Legal Research AI

Riggs National Corp. & Subsidiaries v. Commissioner

Court: Court of Appeals for the D.C. Circuit
Date filed: 1999-01-12
Citations: 163 F.3d 1363, 333 U.S. App. D.C. 371
Copy Citations
28 Citing Cases
Combined Opinion
                        United States Court of Appeals

                     FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT

            Argued December 11, 1998    Decided January 12, 1999 

                                 No. 98-1039

                  Riggs National Corporation & Subsidiaries 

                                  Appellant

                                      v.

                  Commissioner of Internal Revenue Service, 

                                   Appellee

                   Appeal from the United States Tax Court 

                              (No. TAX-24368-89)

     Thomas C. Durham argued the cause for appellant.  With 
him on the briefs were Joel V. Williamson, Kim Marie 
Boylan, and Stephen M. Feldhaus.

     Charles Bricken, Attorney, United States Department of 
Justice, argued the cause for appellee.  With him on the brief 
were Loretta C. Argrett, Assistant Attorney General, and 
David English Carmack, Attorney.
     Stephen D. Gardner was on the brief for amicus curiae 
National Foreign Trade Council, Inc.

     Before:  Wald, Silberman, and Tatel, Circuit Judges.

             Opinion for the Court filed by Circuit Judge Silberman.

     Silberman, Circuit Judge:  Riggs Bank, asserting that it 
had paid taxes to the Brazilian government with respect to 
interest income on loans it had made to the Central Bank of 
Brazil, claimed foreign tax credits under s 901 of the Internal 
Revenue Code.  The Commissioner disallowed the credits on 
the theory that Riggs was not "legally liable" for the tax 
under Brazilian law, and the Tax Court denied Riggs' petition 
for relief.  We reverse.

                                      I.

                                      A.

     Riggs National Corporation's subsidiary Riggs Bank was 
one of numerous banks that made loans to the Central Bank 
of Brazil during the early to mid-1980s as part of a plan to 
rescue Brazil from a debt crisis.  Riggs' loans were so-called 
"net loans."  In a net loan, the borrower contractually agrees 
not only to pay interest to the lender, but also to pay any 
local (Brazilian) tax that the lender owes on that interest 
income.  Every interest payment the lender receives is then 
free of local tax--the borrower has paid it.  By contrast, in a 
"gross loan," the lender remains subject to local tax liability.  
In either type of loan, which party technically conveys the tax 
payment to the local government is of little moment.  In a 
gross loan, either the lender could remit the tax to the local 
government or the borrower could withhold that amount and 
remit it to the local government on behalf of the lender.  So 
too in a net loan (where the concept of "withholding" does not 
really apply because the interest payments are free of local 
tax), either the borrower could remit the tax to the local 
government or the borrower could send to the lender both the 
guaranteed net loan interest payment and the appropriate 
amount of tax payment on the understanding that the lender 
would then remit the tax to the local government.  (In 



practice in Brazil, the borrower does the "withholding" of the 
local tax in the gross loan situation and the "paying" of the 
local tax in the net loan situation.)  The real difference 
between gross loans and net loans lies not in who licks the 
stamp on the envelope to the Brazilian government, but in 
who bears the economic burden of the tax.

     The key feature of a net loan is its placement of the risk of 
a change in the local tax rate on the borrower.  If the local 
tax rate rises after the parties have set the interest rate, the 
lender continues to receive the same interest payment free of 
local tax--it is the borrower who suffers.  On the other hand, 
if the local tax rate falls after the parties have set the interest 
rate, the lender still continues to receive the same interest 
payment free of local tax--but now the borrower has become 
better off because his assumed tax liability is lower.

     Computing the lender's tax liability on a gross loan is easy:  
one simply multiplies the local tax rate by the amount of 
interest income.  So if the local tax rate is 25% and the 
interest payment is $12 (assume a 12% interest rate and $100 
principal), the lender's local tax liability is $3.  Computing the 
lender's local tax liability on a net loan--which, recall, is 
assumed by the borrower--is slightly more complicated.  The 
parties' loan agreement sets forth the interest income as an 
after-tax amount, which presumably would be smaller than 
the before-tax amount in a gross loan because, all things 
being equal, a borrower entering a net loan will get a lower 
interest rate in exchange for assuming the lender's tax liabili-
ty.  To maintain parity between the tax revenue from net 
loans and gross loans, the Brazilian government requires that 
the after-tax income specified in the parties' net loan agree-
ment be adjusted--"grossed-up"--into a hypothetical before-
tax amount.  The "gross-up" adjustment requires one to look 
at the interest rate selected by the parties in their net loan 
agreement, then assume that the parties had chosen the gross 
loan form rather than the net loan form, and extrapolate the 
interest rate the parties would have agreed upon if they had 
entered a gross loan.1

