Legal Research AI

Milk Industry Foundation v. Glickman

Court: Court of Appeals for the D.C. Circuit
Date filed: 1998-01-20
Citations: 132 F.3d 1467, 328 U.S. App. D.C. 121
Copy Citations
13 Citing Cases
Combined Opinion
                        United States Court of Appeals


                     FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT


              Argued November 20, 1997 Decided January 20, 1998 


                                 No. 97-5163


                          Milk Industry Foundation, 

                                  Appellant 


                                      v.


                       Daniel R. Glickman, Secretary, 

                 United States Department of Agriculture and 

                     Northeast Dairy Compact Commission, 

                                  Appellees


                Appeals from the United States District Court 

                        for the District of Columbia 

                               (No. 96cv02027)


     Steven J. Rosenbaum argued the cause for appellant, with 
whom Jonathon C. Drimmer and Jason A. Levine were on 
the briefs.

     Douglas N. Letter, Appellate Litigation Counsel, U.S. De-
partment of Justice, argued the cause for appellee Daniel R. 



Glickman, Secretary, United States Department of Agricul-
ture, with whom Frank W. Hunger, Assistant Attorney Gen-
eral, Mary Lou Leary, U.S. Attorney, and Stephen W. Pres-
ton, Deputy Assistant Attorney General, U.S. Department of 
Justice, were on the brief.

     Clifford M. Sloan argued the cause for appellee Northeast 
Dairy Compact Commission, with whom Michael A. Rotker 
was on the brief.

     Paul A. Strandberg, Assistant Attorney General, State of 
Minnesota, was on the brief for amici curiae States of Minne-
sota, Wisconsin, and South Dakota.

     Emily J. Gould, Assistant Attorney General, State of Ver-
mont, was on the brief for amici curiae State of Connecticut, 
et al.

     Eric Rome was on the brief for amici curiae Public Voice 
for Food and Health Policy, et al.

     Roy J. Rodney, Jr. and Endya E. Delpit were on the brief 
for amici curiae Commissioners of the Louisiana, Arkansas, 
Georgia, South Carolina and West Virginia Departments of 
Agriculture.

     Before:  Edwards, Chief Judge, Henderson, and Rogers, 
Circuit Judges.

     Opinion for the Court filed by Chief Judge Edwards.

     Concurring opinion filed by Circuit Judge Rogers with 
whom Circuit Judge Henderson concurs.

     Edwards, Chief Judge:  In 1993, the six New England 
states--Connecticut, Maine, Massachusetts, New Hampshire, 
Rhode Island, and Vermont ("Compact states")--agreed to 
form the Northeast Interstate Dairy Compact ("Compact") to 
enable them to raise the minimum milk prices that dairy 
processors must pay to dairy farmers in their region for milk 
processed and consumed in fluid form ("farm-gate prices").  
The Constitution provides that "[n]o State shall, without the 
Consent of Congress, ... enter into any Agreement or Com-
pact with another State...."  U.S. Const. art. I, s 10, cl. 3 
("compact consent clause").  Congress purported to consent 
to the Compact with the passage of the Federal Agricultural 



Improvement and Reform Act of 1996 ("FAIRA") s 147, 7 
U.S.C. s 7256 (Supp. 1996).  Congress conditioned its consent 
on a finding of a "compelling public interest" by the Secretary 
of Agriculture ("Secretary").

     Appellant, the Milk Industry Foundation, contends that 
Congress did not "consent" to the Compact but instead 
impermissibly delegated this constitutional responsibility to 
the Secretary.  Appellant also claims that even assuming, 
arguendo, that the delegation was lawful, the Secretary exer-
cised his delegated authority arbitrarily and capriciously in 
violation of the Administrative Procedure Act ("APA").

     The congressional action here is not substantially different 
from countless pieces of contingent legislation enacted by 
Congress over the last few decades--including many that 
have been challenged and upheld by the courts.  Appellant 
asserts that the instant delegation is somehow different be-
cause it involves an interstate compact.  This claim is merit-
less.  Furthermore, we have no doubt that, in instructing the 
Secretary to authorize the Compact only upon finding a 
"compelling public interest in the Compact region," Congress 
provided an "intelligible principle" to guide the Secretary's 
exercise of the delegated power.  Accordingly, we hold that 
the delegation is constitutional.

