zimmerman, No.  94-2161, slip
                                                       

op. at  17,     F.3d     ,    , (1st  Cir. 1996) (stating  that a

"district court's award  is reviewed for  an abuse of  discretion

unless it  relies on  an erroneous legal  determination").   As a

result, we must vacate the antitrust damage award of $4.5 million

($1.5 million trebled), and remand for further proceedings.

                  II.  Arguments for a New Trial
                            II.  Arguments for a New Trial

          In  addition to  its  arguments  for  reversal  of  the

district  court's  findings, CAPECO  makes several  arguments for

reversal of the district court's  denial of its motion for a  new

trial.

          "The authority to  grant a new trial . .  . is confided

almost entirely to the exercise of discretion on the  part of the

trial court."   Allied Chem. Corp. v. Daiflon, Inc., 449 U.S. 33,
                                                             

36 (1980), cited in Wells Real Estate, Inc. v. Greater Lowell Bd.
                                                                           

of Realtors,  850 F.2d 803, 810 (1st Cir.  1988).  "Only abuse of
                     

discretion will trigger  reversal of a denial of a motion for new

                               -42-
                                         -42-


trial."  Vel zquez  v. Figueroa-G mez, 996 F.2d  425, 427 (1993).
                                               

In reviewing for  abuse of discretion, we must bear  in mind that

the  trial court's discretion is quite limited concerning motions

for new trials.  "A trial judge may not upset the  jury's verdict

merely   because  he   or  she   would  have  decided   the  case

differently."  Id.
                            

                     A.  Duplicative Judgment
                               A.  Duplicative Judgment

          In  support of  its  request for  a  new trial,  CAPECO

argues  that  the  damages awards  constituted  an  impermissible

double recovery.   CAPECO contends that both  Coastal's antitrust

and tort claims were grounded in  the same set of acts.   Because

we  vacate and remand the  antitrust damages for further findings

on price  discrimination damages, we  construe CAPECO's  argument

that price  discrimination  and  tort  damages  would  constitute

duplicative damage recoveries,   see Borden  v. Paul Revere  Life
                                                                           

Ins. Co., 935 F.2d 370, 382 (1st  Cir. 1991) ("recovery against a
                  

defendant  under  one  tort   theory  precludes  any  duplicative

recovery for the same damages under some other tort theory"), and

so a new trial or remittitur is required, see Dopp v.  HTP Corp.,
                                                                          

947 F.2d 506, 516 (1st Cir. 1991).

          We  reject this  argument for  three  reasons.   First,

CAPECO failed  to object to  the form or  content of  the special

interrogatories to which the  jury answered.  Second, CAPECO  may

well have  waived its right  to raise  this issue here,  since it

failed to  raise the  issue  in a  timely manner  with the  trial

court.  Previously, we have held  that a defendant may not  argue

                               -43-
                                         -43-


verdict inconsistency  if he or  she failed to object  "after the

verdict  was read  and  before  the jury  was  discharged."   See
                                                                           

McIsaac v. Didriksen  Fishing Corp., 809 F.2d 129,  134 (1st Cir.
                                             

1987).  This  rule is grounded in the realization that "to decide

otherwise   would   countenance    'agreeable   acquiescence   to

perceivable  error  as a  weapon  of appellate  advocacy.'"   Id.
                                                                           

(quoting Merchant  v. Ruhle,  740 F.2d 86,  92 (1st  Cir. 1984)).
                                     

The same  concern should make  us hesitate to  consider arguments

about verdict redundancy that were similarly not put forth below.

          Finally, "[a] special  verdict will be upheld  if there

is a view of the case which makes the jury's answers consistent."