__________
     1 We should point out that a net loan transaction between a 
United States lender and a United States borrower would implicate 


     The foregoing is best illustrated by an example.  Suppose a 
lender extends a $100 net loan to a borrower, specifying a 9% 
annually compounded interest rate, and assume a local tax 
rate on interest income of 25%.  In the first year of the loan, 
the lender will receive interest income of $9 (i.e., 9% of the 
$100 principal), and this income will be free of local tax.  The 
borrower of course pays the $9 interest payment to the 
lender.  How much local tax does the borrower pay--on the 
lender's behalf--to the local government?  We identify the 
interest rate the parties would have agreed upon had they 
selected the gross loan form, which is the interest rate 
necessary to provide the lender with the same $9 interest 
income if the lender had to pay his own local tax obligation.  
The answer is 12%.  That interest rate would yield interest 
income of $12 to the lender in the first year of the loan;  the 
local tax on this income would be $3 (i.e., 25% of $12);  and 
the lender would be left with $9 at the end of the day.2

__________
only United States tax law and would be treated entirely different-
ly.  The borrower's contractual assumption of the lender's tax 
liability would not relieve the lender of tax liability, for the borrow-
er's discharge of the lender's tax liability on the interest income 
would itself constitute income to the lender.  Old Colony Trust Co. 
v. Commissioner of Internal Revenue, 279 U.S. 716, 729 (1929);  26 
U.S.C. s 61(a) (1994).  If the borrower covenanted to pay not only 
the interest payment to the borrower and the lender's tax liability 
on the interest payment, but also the lender's tax liability on the 
income resulting from the borrower's discharge of the lender's 
liability on the interest payment, that additional payment would 
again constitute income to the lender.  And so on.  For whatever 
reason, Brazilian tax law does not lead us into this endless circle.  
Instead, it draws a line at the borrower's discharge of the lender's 
tax liability on the interest income--only the grossed-up amount of 
interest income is treated as income for purposes of Brazilian tax 
law.

     2 Although the trial-and-error method will suffice to identify the 
grossed-up interest rate, the adjustment can also be performed 
more formally.  The equation is rg = rn/(1--t), where rg is the 
interest rate the parties would have selected had they entered a 
gross loan rather than a net loan, t is the local tax rate, and rn is the 
interest rate the parties actually selected in their net loan agree-



     The lender's Brazilian tax liability is only half of the story.  
In calculating his United States tax liability, the lender must 
include in gross income the interest payment he receives from 
the borrower and the Brazilian tax paid (on his behalf) by the 
borrower to the Brazilian tax collector.  Old Colony Trust Co. 
v. Commissioner of Internal Revenue, 279 U.S. 716, 729 
(1929);  26 U.S.C. s 61 (1994).  But there is potentially also a 
benefit to our lender under U.S. tax law:  the Internal Reve-
nue Code allows a taxpayer to take as a credit against his 
U.S. tax liability on income earned in a foreign country the 
amount of foreign tax he has paid on that same income.  Id. 
s 901.

     This brings us to the dispute between Riggs Bank and the 
Commissioner.  Riggs claims it is entitled to foreign tax 
credits in the amount of the Brazilian taxes paid on its behalf 
by the borrower, the Central Bank of Brazil, pursuant to a 
net loan agreement.  The Commissioner disagrees, arguing 
that under Brazilian law, there was no obligation on either 
Riggs or the Central Bank to pay a tax given the Central 
Bank's tax-immune status as a governmental entity, and so 
any payments made were voluntary and not a "creditable" tax 
for purposes of the foreign tax credit.  (The Commissioner 
does not seek to "have his cake and eat it too" by denying 
Riggs the foreign tax credit and by including in Riggs' gross 
U.S. income the "voluntary payment" made by the Central 
Bank to the Brazilian Treasury--that illogical position, once 
advanced by the Commissioner, has been rejected and aban-
doned.  See Continental Illinois Corp. v. Commissioner of 
Internal Revenue, 998 F.2d 513, 517-18 (7th Cir. 1993).)