     We also reject Appellant's APA claim.  Evaluating the 
Secretary's finding of a "compelling public interest" within 
the relevant context at issue, we find that he "examine[d] the 
relevant data and articulate[d] a satisfactory explanation for 
[his] action[,] including a rational connection between the 
facts found and the choice made."  Thus his decision is not 
arbitrary and capricious under the APA.  See Motor Vehicle 
Mfrs. Ass'n v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 463 U.S. 29, 
43 (1983) (internal quotations omitted).

                                I. Background 


A.  The National Scheme for the Regulation of Milk Prices 

     Congress initiated the federal program for the regulation of 
farm-gate milk prices with the passage of the Agricultural 



Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 ("AMAA") s 2, 7 U.S.C. 
ss 601-624, 671-674 (1994).  The AMAA delegates the au-
thority to set minimum milk prices nationwide to the Secre-
tary, s 608c(18), while the states retain authority to establish 
milk prices above the federal price floor.  See United Dairy 
Farmers Coop. Ass'n v. Milk Control Comm'n of Pennsylva-
nia, 335 F. Supp. 1008, 1013-15 (M.D. Pa.) (three judge 
court), aff'd without opinion, 404 U.S. 930 (1971).

B.  The Northeast Interstate Dairy Compact 

     In 1988, Vermont initiated an effort to regulate milk prices 
beyond its own state borders by forming an interstate com-
pact with neighboring states.  By 1993, all of the New 
England state legislatures had approved the formation of the 
Northeast Interstate Dairy Compact, and all of the states' 
governors had signed resolutions supporting it.  See Milk 
Indus. Found. v. Glickman, 949 F. Supp. 882, 885 (D.D.C. 
1996) ("MIF I") (explaining history of Compact).  A principal 
objective of the Compact is to preserve dairy farms in the 
Compact states.  See Compact art. I, s 1, reprinted in Ap-
pendix to Brief for Appellee Northeast Dairy Compact Com-
mission.  The Compact states agreed to establish a Commis-
sion consisting of three to five representatives from each 
state, with at least one person from each state being a dairy 
farmer and another a consumer representative, to administer 
the Compact.  Compact art. III, s 4.

     The Compact grants the Commission authority to, among 
other things, establish an "over-order" farm-gate price, a 
price of up to $1.50 per gallon over the federal minimum price 
for milk used for fluid products.  Compact art. IV, s 9.  The 
Compact's voting requirements are designed to ensure that 
the Commission does not pass any over-order prices without 
the broad consensus of the Compact states, both dairy-
producing and dairy-consuming states.  See Compact art.  
III, s 5 (requiring at least two-thirds vote of the delegations 
present to establish or terminate an over-order price);  id.  
("The establishment of a regulated area which covers all or 
part of a participating state shall require also the affirmative 
vote of that state's delegation.").



C.  Congress' Consent to the Compact 

     Congress consented to the Compact with the enactment of 
FAIRA s 147, 7 U.S.C. s 7256 (Supp. 1996).  See MIF I, 949 
F. Supp. at 886-87 (detailing efforts to obtain congressional 
consent to the compact).  Congress' consent to the Compact 
was made subject to a number of conditions and limitations, 
two of which are relevant here.  First, Congress conditioned 
its consent on a finding by the Secretary that the implemen-
tation of the Compact is in the compelling public interest of 
the Compact region.  s 7256.  ("Based upon a finding by the 
Secretary of a compelling public interest in the Compact 
region, the Secretary may grant the States that have ratified 
the Northeast Interstate Dairy Compact ... the authority to 
implement the [ ] Compact.").  Second, Congress limited the 
duration of its consent to the Compact, providing for its 
termination upon the Secretary's implementation of compre-
hensive reforms of the federal scheme for regulating milk 
prices mandated by FAIRA.  See id. (providing that Con-
gress' consent "shall terminate concurrent with the Secre-
tary's implementation" of pending reforms to the federal 
milk-pricing scheme); see also 7 U.S.C. s 7253 (Supp. 1996) 
(mandating the consolidation and reform of the federal milk-
pricing scheme not later than April 4, 1999).

D. The Secretary's Findings and Appellant's Challenges to 
the Compact 

     On August 28, 1996, the Secretary published a two-
sentence finding of a compelling public interest and autho-
rized the Compact states to implement the Compact.  61 Fed. 
Reg. 44,290 (1996) ("Initial Finding").  Appellant promptly 
filed a motion in the District Court for the District of 
Columbia for a preliminary injunction to bar the implementa-
tion of the Compact, claiming that section 147 of FAIRA was 
an unconstitutional delegation of legislative power and that 
the Secretary had exercised his delegated authority arbitrari-
ly and capriciously in violation of the APA.

