Legality Under Anti-Lottery Laws of Amendments to
Simultaneous Oil and Gas Leasing Procedures
The amendment of the Simultaneous Oil and Gas (SOG) Leasing Procedures to clarify
the discretion of the Secretary o f the Interior to decline to award leases to applicants
whose names are drawn under the SOG procedures, provides some additional support
for the conclusion in the April 7, 1980, O LC memorandum that the SOG program is
not a prohibited lottery within the scope of 18 U.S.C. §§ 1302 and 1304.
Serious legal difficulties would arise if the SOG regulations were amended to establish a
multiple filing system which would give preference to those willing and able to pay the
most for lease opportunities, because of the statutory requirement that oil and gas leases
be awarded not to the highest bidder but to the first qualified person making applica
tion to hold a lease. Moreover, insofar as a multiple Tiling system would tax lease
applicants by making their chances depend on the size o f their payments, and poten
tially enrich the government, it might be considered a violation of the anti-lottery laws.
In the absence of a specific statutory limitation on the amount which may be charged
each applicant for a lease, the Secretary is authorized to increase the present fee to a
level that more accurately reflects the actual cost of administering the system.
June 8, 1981
MEMORANDUM OPINION FOR THE DEPUTY SOLICITOR,
DEPARTM ENT OF THE INTERIOR
You have requested the views of this Office on two legal questions
that involve the Simultaneous Oil and Gas (SOG) Leasing Procedures.
Both of these questions were prompted in part by a memorandum
issued by this Office on April 7, 1980, Applicability o f Anti-Lottery Laws
to Simultaneous O il and Gas Leasing Procedures, 4 Op. O.L.C. 557
(1980). In that memorandum we expressed the view that the random
lease allocation system established by these procedures is not a prohib
ited “lottery” within the meaning of 18 U.S.C. §§ 1302 and 1304. Those
statutes are discussed in detail in that memorandum.
Your first question concerns a recent change in the SOG regulations.
Although it has always been the law that the Secretary of the Interior
has discretion to decline to award leases to applicants whose names are
drawn under the SOG procedures, some portions of the old regulations
did not expressly recognize that discretion. See, e.g., 43 C.F.R.
§ 3112.4-1 (1979) (a lease “will be issued to the first drawee qualified to
receive a lease”). The regulations have now been amended to establish
an offer and acceptance procedure that is more clearly in harmony with
153
the Secretary’s discretionary power.1 You ask whether this change in
the regulation alters our previous conclusion that the SOG program
falls within the usual legal definition of a lottery 2 but is not a prohib
ited lottery within the meaning of §§ 1302 and 1304.
In our previous memorandum we took note of the argument that the
Secretary’s residual discretion distinguishes the SOG program from
some kinds of lotteries. See 4 Op. O.L.C. at 561. We concluded, how
ever, that the existence of discretion in the Secretary does not in itself
make a decisive legal difference in the interpretation of the criminal
statutes. The purpose of the SOG procedures is to “manage the crowd”
while implementing the Secretary’s responsibility to award leases to the
first qualified persons making application. The system operates by allot
ting things of value (oil and gas leases) among multiple qualified appli
cants on the basis of chance. That is the effect of the procedures
whenever the Secretary, in his discretion, awards a lease to a randomly
selected applicant. Whenever that occurs, the SOG procedures so
clearly resemble a “lottery” that there would be a substantial question
concerning their legality if Congress had intended in the relevant crimi
nal statutes to suppress lotteries of every kind. As you know, we
concluded in our previous memorandum that Congress did not intend
to suppress certain “lotteries” employed by officers of the United States
in the due administration of their statutory powers, if such lotteries are
not designed to enrich the “promoters.”
The change in the old regulation to reflect more clearly the scope of
the Secretary’s discretion does not affect our previous analysis or the
conclusion articulated in the April 7, 1980, opinion. If anything, the
clarification of the regulation with respect to the Secretary’s discretion
provides a small measure of additional support for our conclusion that
the SOG program, in its present form, is a reasonable attempt by the
Secretary to carry out a function assigned to him by statute and is not
therefore a prohibited lottery within the scope of §§ 1302 and 1304.
Your second question concerns a proposal that has been made for
further modification of the SOG procedures. Under the present system,
each lease applicant is permitted, for a nominal fee, to file a single
application for a given lease; and all qualified applicants have an equal
chance of being selected under the random selection process. It has
been suggested that this system could be changed to permit applicants
to make an unlimited number of applications. The application fee could
remain the same ($10 for each application), or it could be raised. In
either case, the amended system would permit each applicant to pur
chase as many chances for a lease as he desired, while requiring him to
1T he new regulations are set o u t in 45 Fed. Reg. 35,164 (M ay 1980). In general, they provide that
an applicant whose name is draw n under the SO G procedures may execute and tender a lease
agreem ent, together with a year’s rent, which the Secretary may then accept or reject in his
discretion.
2 See F C C v. American Broadcasting Co., 347 U.S. 284 (1954).
154
pay proportionately for that privilege. Thus, if an applicant wished to
purchase 1,000 chances, he would pay the Department $10,000, assum
ing the application fee remained $10; he would pay $10,000 for 500
chances if the fee were increased to $20 per application.
You note that in our previous memorandum we attributed some
significance to the fact that the present SOG “lottery” does not enrich
federal coffers and does not encourage “gambling” by permitting appli
cants to purchase more than one chance for a lease. In light of that
position, you ask whether we would take a different view of the
“lottery” issue if the SOG regulations were amended to permit multiple
filings either at the present $10 fee or at an increased fee. You also ask
whether our views would be altered if the present single filing system
were retained but the application fee were increased to generate greater
revenues for the government. We will address those questions in turn.