     It is important to understand the nature of appellant's 
economic incentive in seeking the foreign tax credit to appre-
ciate the Commissioner's concern.  The lender's gross cash 
inflow is unaffected by the availability of the credit--the 
lender, pursuant to the net loan agreement, continues to 

__________
ment.  See Continental Illinois Corp. v. Commissioner of Internal 
Revenue, 998 F.2d 513, 516 (7th Cir. 1993).  Plugging in the 
numbers from the example set forth in the text, we can verify our 
trial-and-error calculation;  rg = .09/(1--.25) = .12;  i.e., 12%.



receive the same guaranteed interest rate.  Nor is there any 
effect on the lender's Brazilian tax liability;  by definition, in a 
net loan, the lender has passed his Brazilian tax obligation to 
the borrower.  The economic advantage stems, rather, from 
the effect on the lender's U.S. tax liability.  Although the 
lender's U.S. tax liability increases by the U.S. tax rate 
multiplied by the amount of Brazilian tax paid on his behalf 
by the borrower, the lender's U.S. tax liability simultaneously 
decreases by the entire amount of the Brazilian tax.  The key 
point is that the foreign tax credit is a credit--not a deduc-
tion.  So long as the U.S. tax rate is less than 100%, the 
decrease in U.S. tax liability outweighs the increase.  And the 
lender can then apply this excess tax credit toward offsetting 
the rest of his U.S. tax liability on this same foreign source 
income.

                                      B.

     In 1983, appellant and several other banks contemplating 
extending net loans to the Central Bank of Brazil were well 
aware of the potential tax benefit just described and that a 
precondition to qualifying for the foreign tax credit was 
establishing that there was indeed a Brazilian tax for which 
they would be liable.  Although, as we have noted, it was 
undisputed that Brazil imposed a tax on interest income paid 
by Brazilian borrowers to non-Brazilian lenders, the Central 
Bank is no ordinary Brazilian borrower.  Rather, the Central 
Bank is a governmental entity and thus immune from tax on 
its own income under the Federal Constitution of Brazil.  It 
might have been thought that the Central Bank's own tax 
immunity would not bear on its obligation to pay the tax on 
any loan, including a net interest loan, for in such a transac-
tion the Central Bank would not really discharge its own tax 
obligation, but rather a tax obligation contractually assumed 
from the lender.  But there was authority in Brazilian law for 
the proposition that the tax-immune status of an entity such 
as the Central Bank shielded not only its own income, but 
also the interest income of a foreigner who lends to that tax-
immune entity in a net loan transaction.  The Brazilian 
Supreme Court had so ruled, see State of Parana v. Central 



Bank (cited in Riggs Nat'l Corp. v. Commissioner, 107 T.C. 
301, 342 (1996) (entered by Tax Court by order dated Oct. 15, 
1997)), and the Brazilian Revenue Service issued an "officio" 
to the same effect, see SRF 368 (cited in Riggs, 107 T.C. at 
313-14).

     An on-point Brazilian Supreme Court decision and an unfa-
vorable revenue service ruling did not, however, foreclose the 
Bank's hopes for a foreign tax credit.  Brazil does not follow 
the common law rule of stare decisis, so the Supreme Court's 
prior opinion is not necessarily authoritative, and, as in the 
United States, the revenue service might be persuaded to 
change its view.  Brazilian tax immune entities were obliged, 
under Brazilian law, to withhold taxes from gross loan inter-
est payments, see Federal Gov't v. Highway Dep't of the State 
of Parana (cited in Riggs, 107 T.C. at 341)--notwithstanding 
their own tax immune status--so it could be contended that 
the contrary treatment of net loans was anomalous.  Appel-
lant and other banks requested definitive guidance on the 
matter, and the Minister of Finance--the highest ranking 
Brazilian authority on tax matters--obliged them with a 
favorable private letter ruling, which under Brazilian law 
binds the parties.