     Following the District Court's denial of Appellant's motion 
for a preliminary injunction, the Secretary moved to stay 



proceedings so that he could review the entire administrative 
record and provide an amplified decision justifying his finding 
of a compelling public interest.  The District Court granted 
this motion, instructing the Secretary to hold open the possi-
bility of reaching a contrary conclusion upon reexamination of 
the record.  Milk Indus. Found. v. Glickman, 955 F. Supp. 8, 
9 (D.D.C. 1997).

     The Secretary issued a second decision on March 28, 1997, 
again finding a compelling public interest in the Compact 
region warranting authorization of the Compact.  62 Fed. 
Reg. 14,879 (1997) ("Amplified Decision").  In reaching his 
decision, the Secretary emphasized the importance of taking 
"reasonable measures to preserve small family farms," noting 
that "America wants and still needs the family farm.  This 
belief is obviously strongly held by the people of the Compact 
region."  Id. at 14,879-80 (finding that "small dairy farms are 
an essential part of the character and culture in the Compact 
region").  The Secretary also noted that the Compact is a 
short-term measure which will expire upon the completion of 
the pending reform of the federal milk-pricing scheme.  Id. at 
14,880.  The Secretary found that the Compact likely would 
result in higher milk prices and therefore, at least in the 
short-term, provide higher profitability for, and decrease 
financial pressures on, family-sized dairy farms in New Eng-
land.  Id. at 14,879.  After noting his countervailing concern 
over the Compact's potential to increase the cost of milk for 
low-income families, the Secretary concluded that there is a 
compelling public interest in the Compact region in favor of 
authorizing the Compact, stating that, "the balance has been 
properly struck, given current conditions.  The Compact is a 
short-term measure that, if implemented with common sense 
and sensitivity to the needs of all affected persons and 
interests, can benefit the dairy producers and all citizens in 
the Compact region without producing adverse side effects."  
Id. at 14,880.

     At the time the Secretary published his Initial Finding, he 
also published a statement saying that he was "concerned 
about potential effects of the Compact in several respects" 
and that he would revoke his authorization if he determined 



that conditions warranted revocation.  61 Fed. Reg. at 44,291.  
Likewise, in his Amplified Decision, the Secretary maintained 
that he would revoke authorization if he determined that 
changing conditions in the Compact region warranted such 
action.  62 Fed. Reg. at 14,880.  However, in an addendum to 
his Amplified Decision, the Secretary retreated from this 
position.  62 Fed. Reg. 16,539 (1997) ("Addendum").

     Following issuance of the Secretary's Amplified Decision, 
the parties cross-moved for summary judgment.  The District 
Court granted Appellees' summary judgment motion and 
denied Appellant's summary judgment motion.  Milk Indus.  
Found. v. Glickman, 967 F. Supp. 564 (D.D.C. 1997) ("MIF 
II").

                                II. Analysis 


     We review the District Court's grant of summary judgment 
de novo.  See Tao v. Freeh, 27 F.3d 635, 638 (D.C. Cir. 1994);  
see also Dr Pepper/Seven-Up Cos. v. FTC, 991 F.2d 859, 862 
(D.C. Cir. 1993) ("Where the decision under review is the 
district court's assessment of the legal sufficiency of an 
agency's action in light of the record, ... [w]e proceed as if 
the Commission's decision had been appealed to this court 
directly," notwithstanding the intervening step; the district 
court's decision is not entitled to any particular deference) 
(internal quotations and citations omitted).  On the APA 
claim, our review of the Secretary's finding is deferential.  
See State Farm, 463 U.S. at 43 ("The scope of review under 
the 'arbitrary and capricious' standard is narrow and a court 
is not to substitute its judgment for that of the agency.").

A.  Congress' Contingent Consent Was a Lawful Delegation 

     In Field v. Clark, 143 U.S. 649 (1892), the Supreme Court 
articulated what has come to be known as the "delegation 
doctrine."  However, since Field, the Court has invalidated 
statutes on grounds of unlawful delegations on only two 
occasions, both of which occurred prior to the full develop-
ment of the regulatory state ushered in by the New Deal.  
See A.L.A. Schecter Poultry Corp. v. United States, 295 U.S. 