McIsaac, 809 F.2d  at 133.  As  we have noted above,  Coastal may
                 

have had a  legitimate Article 1802 claim apart  from any overlap

with antitrust law.  Had CAPECO chosen to object to  the district

court's  instructions, the district court may have corrected this

problem.  Accordingly,  giving the district court the  benefit of

the doubt, had  it responded to a timely  objection by CAPECO and

given  an  Article 1802  instruction  that did  not  overlap with

antitrust  claims,  the  jury's  damages  verdicts  on  tort  and

antitrust  claims could  have been  consistent.   Even  assuming,

arguendo,   that  CAPECO  correctly  asserts  that  such  overlap
                  

occurred,  to grant  CAPECO  a new  trial  now  on the  basis  of

duplicative recovery  would allow it  to avoid the result  of its

own failure to object to the Article 1802 instruction.

                       B.  CAPECO's Experts
                                 B.  CAPECO's Experts

                               -44-
                                         -44-


          Additionally, CAPECO  argues that the  district court's

refusal to allow its two experts, Dr. Jorge Freyre ("Dr. Freyre")

and  Dr. El as Guti rrez ("Dr.  Guti rrez"), to testify was based

on a fundamental error of law and was an abuse of discretion that

requires  that we  reverse the  district  court and  order a  new

trial.

          In  order  to evaluate  CAPECO's  contentions, we  must

review the district court's orders leading up to the exclusion of

the  relevant  testimony.   The  district court's  June  22, 1993

Scheduling Order  stated that  "[t]he parties  will announce  the

names and  qualifications of their  experts by October  1, 1993."

This  date was  modified subsequently  to December  1, 1993.   In

compliance  with   this  order,  CAPECO   named  C sar   Figueroa

("Figueroa")    and    Rafael    Mart nez-Margarida   ("Mart nez-

Margarida").   On March  1, 1994,  pursuant to  a  motion by  new

counsel for Caribbean,  the district court modified  the previous

order and issued a revised  scheduling order stating "all experts

are to be announced by March 30," and also specifying that expert

reports to be used "during each party's case-in-chief" were to be

exchanged on June 3, 1994,  and that expert rebuttal reports were

to be exchanged  on July 1, 1994.   Upon CAPECO's June  1 motion,

the date for reports to be exchanged was extended  by an "Omnibus

Order" to  ten days after service of that order, dated August 15,

1994.   On August  29, 1994, Coastal  delivered to  CAPECO expert

reports  prepared by  Dr. Sherwin  and  Dr. Zalacain, and  CAPECO

provided  Coastal with  an expert  report  prepared by  Figueroa.

                               -45-
                                         -45-


These  experts were deposed between September 9 and September 14,

and  thereafter  CAPECO  retained  experts  Dr.  Freyre  and  Dr.

Guti rrez ostensibly as  rebuttal witnesses under Fed. R. Civ. P.

26(a)(2)(C).  CAPECO informed Coastal on September 20, 1994, that

it had retained  Dr. Freyre as a rebuttal  witness, and similarly

informed Coastal  of Dr. Guti rrez  on or about October  4, 1994.

CAPECO informed  the  district court  about  Dr. Freyre  and  Dr.

Guti rrez on October 5, 1995.

          The  district  court   instructed  CAPECO  to   produce

Dr. Freyre  and Dr.  Guti rrez  and to  make  them available  for

depositions.  On  October 5 and October 6,  Coastal filed motions

in limine to  exclude Dr. Freyre and Dr. Guti rrez, respectively,

on   the  theory   that  neither   witness   could  properly   be

characterized as  a "rebuttal" witness within the meaning of Rule

26(a)(2)(C), and thus both should have been disclosed previously.

After  oral argument, the district court granted Coastal's motion

and excluded the testimony of  Dr. Freyre and Dr. Guti rrez.  The

district court, upon  CAPECO's admission that  it planned to  use

Dr. Freyre  and Dr. Guti rrez  in its  case-in-chief, noted  that

"you got a problem  with my orders because you  have not complied

with my orders  insofar as Freyre and Guti rrez [are] concerned,"

apparently referring  to the  previous scheduling order  deadline

for experts in the case-in-chief to be disclosed.