     The ruling concluded that the Central Bank--notwithstand-
ing its tax-immune status--was required under Brazilian law 
to pay the tax obligation assumed from lenders in the contem-
plated net loan transactions.  It explicitly stated that the 
Central Bank "must ... pay the income tax on the interest 
paid."  Riggs, 107 T.C. at 331.3  The Minister distinguished 
the earlier revenue ruling.  The loans to the Central Bank 
were regarded as unique in that the funds advanced to the 
Central Bank were--under the terms of the debt restructur-
ing plan--available for relending by the Central Bank to 
private Brazilian borrowers.  The Minister deemed it appro-
priate to "look through" the Central Bank to those ultimate 
private borrowers--so-called "borrowers-to-be"--for pur-

__________
     3 The ruling was actually prepared by the Secretaria da Receita 
Federal and then adopted by the Minister.  The SRF is under the 
Minister of Finance in the hierarchy of Brazilian taxing authority.



poses of deciding the proper tax treatment of the loans.  And 
it was settled Brazilian law that a private borrower in a net 
loan was required to pay the tax obligation it had contractual-
ly assumed from the lender.  The Minister concluded that the 
"borrowers-to-be" aspect of the loans compelled an analogy to 
the garden variety private borrower situation, and that the 
Central Bank must "as a substitute for such borrowers [to-be] 
pay the income tax incident on the interest from January 1, 
1984 to the end of the period of availability for such funds to 
be relent."  Id.

     Riggs assumed, based on this definitive ruling from Brazil's 
highest tax authority, that the Brazilian tax was a creditable 
tax under s 901 and it determined its U.S. tax liability 
accordingly in the years 1984-86.  This involved including in 
gross income the interest payments as well as the Brazilian 
tax obligation discharged by the Central Bank, applying the 
U.S. tax rate to that amount, and finally crediting against that 
U.S. tax liability the amount of the Brazilian tax obligation 
discharged by the Central Bank.  The Commissioner disa-
greed that the asserted payments made by the Central Bank 
to the Brazilian tax collector constituted creditable taxes for 
purposes of s 901, redetermined Riggs' U.S. tax liability, and 
sent Riggs a notice of deficiency.4  The Commissioner argued 
that a proper interpretation of Brazilian law led to the 
conclusion--notwithstanding the Minister of Finance's private 
letter ruling--that no Brazilian tax is imposed on either 
lender or borrower where the borrower is a tax-immune 
entity;  therefore, any payments made were voluntary and not 
"taxes paid or accrued ... to any foreign country."  26 
U.S.C. s 901(b)(1).

     The Bank argued in the Tax Court that the Commissioner's 
theory depended on declaring ineffectual the Minister of 
Finance's private letter ruling, and that adoption of such a 
theory by the Tax Court would therefore run afoul of the act 

__________
     4 The amounts of foreign tax credit at issue for each year are:

1984     $166,415

1985      181,272

1986      317,019

of state doctrine.  The Tax Court disagreed--it viewed the 
private letter ruling as nothing "more than perhaps an admin-
istrative advisory opinion"--and thereupon engaged in a com-
prehensive review of Brazilian law on the issue of whether a 
tax-immune borrower in a net loan transaction is considered 
to assume the lender's tax obligation as a private borrower 
would, and thus whether that tax-immune borrower is re-
quired to pay that amount to the Brazilian tax collector.  
Riggs, 107 T.C. at 359.  The Tax Court held that under 
Brazilian law, a tax-immune borrower such as the Central 
Bank is not required to pay the tax, and approved the 
Commissioner's determination that the asserted payments did 
not constitute creditable taxes for purposes of s 901.

                                     II.


     Riggs Bank primarily relies on the act of state doctrine.  
The doctrine directs United States courts to refrain from 
deciding a case when the outcome turns upon the legality or 
illegality (whether as a matter of U.S., foreign, or internation-
al law) of official action by a foreign sovereign performed 
within its own territory.  W.S. Kirkpatrick & Co., Inc. v. 
Environmental Tectonics Corp., 493 U.S. 400, 406 (1990).  It 
stems from separation of powers concerns;  it reflects " 'the 
strong sense of the Judicial Branch that its engagement in 
the task of passing on the validity of foreign acts of state may 
hinder' the conduct of foreign affairs."  Id. at 404 (quoting 
Banco Nacional de Cuba v. Sabbatino, 376 U.S. 398, 423 
(1964));  see generally Restatement (Third) of the Foreign 
Relations Law of the United States s 443 cmt. a (1986).5

     The government suggests that a foreign administrative 
official's interpretation of foreign law is not the type of act of 

__________
     5 The doctrine does not operate by depriving courts of jurisdic-
tion;  rather it functions as a doctrine of abstention.  See In re 
Minister Papandreou, 139 F.3d 247, 256 (D.C. Cir. 1998).  The 
party invoking the act of state doctrine has the burden of establish-
ing the factual predicate for the doctrine's applicability.  Lamb v. 
Phillip Morris, Inc., 915 F.2d 1024, 1026 & n.4 (6th Cir. 1990).