495 (1935); Panama Refining Co. v. Ryan, 293 U.S. 388 
(1935).  In recent decades, it has become widely accepted that 
Congress may, as a general matter, confer substantial author-
ity upon a coordinate branch of government, as long as it 
provides an "intelligible principle" to guide the delegatee's 
exercise of the power conferred.  See, e.g., Mistretta v. Unit-
ed States, 488 U.S. 361, 372 (1989).

     1. The Power Delegated was Delegable Power

     In the instant case, Congress made its consent contingent 
upon a finding by the Secretary that the Compact was in the 
compelling public interest of the Compact region.  This act of 
contingent legislation is not substantially different from 
countless pieces of legislation passed by Congress over the 
last several decades--including many which have been chal-
lenged under the delegation doctrine and found to be consti-
tutional by reviewing courts.  We are unpersuaded by Appel-
lant's efforts to distinguish the delegation in this case, on the 
grounds of both the nature of the legislative power delegated 
and the extent of executive action involved, from delegations 
that have been upheld as constitutional.

     Appellant argues that consent to the Compact does not 
entail on-going administration of a regulatory scheme by the 
Executive Branch, on the assumption that this matters.  
However, precedent does not support Appellant's suggestion 
that contingent legislation is permissible only when associated 
with the administration of an on-going regulatory scheme.  
Rather, the Supreme Court has adopted the "general rule" 
that " '[a] constitutional power implies a power of delegation 
of authority under it sufficient to effect its purposes.' "  Lov-
ing v. United States, 116 S. Ct. 1737, 1748 (1996) (quoting 
Lichter v. United States, 334 U.S. 742, 778 (1948) (alteration 
in original)).  See also Yakus v. United States, 321 U.S. 414, 
425-26 (1944) ("Congress is not confined to that method of 
executing policy which involves the least possible delegation 
of discretion to administrative officers.").

     The Court frequently has upheld Congress' delegation of 
responsibilities to the Executive through contingent legisla-
tion requiring an executive agent to take some action upon 



the finding of specified conditions.  For example, in upholding 
Congress' delegation to the Price Administrator to fix com-
modity prices that would be fair and equitable and would 
effectuate the purposes of the Emergency Price Control Act 
of 1942, the Court stated:

     The essentials of the legislative function are the determi-
     nation of the legislative policy and its formulation and 
     promulgation as a defined and binding rule of con-
     duct....  These essentials are preserved when Congress 
     has specified the basic conditions of fact upon whose 
     existence or occurrence, ascertained from relevant data 
     by a designated administrative agency, it directs that its 
     statutory command shall be effective.

Yakus, 321 U.S. at 424-25.  Thus, the relevant distinction 
between the legislative and the executive is one of function, 
not of frequency.  See Loving, 116 S. Ct. at 1744 (" 'The true 
distinction ... is between the delegation of power to make 
the law, which necessarily involves a discretion as to what it 
shall be, and conferring authority or discretion as to its 
execution, to be exercised under and in pursuance of the law.  
This first cannot be done; to the latter no objection can be 
made.' ") (quoting Field, 143 U.S. at 693-94) (alteration in 
original).

     In any case, the Secretary's delegated role here is consis-
tent with the Secretary's role in the regulation of milk prices 
nationwide.  In this instance, the Secretary was not asked to 
regulate milk prices directly.  Instead, he was asked to 
determine whether permitting the Compact Commission to 
override the national minimum price for milk, in the case of 
the Compact states pending reform of the federal milk-
pricing scheme, would be in the compelling public interest of 
the Compact region.  This question implicates the Secretary's 
administrative role in regulating milk prices.

     Appellant asserts that congressional consent to interstate 
compacts must be "effective of its own force, with no role for 
the Executive," Brief for Appellant at 11, but fails to offer 
any compelling reason why the compact consent clause should 
be understood differently from Congress' other Article I 



powers for the purposes of the delegation doctrine.  Cf. 
Loving, 116 S. Ct. at 1748 (Congress' power to "make Rules 
for the Government and Regulation of the land and naval 
forces" pursuant to U.S. Const. art. I, s 8, cl. 14 ("Clause 14") 
"is no less plenary than other Article I powers") (citations 
omitted).  If, as the Court held in Loving, Congress can 
lawfully delegate the power to define crimes--a power which 
is arguably at the height of that which might be defined as 
legislative--then surely it can lawfully delegate to the Secre-
tary the power to authorize an interstate compact upon the 
finding that the Compact would serve a compelling public 
interest in the Compact region.  Although it may still be 
possible to posit hypothetical instances of delegations which 
might be found unlawful, we are unconvinced that this is such 
an instance.