          CAPECO  argues (1) that  because the Omnibus  Order did

not  provide  a deadline  for  the  exchange  of rebuttal  expert

reports,   no  scheduling  order   applied,  and   therefore  the

                               -46-
                                         -46-


disclosure of Dr. Freyre and Dr. Guti rrez was controlled by Rule

26(a)(2)(C);17  and (2) that the district court misconstrued Rule

26(a)(2)(C) to signify that a defendant cannot offer testimony to

"contradict  or  rebut"  under  Rule 26(a)(2)(C).    We  need not

consider whether  the district  court in  fact misconstrued  Rule

26(a)(2)(C),  because,  for three  reasons, we  find no  abuse of

discretion  in its  exclusion  of  these  witnesses  as  rebuttal

witnesses.  First, at no time  did CAPECO ever seek leave of  the

court  to  announce  the  names  of  experts  not  disclosed   by

December 1, 1993, as  originally required, or by  March 30, 1994,

as  permitted by  the  trial court.   CAPECO's  motion of  June 1

sought extension  principally  due to  alleged noncooperation  by

Coastal  in discovery, making CAPECO's experts' task difficult to

complete by the deadline then in effect.  We cannot  conclude, as

CAPECO  does, that  the Omnibus  Order's  extension rendered  all

other  orders unbinding.   Because  CAPECO  did not  ask for  its

extension on the grounds it  now argues, the district court could

not  have  had  such an  effect  in  mind, nor  was  it  given an

opportunity to consider such effect.   A trial court may "readily

exclude a  witness or exhibit  if some previous  order had set  a

deadline  for  identification and  the  proponent [has],  without

adequate excuse, failed  to list the witness or  exhibit."  Fusco
                                                                           

                    
                              

17    Rule  26's   schedule  concerning  the  duty   to  disclose
information concerning expert witnesses and their opinions may be
altered by  the court.  See Fed.  R. Civ. P. 26(a)(2)(C) (setting
                                     
forth  schedule of  disclosure  of  expert  testimony  "[i]n  the
absence of other directions from  the court or stipulation by the
parties").

                               -47-
                                         -47-


v. General  Motors Corp., 11 F.3d  259, 265 (1st  Cir. 1993); see
                                                                           

also Freund  v. Fleetwood  Enter., Inc., 956  F.2d 354  (1st Cir.
                                                 

1992).

          Additionally, we cannot agree that the district court's

March 1, 1994, Scheduling Order was necessarily superceded, given

that  that order  scheduled trial  for October  24, 1994,  and in

fact, trial began on  that date.  The  proximity in time  between

CAPECO's attempts  to bring in  Dr. Freyre and Dr.  Guti rrez and

actual trial casts doubt on  any argument that CAPECO was somehow

misled  into thinking  that previous  Scheduling  Orders did  not

apply.   Finally, even assuming  that CAPECO is correct  that the

Scheduling Order's  provisions regarding  rebuttal witnesses  had

been superceded and  thus Rule 26(a)(2)(B) applied,  the district

court  might still have enforced its previous deadlines regarding

experts in the case-in-chief.  For  better or for worse, at  oral

argument  on October  21, 1994  (three days  before trial  was to

start),   counsel  for  CAPECO  identified  Dr.  Freyre  and  Dr.

Guti rrez as witnesses in its case-in-chief.18

          Given  the circumstances, we  cannot conclude  that the

exclusion of the testimony of Dr. Freyre and Dr. Guti rrez was an

abuse of discretion warranting a new trial.

             C.  CAPECO's Meeting Competition Defense
                       C.  CAPECO's Meeting Competition Defense

                    
                              

18  At  one point in the  oral argument over Coastal's  motion in
limine to exclude  Dr. Freyre and Dr. Guti rrez,  the court asked
"And  when are  you  going to  bring  them?"   To  this question,
counsel  for CAPECO  directly  responded, "We  are  going to  use
[them] in our case [in] chief."