state contemplated by the doctrine.6  To be sure, the doctrine 
has been applied principally to more "tangible" acts.  See, 
e.g., Sabbatino, 376 U.S. at 403-04 (expropriation of proper-
ty);  Ricaud v. American Metal Co., 246 U.S. 304, 310 (1918) 
(same);  Underhill v. Hernandez, 168 U.S. 250, 254 (1897) 
(detention of person by sovereign official);  Credit Suisse v. 
United States Dist. Court for the Cent. Dist. of Calif., 130 
F.3d 1342, 1347 (9th Cir. 1997) (asset freeze orders);  Callejo 
v. Bancomer, S.A., 764 F.2d 1101, 1114 (5th Cir. 1985) (pro-
mulgation of exchange control regulations).  That we are 
unaware of cases treating an interpretation of law as an act of 
state, of course, does not foreclose the doctrine's applicability.  
We are, however, hesitant to treat an interpretation of law as 
an act of state, for such a view might be in tension with rules 
of procedure directing U.S. courts to conduct a de novo 
review of foreign law when an issue of foreign law is raised.  
See Fed. R. Civ. P. 44.1;  Tax Court R. 146.

     But, whether or not it can be said that the Brazilian 
Minister of Finance's interpretation of Brazilian law qualifies 
as an act of state, the Minister's order to the Central Bank to 
withhold and pay the income tax on the interest paid to the 
Bank goes beyond a mere interpretation of law.  The Minis-
ter, after all, ordered that the Central Bank "must, in substi-
tution of the future not yet identified debtors of the tax [i.e., 
the borrowers-to-be], pay the income tax on the interest paid 

__________
     6 The government does not contend that the act of state doctrine 
is inapplicable here because one of the litigants, the Commissioner, 
is an executive branch official.  Insofar as the Commissioner is an 
executive branch official, it might be thought that the separation of 
powers concerns underlying the doctrine are not present.  While 
not yet endorsed by a majority of the Supreme Court, some justices 
have suggested an exception to the doctrine for cases in which the 
executive branch has represented in a so-called "Bernstein" letter, 
see Bernstein v. N.V. Nederlandsche-Amerikaansche Stoomvaart-
Maatschappij, 210 F.2d 375 (2d Cir. 1954), that it has no objection 
to denying validity to the foreign sovereign act.  See First National 
City Bank v. Banco Nacional de Cuba, 406 U.S. 759, 768-770 (1972) 
(opinion of Rehnquist, J., joined by Burger, C.J., and White, J.);  see 
generally Restatement s 443 Reporter's Note 8.



during the period in which the funds remained available for 
relending."  Riggs, 107 T.C. at 331.  Such an order has been 
treated as an act of state.  See Credit Suisse, 130 F.3d at 
1347 (asset freeze orders);  Callejo, 764 F.2d at 1114 (ex-
change control regulations).  The Tax Court's conclusion on 
Brazilian law--that no tax is imposed on a net loan transac-
tion involving a governmental entity as borrower--implicitly 
declared "non-compulsory," i.e., invalid, the Minister's order 
to the Central Bank to pay the taxes.  The act of state 
doctrine requires courts to abstain from even engaging in 
such an inquiry.

     The Commissioner nevertheless argues, and the Tax Court 
agreed, that the Minister's order to the Central Bank was not 
actually a compulsory order and thus not a "definitive" act of 
state.  The Tax Court reasoned that Riggs' "experts did not 
elaborate on whether the Central Bank, under Brazilian law, 
was legally compelled to accept and follow the ruling," and 
speculated that the Central Bank would likely succeed in 
overturning the ruling if it sought an appeal in the Brazilian 
courts.  Riggs, 107 T.C. at 359.  Here the Tax Court simply 
misread the record.  See Commissioner of Internal Revenue 
v. Duberstein, 363 U.S. 278, 289-91 (1960).  Both parties' 
experts testified that acts of an executive official such as the 
Minister are valid and binding until declared invalid by a 
Brazilian court, Bekin Dep. (cited in Joint Appendix ("J.A.") 
353-54);  Pedreira Aff. p 7 (cited in J.A. 1156), and it is 
undisputed that no such invalidation has occurred.  Moreover, 
appellant had no standing under Brazilian law to litigate the 
validity of the Minister's ruling;  only the Central Bank had 
that right, and it declined to do so.