     Appellant notes that, in Loving, the Court observed at 
length that the Executive has traditionally played a signifi-
cant role in the regulation of the military, see id. at 1744-48, 
thus suggesting that Loving should not be viewed as a 
weighty precedent in this case.  There is nothing in the 
Loving opinion that we can find, however, indicating that this 
historical fact is a limiting principle governing application of 
the delegation doctrine.  Indeed, such a reading of Loving 
would conflict with previous statements of the Court.  See, 
e.g., Mistretta, 488 U.S. at 385 ("Our constitutional principles 
of separated powers are not violated ... by mere anomaly or 
innovation.").  Rather, it appears that the Loving Court 
examined the historical practice of England as a tool for 
ascertaining the Framers' intent in drafting Clause 14.  See 
Loving, 116 S. Ct. at 1747 ("... the Framers knew well this 
history ...").  In addition, the Court emphasized the lack of 
any clear and "absolute rule against" the delegation at issue 
in Loving.  See id. at 1748.  Although Appellant maintains 
that the delegation at issue here is a novelty, it fails to 
identify any clear and absolute rule against such a delegation.



     2.  The Delegation Was Governed by an Intelligible 
         Principle

     Where the power at issue is a delegable power, Congress 
may provide discretionary authority to a coordinate branch of 
government "[s]o long as Congress 'lay[s] down by legislative 
act an intelligible principle to which the person or body 
authorized to [exercise the delegated authority] is directed to 
conform.' "  Mistretta, 488 U.S. at 372 (quoting J.W. Hamp-
ton, Jr., & Co. v. United States, 276 U.S. 394, 406 (1928) 
(second alteration in original)).  Applying this general rule 
over the last several decades, the Supreme Court has upheld, 
"without deviation, Congress' ability to delegate power under 
broad standards," id. at 373, including delegations authorizing 
the Executive to take action upon finding that it would be in 
the "public interest" to do so.  See, e.g., National Broadcast-
ing Co. v. United States, 319 U.S. 190, 225-26 (1943) (uphold-
ing delegation to FCC to regulate broadcast licensing in the 
"public interest"); New York Cent. Sec. Corp. v. United 
States, 287 U.S. 12, 24 (1932) (upholding delegation to ICC to 
authorize the consolidation of carriers where it finds that such 
consolidation would be in "the public interest");  see also 
Yakus, 321 U.S. at 425 ("It is no objection [under the delega-
tion doctrine] that the determination of facts and the infer-
ences to be drawn from them in the light of the statutory 
standards and declaration of policy call for [the delegated 
agent's] judgment, and for the formulation of subsidiary 
administrative policy within the prescribed statutory frame-
work.") (citations omitted).

     The "compelling public interest in the Compact region" 
standard falls well within established "intelligible principle" 
parameters.  Indeed, Appellant's arguments in support of its 
APA claim convincingly demonstrate that the "compelling 
public interest" standard is discernible and demanding.  In 
advancing this argument, Appellant has no difficulty--nor do 
we--in defining the scope of the "compelling public interest" 
standard.

B.  The Secretary's Finding Was Not Arbitrary and 
    Capricious

     Congress' requirement that the Compact can only be au-
thorized upon a finding of a compelling public interest in the 



Compact region provides a demanding standard requiring 
that the data and reasoning justifying the Secretary's finding 
weigh heavily in favor of authorizing the Compact.  We find 
that the Secretary's Amplified Decision meets this standard.

     1.  The Secretary's Finding is "Agency Action" Reviewable 
         Under the APA

     As a threshold matter, the Secretary argues that his find-
ing is not "agency action" reviewable under the APA, but 
rather "merely [a] determin[ation] that conditions in the 
Compact region met the condition set by Congress for imple-
mentation of the Compact."  Brief for Appellee Secretary at 
30.  This is a distinction without a difference.  The APA 
defines "agency action" to include agency rules, see 5 U.S.C. 
s 551(13), and defines an agency "rule" as "the whole or a 
part of an agency statement of general or particular applica-
bility and future effect designed to implement, interpret, or 
prescribe law or policy...."  5 U.S.C. s 551(4).  The Secre-
tary neither disputes that the APA's procedural requirements 
for informal rulemaking were satisfied, see 5 U.S.C. s 553, 
nor explains why his Amplified Decision should not be under-
stood as a rule implementing congressional policy.  We see no 
meaningful distinction between the delegation at issue here 
and the many acts of contingent legislation passed by Con-
gress over recent decades.  Through such contingent legisla-
tion, Congress enacts a policy (in this case, consent to the 
Compact), which is to be implemented upon the Executive's 
finding of the conditions specified by Congress (in this case, a 
"compelling public interest in the Compact region").  Clearly, 
the Secretary's finding and his corresponding authorization of 
the Compact is a rule reviewable under the APA's "arbitrary 
and capricious" standard.