                               -48-
                                         -48-


          CAPECO  also argues that the district court should have

given jury  instructions on  the affirmative  defense of  meeting

competition.   Section  2(b) of  Clayton Act,  as amended  by the

Robinson-Patman Act, permits a defendant  to rebut a prima  facie
                                                                           

case of violation  by showing that its  lower price "was made  in

good faith to  meet an equally  low price of  a competitor."   15

U.S.C.    13(b).  The "meeting competition" defense can be raised

only  by a defendant  who responds in good  faith to the believed

lower  price of  a competitor.   United  States v.  United States
                                                                           

Gypsum Co.,  438 U.S. 422  (1978), appeal after remand,  600 F.2d
                                                                

414 (3d Cir. 1979), cert. denied, 444 U.S. 884 (1979).
                                          

          We need not consider CAPECO's argument that it believed

in  good faith  that it  was responding  to a  competitive threat

posed by Coastal in combination  with its parent CFMI, because we

conclude that even  assuming that Coastal and CFMI  were a single

entity, they do not constitute  a competitor in the same specific

area as CAPECO, see Falls City, 460 U.S.  at 448.  In Falls City,
                                                                          

the  Supreme Court concluded  that Congress intended  the meeting

competition  defense "to allow reasonable pricing responses on an

area-specific  basis  where   competitive  circumstances  warrant

them."   Id. at 448.   Here, the district court  could reasonably
                      

conclude  that the defense did not  apply, since there was a lack

of  evidence, beyond CAPECO's own employees' testimony about what

they believed to  be the case, that CFMI offered  lower prices on

bunker fuel in San Juan than CAPECO.  See Rose  Confections, Inc.
                                                                           

v. Ambrosia Chocolate  Co., 816 F.2d 381, 391-93  (8th Cir. 1987)
                                    

                               -49-
                                         -49-


(ruling  defense rejected where  seller relied on  "assumption or

speculation" without  verification that competitor's  prices were

in fact lower).  Therefore, we do not find abuse of discretion in

the district court's denial of a  new trial based on its  refusal

to issue a jury instruction on the meeting competition defense.

          D.  CAPECO's Puerto Rico Law Tort Counterclaim
                    D.  CAPECO's Puerto Rico Law Tort Counterclaim

          CAPECO  contends  that  the  district  court  erred  in

dismissing its counterclaim grounded in Article 1802, 31 L.P.R.A.

  5141.  According  to CAPECO, it  was a compulsory  counterclaim

and was thus  not barred by the one year  statute of limitations,

at least to the extent of defeating the main claim.

          We reject CAPECO's argument for two reasons.  First, in

opposition  to Coastal's  motion  for  summary  judgment  on  the

counterclaim,  it failed  to  inform the  district  court of  the

theory  it  now  advances,  that  it is  entitled  to  recoupment

notwithstanding the  statute of  limitations.   Additionally, the

gist of CAPECO's counterclaim argument  was that the threat posed

by Coastal and CFMI allegedly working in concert forced CAPECO to

give Harbor  and  Caribbean discounts,  costing CAPECO  potential

profits.  Given that we  uphold the district court's finding that

these  discounts were illegal price discrimination, it appears at

least doubtful under Puerto Rico  law that CAPECO can collect for

any lost profits thereby incurred.  See, e.g., Rubio-Sacarello v.
                                                                        

Roig,  84 D.P.R.  344, 351  (P.R. 1962)  (stating, in  a contract
              

context, that  one who  is guilty of  illegality cannot  bring an

action).  As a result, we fail to find abuse of discretion by the

                               -50-
                                         -50-


district court  in its decision not to grant  a new trial on this

basis.

                            CONCLUSION
                                      CONCLUSION
                                                

          Coastal   succeeded  below   on  three   claims:  price

discrimination, monopolization  and  tort.   CAPECO's failure  to

make the points below that it now argues on appeal hamstrung  its

attempt to obtain  reversal of the price discrimination  and tort

claims.  But  the definition of relevant  market Coastal espoused

could  not  be  reasonably  adopted  by  the  jury,  since   this

definition  was legally insufficient in neglecting to account for

downstream constraints on  the proposed monopoly, and  in failing

to draw on  sufficient evidence regarding those constraints.

          For the foregoing reasons, the judgment of the district

court is affirmed in part, reversed in part, and remanded.
                                                                   

                               -51-
                                         -51-