                                   * * * *


     The Commissioner argues that if the act of state doctrine 
requires courts to treat the Minister's ruling as binding, it 
would jeopardize the Commissioner's ability to determine 
when taxpayers are eligible for the foreign tax credit.  That 
is not so.  The Commissioner's challenge focused entirely on 
whether Brazilian law required the Central Bank to pay 



taxes on these loans to the Brazilian government.  The 
Commissioner might have conceded the legitimacy of the 
Minister of Finance's order, but contended that under U.S. 
tax principles, the payments should not be considered a 
creditable tax under s 901.  That alternative argument, if 
accepted by the Tax Court, would not run afoul of the act of 
state doctrine because it would not require the Tax Court to 
declare invalid the Minister's order to the Central Bank to 
make the payments;  it would only require the Tax Court to 
interpret the U.S. tax consequences of those concededly 
mandated payments.  See Kirkpatrick, 493 U.S. at 405.  In-
quiry into the U.S. tax consequences of foreign levies is what 
this area of tax law is all about, and is the premise of the 
Supreme Court's dictum in Biddle v. Commissioner of Inter-
nal Revenue, 302 U.S. 573, 579 (1938):

     The phrase "income taxes paid," as used in our own 
     revenue laws, has for most practical purposes a well-
     understood meaning to be derived from an examination 
     of the statutes which provide for the laying and collection 
     of income taxes.  It is that meaning which must be 
     attributed to it as used in section [901].

The Treasury's own regulation acknowledges the distinction 
between the Commissioner's claim in this case, which impli-
cates the act of state doctrine, and the ordinary Biddle-type 
inquiry, which does not.  The regulation provides, in relevant 
part:  "Whether a foreign levy [is creditable for purposes of 
s 901] is determined by principles of U.S. law and not by 
principles of the law of the foreign country."  26 C.F.R. 
s 1.901-2(a)(2)(i) (1998).  Ordinarily, the Commissioner takes 
the foreign country's laws and requirements as given and 
determines their U.S. tax consequences "by principles of U.S. 
law and not by principles of the law of the foreign country."  
Id.  In this case, by contrast, the Commissioner focused on 
the foreign country's laws and requirements themselves and 
presented arguments based on foreign law that no payment 
requirement existed.

     We think we understand why the Commissioner was so 
troubled by this transaction.  The government's brief hinted 
that to allow the Bank to take the tax credit in this situation 



was to give it virtually "a free lunch"--at the American 
Treasury's expense.  A national governmental borrower is 
different than a private borrower or a state borrower:  al-
though the Central Bank has assumed the lender's tax obli-
gation in the net loan agreement, that transaction just re-
quires the federal government to take a bit of money from 
one of its pockets and put it in the other.  Whereas a private, 
or even a state borrower, in a net loan arrangement bears a 
real economic risk when it assumes the lender's tax liability 
and the loan transaction's terms--possibly through lower 
interest rates--presumably reflect that economic risk.  But in 
this situation the economic risk seems artificial.  According to 
both counsel, however, Treasury regulations do not admit of a 
distinction between the foreign tax credit treatment of a net 
loan with a central government entity as borrower and any 
other entities as borrowers.  See 26 C.F.R. s 1.901-2(f)(2)(ii) 
Ex. 3;  see generally II Joseph Isenbergh, International 
Taxation p 29.12.3 (2d ed. 1997).

     Of course, the opportunistic nature of the Brazilian govern-
ment's action is particularly vexing.  The Minister's ruling 
essentially accomplished a one-time increase in Brazilian tax-
es from 0% to 25%, applicable, by virtue of the narrowly 
targeted borrowers-to-be-theory, only to the transaction be-
tween Riggs (and other foreign banks) and the Central Bank 
of Brazil;  it had no effect on other Brazilian borrowers.  But 
although we can visualize prophylactic regulatory measures 
that would prevent this device from being utilized, the Com-
missioner has not yet fashioned a legitimate legal challenge to 
Riggs' use of the foreign tax credit in this case.

                                   * * * *

     For the foregoing reasons, we reverse the decision of the 
Tax Court and remand the case so that the Tax Court may 
determine in the first instance which of Riggs' loans were 
subject to the Minister's ruling, whether the taxes were in 
fact paid by the Central Bank, and whether Riggs' credits 
must be reduced by the amount of any subsidies that the 
Central Bank may have received.

                                                                    So ordered.