     2.The Secretary's Finding of a Compelling Public Inter-
       est in the Compact Region is Not Arbitrary and Capri-
       cious

     Under familiar and well-established principles, the Secre-
tary's finding must be upheld as long as the Secretary 
"examine[d] the relevant data and articulate[d] a satisfactory 
explanation for its action including a 'rational connection 
between the facts found and the choice made.' "  State Farm, 



463 U.S. at 43 (quoting Burlington Truck Lines, Inc. v. 
United States, 371 U.S. 156, 168 (1962)); Republican Nat'l 
Comm. v. Fed. Election Comm'n, 76 F.3d 400, 407 (D.C. Cir. 
1996) (APA's arbitrary and capricious standard of review is 
"satisfied if the agency enables us to see what major issues of 
policy were ventilated ... and why the agency reacted to 
them as it did") (internal quotations omitted), cert. denied, 
117 S. Ct. 682 (1997).  To meet this standard, the factors 
undergirding the Secretary's finding must be appropriate to 
the relevant context.  In the instant case, four aspects of the 
relevant context are particularly noteworthy.

     First, the Secretary was required to find a compelling 
public interest in the Compact region.  See 7 U.S.C. s 7256 
(Supp. 1996).  Thus, contrary to Appellant's arguments, how 
the situation of dairy farmers in New England compares to 
that of dairy farmers in the remainder of the country is 
largely irrelevant.  Rather, an appropriate inquiry must focus 
on the Compact region measured in absolute, not relative, 
terms.

     Second, it is significant here that Congress' consent to the 
Compact is for a very limited duration.  Consent expires 
upon the completion of pending reforms of the federal scheme 
for regulating milk prices nationwide, rendering the Compact 
a transitional, interim measure.  See id. (providing that Con-
gress' consent "shall terminate concurrent with the Secre-
tary's implementation of the dairy pricing and Federal milk 
marketing order consolidation and reforms under section 7253 
of this title").

     Third, it is also important to bear in mind that, under the 
disputed legislation, the Secretary is not authorized to imple-
ment any particular regulatory measure, but, rather, to deter-
mine whether the Compact Commission should be allowed to 
regulate milk prices in the Compact region.  Appellant ar-
gues that the Secretary erred in failing to give due weight to 
the possibility that increased milk prices might burden low-
income families in the Compact region.  However, any 
"weighing" of this factor must take into account the gover-
nance structure of the Commission, for it will be the Commis-



sion's actions, not the Secretary's, that will affect consumer 
prices.  Significantly, the Commission is composed of equal 
numbers of representatives from each Compact state--those 
which are primarily dairy-consuming states as well as those 
which are primarily dairy-producing states.  Compact art.  
III, s 4.  In addition, at least one representative from each 
state must be a consumer representative, id., a two-thirds 
vote of the Commission is required to raise farm-gate prices, 
and each state is subject to a Compact regulation increasing 
farm-gate prices only if the state's delegation votes for the 
measure.  Compact art. III, s 5.

     Finally, the record clearly identifies a strong consensus 
within the Compact states that the preservation of family 
dairy farms is of vital importance to the region's economic 
and environmental interests in a number of ways.  Thus, 
although the availability of a sufficient supply of milk from 
large-scale farmers--even in the event that local family farm-
ers go out of business--is a relevant inquiry in assessing 
whether there is a compelling public interest, it must be 
balanced against this countervailing factor of a strong region-
al desire to maintain family dairy farms.

     Within this overall context, the Secretary's finding of a 
compelling public interest within the Compact region was 
reasonably supported by the following key factors:  (1) a 
principal objective of the Compact is to preserve family farms 
in the Compact region; (2) family dairy farmers in the region 
are under severe financial stress; and (3) the Compact will 
effectively preserve family dairy farms during the transitional 
period pending reform of the national scheme for regulating 
milk prices, at which time congressional consent will expire.  
These factors, in turn, were reasonably supported by the 
record before the Secretary.  See MIF II, 967 F. Supp. at 571 
n.8 (citing portions of the record supporting key factors relied 
on by the Secretary).

     Prior to this case, the Secretary, in reviewing milk prices 
pursuant to his authority under the AMAA, found that it 
would not be in the public interest to raise farm-gate prices in 
New England.  See 58 Fed. Reg. 12,634 (1993).  Appellant 



argues that this prior decision cannot be squared with the 
decision under attack here.  We disagree.  First, the question 
addressed by the Secretary in the instant case is not whether 
farm-gate prices should be increased, but whether the Com-
pact Commission should be authorized to raise prices during 
the transitional period pending reform of the national price-
regulation scheme.  Notably, the factors relevant to a price 
determination in a federal milk marketing order under the 
AMAA and those considered by the Commission under the 
Compact are not identical.  Compare 7 U.S.C. ss 602, 
608c(18) (1994) with Compact arts. I, IV, ss 1, 9(e), (f).  
Moreover, individual states already possess the authority to 
regulate prices above the AMAA floor.  See United Dairy 
Farmers, 335 F. Supp. at 1013.  In a region in which individ-
ual state regulation is impracticable because of the small 
geographic area and the interrelationships among neighbor-
ing states, the Compact simply gives the New England region 
similar authority.  Thus, permitting state governments to 
collaborate in setting farm-gate prices above the AMAA price 
floor is hardly incompatible with the objectives of the AMAA. 
In any event, even if the Secretary were deciding directly 
whether prices should be raised, it is well-established that he 
would not be bound by his prior decision, so long as the 
decision under review is well-reasoned.  See, e.g., DIRECTV, 
Inc. v. FCC, 110 F.3d 816, 826 (D.C. Cir. 1997);  National 
Audubon Soc'y v. Hester, 801 F.2d 405, 408 (D.C. Cir. 1986).

     Furthermore, the fact that the Secretary considered possi-
ble negative consequences of authorizing the Compact does 
not render his finding invalid; rather, this merely demon-
strates that the Secretary realized that the compelling public 
interest standard is a high hurdle and weighed factors on 
every side.  In particular, the Secretary's concern that the 
Compact might result in higher retail prices for fluid milk in 
the Compact region does not invalidate his finding.  The 
Secretary noted this concern, but, while expressing some 
uncertainty as to how the Commission would implement the 
Compact, he ultimately assumed that the Commission would 
be sensitive to consumer needs and thus that any rise in milk 
prices would not be so great as to offset the compelling public 



interests warranting authorization of the Compact.  See Am-
plified Decision, 62 Fed. Reg. at 14,880.  The reasonableness 
of this assumption is amply supported by the Compact's 
structural requirements designed to protect consumer inter-
ests, described above.  As an additional safeguard to ensure 
that the Compact is implemented with sensitivity to all affect-
ed persons and interests, the Secretary offered the Commis-
sion the assistance of the Department of Agriculture to 
achieve this goal.  Id.

     Finally, the Secretary's initial emphasis on a perceived 
authority to revoke the Compact, followed by his acknowledg-
ment that he lacks such revocation authority, is not determi-
native of the question before us.  The Secretary first stated, 
in his Amplified Decision, that, "[g]iven the shifting nature of 
the compelling interest test, the Department strongly believes 
that the authority to withdraw or revoke its authorization is 
an essential element of any decision which finds that a 
compelling public interest exists."  62 Fed. Reg. at 14,880.  
In an Addendum to that decision, published approximately 
one week later, the Secretary recognized that he "may have 
inadvertently created the impression that it would have been 
impossible for [him] to authorize implementation in the ab-
sence of revocation authority" and clarified that, "[i]n fact, 
... [his] finding of compelling public interest was based on a 
broad array of factors which [he] discussed in [the Amplified 
Decision and] was not contingent upon the existence of revo-
cation authority."  62 Fed. Reg. at 16,539.

     The Secretary's mistaken belief that he could revoke autho-
rization of the Compact, should he determine that changing 
conditions warranted revocation, does not render his decision 
invalid in light of the demanding "compelling public interest" 
standard.  In his Amplified Decision, the Secretary concluded 
that "given current conditions" authorization of the Compact 
was in the compelling public interest of the Compact region.  
62 Fed. Reg. at 14,880.  Rather than attempt to predict 
precisely how relevant conditions might play out in the future, 
the Secretary simply planned to revoke his authorization 
should changing conditions warrant.  See id.  ("Facts and 
circumstances that may currently justify authorization may 



subsequently change to the extent that a compelling public 
interest no longer exists in the Compact region.").  However, 
when pushed to clarify whether--even without revocation 
authority and without being able to predict with certainty 
how relevant conditions might change--he anticipated that 
authorization nevertheless would be in the compelling public 
interest of the Compact region, the Secretary clarified that 
authorization was still warranted.  See Addendum, 62 Fed. 
Reg. at 16,539.  On the record at hand, we have no good 
reason to question this predictive judgment.

     Under the arbitrary and capricious standard of review, "an 
agency's predictive judgments about areas that are within the 
agency's field of discretion and expertise" are entitled to 
"particularly deferential" review, as long as they are reason-
able.  International Ladies' Garment Workers' Union v. 
Donovan, 722 F.2d 795, 821-22 (D.C. Cir. 1983) (citations 
omitted).  The question of whether permitting the Compact 
Commission to override federal farm-gate prices pending the 
reform of the national milk pricing scheme would be in the 
compelling public interest of the Compact region implicates 
the Secretary's expertise in the regulation of milk prices.  We 
find that the Secretary's predictive judgment on this point is 
reasonable, notwithstanding his confusion over the authority 
to revoke.

                               III. Conclusion 


     For the reasons explained above, the District Court's deci-
sion granting Appellees' summary judgment motion and de-
nying Appellant's summary judgment motion is affirmed.

So ordered.





     Rogers, Circuit Judge, with whom Henderson, Circuit 
Judge joins, concurring:  I join the opinion of the court and 
write separately only to note another reason underscoring 
why the condition requiring that the Secretary of Agriculture 
determine whether a compelling public interest existed in the 
Compact region does not involve an impermissible delegation.

     The Compact Clause has always been recognized as a 
device to protect federal power from encroachments by the 
states.  The Framers required the "Consent of Congress" 
before any state could "enter into any Agreement or Compact 
with another State."  U.S. Const. art. I, s 10, cl. 3.  It has 
ever since been "evident that the [Compact Clause] prohibi-
tion is directed to the formation of any combination tending to 
the increase of political power in the States, which may 
encroach upon or interfere with the just supremacy of the 
United States."  Virginia v. Tennessee, 148 U.S. 503, 519 
(1893).  As Joseph Story explained, "the consent of congress 
may be properly required, in order to check any infringement 
of the rights of the national government;  and at the same 
time a total prohibition, to enter into any compact or agree-
ment, might be attended with permanent inconvenience, or 
public mischief."  Joseph Story, 3 Commentaries on the 
Constitution of the United States s 1397 (1833);  see also 
Felix Frankfurter & James M. Landis, The Compact Clause 
of the Constitution--A Study in Interstate Adjustments, 34 
Yale L.J. 685, 694-95 (1925).

     The Compact Clause was drafted at a time when the states 
were relatively powerful and independent entities.  The draft-
ers of the Constitution sought to ensure the supremacy of 
federal power in interstate affairs.  Although the drafters 
spoke of congressional consent, it is clear that they hoped not 
just to vindicate the legislative power of Congress, but to 
protect the power of the entire federal government with the 
Clause.  Indeed, the Supreme Court has since recognized 
that the Compact Clause required congressional consent for 
interstate compacts only when the compact infringes upon 



federal power.  See, e.g., United States Steel Corp. v. Multi-
state Tax Comm'n, 434 U.S. 452, 459-60, 471 (1978).

     With this background in mind, it is clear that the process of 
consent in the instant case fully realized the purpose of the 
Compact Clause.  The New England states appropriately 
sought congressional consent to the dairy compact, which will 
affect the federal regulation of milk prices pursuant to the 
Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937, 7 U.S.C. 
ss 601-624, 671-674 (1994).  They obtained that consent from 
Congress and its delegate, the Secretary of Agriculture.  
Both Congress and the Secretary were capable of vindicating 
the federal power protected by the Compact Clause, the 
former under the Clause itself, and the latter by virtue of 
delegated and statutory powers.  As the Supreme Court has 
observed, "the constitution makes no provision respecting the 
mode or form in which the consent of congress is to be 
signified, very properly leaving that matter to the wisdom of 
that body, to be decided upon according to the ordinary rules 
of law, and of right reason."  Green v. Biddle, 21 U.S. (8 
Wheat.) 1, 85-86 (1823).  For these reasons, the balance of 
power envisioned in the Compact Clause has been preserved 
by the actions of the New England states, Congress, and the 
Secretary.