1. Multiple filing. We have carefully reviewed with appropriate offi
cials within your Department the policy reasons behind your consider
ation of a multiple filing system. We understand that the SOG program
is not entirely satisfactory from a policy standpoint. As presently ad
ministered, it is inefficient economically, for it does not allocate leases
to the applicants who are most qualified to explore for oil and gas. It
has produced a private assignment market in which leases obtained by
applicants who have no intention of exploring for oil or gas are sold to
bona fide exploration companies for impressive profits. It encourages
fraud by creating an economic incentive for violation of the single
application rule. The suggestion has been made that these problems
could be ameliorated, or perhaps even cured, if applicants were permit
ted to register the strength of their desires for a given lease by purchas
ing multiple chances at an aggregate price that would approximate the
“true” value of the exploration opportunity represented by the lease.
We do not question the merit of the policy argument, but we think
that serious legal difficulties would arise if the SOG program were
amended to establish a multiple filing system. We could not recommend
that such a change be made without further statutory authorization.
The primary problem is that the change would make it more difficult
to argue that the SOG system is an otherwise lawful and reasonable
means of carrying forward the underlying statutory mandate—the re
quirement that the Secretary award these leases, not to the highest
bidders, but to the persons “first making application” who are “quali
fied to hold a lease.” See 30 U.S.C. § 226(c). The random selection
process was sustained in Thor-Westcliffe Development, Inc. v. Udall, 314
F.2d 257 (D.C. Cir. 1963), as a reasonable means of “managing the
crowd” while complying with that mandate; but if the system were
changed to authorize multiple filings at prices that would depend on
the number of filings made by each applicant, the Secretary would be
“managing the crowd” by giving an advantage to those applicants who
155
are willing and able to pay the most for lease opportunities. We think it
would be difficult to reconcile that preference with the legislative
intention that appears on the face of the leasing statute. Among other
wise qualified applicants,3 the willingness of one applicant to pay more
than the others for a chance at a lease may be some indication of the
relative strength of his desire to exploit the exploration opportunity; it
may also be nothing more than an indication of his willingness to risk
more money to obtain a lease that can be sold on the assignment
market. In any case, there is no suggestion in the statute that an
applicant’s willingness to pay more should entitle him to priority over
the other qualified applicants, all o f whom seek a place in line.4 Con
gress has mandated that the lease should be awarded not to the person
who is willing to pay the most, but to the person “first making applica
tion.” In complying with that mandate the Department has long taken
the position that all applicants should be given an “equal chance” for a
lease. The single application rule was adopted for that very reason.
That interpretation of the statute has been approved by the courts, see
M cK ay v. Wahlenmaier, 226 F.2d 35 (D.C. Cir. 1955); and it has been
tacitly accepted by Congress, a fact noted in our previous memoran
dum.
Without further legislation, the question of authorization is made
more problematic by the statutory prohibition against “lotteries.” We
must construe the Acts of Congress harmoniously where such a con
struction is possible. Implied amendments or repeals are disfavored, and
that principle is relevant here. It is one thing to conclude, as the court
concluded in Thor-Westcliffe Development, Inc. v. Udall, supra, that
Congress has impliedly authorized the Secretary to pick randomly
among a crowd of applicants when he has no more effective means of
determining who is “first” while maintaining order in the queue; but it
is quite another to conclude that Congress has impliedly authorized a
system to multiple filings that would bear not only a formal, but also a
substantive resemblance to devices that Congress has condemned in
other legislation. Through the criminal statutes Congress has sought to
suppress lotteries designed to tax the public and to enrich the “promot
ers.” A multiple filing system would tax lease applicants by making
their chances depend on the size of their payments; and it could enrich
the government, depending on the actual cost of administrative system
3T he statute suggests that virtually any citizen o f the United States is “qualified” to hold a lease,
subject to certain statutory ceilings on aggregate lease holdings. See 30 U.S.C. §§ 181 and 184. The
relevant regulations reflect that interpretation of the statute. See 43 C.F.R. § 3102 1 et seq.
4T he legislative history of th e leasing statute is consistent with the view that the size of an
applicant's payments should not entitle him to priority T he lease system replaced the old system of
prospecting permits for land containing no known deposits o f oil and gas; yet in replacing the old
system. Congress ultimately declined to subject the new prospecting leases to competitive bidding.
Congress thereby preserved the central feature o f the prospecting system—the preference given to the
“ first” claimant, whatever his financial resources. See Act o f August 21, 1935, ch. 599, 49 Stat. 674; see
also 79 Cong Rec. S12075 (July 30, 1935) (remarks of Senator Pittman); see also Act of August 8,
1946, ch 916, § 3, 60 Stat. 951; see also S. Rep. No. 1392, 79th Cong., 2d Sess. (1946).
156
and the number of chances purchased by the applicants in a particular
case. Since, as we noted in our earlier memorandum, Congress was
concerned with the moral issues presented by schemes in which persons
are encouraged to risk their resources on the chance of a windfall, we
are concerned that a multiple filing system would appear to do pre
cisely that and might therefore be considered a violation of the anti
lottery laws. In general, the more closely the leasing system resembles
otherwise prohibited lotteries, the more difficult it becomes to sustain
the system under the leasing statute, for the leasing statute cannot
authorize an otherwise prohibited lottery without impliedly amending
the criminal statutes pro tanto.
2. Single filing, increased fee. You have asked whether any legal
difficulty would be presented by a simple increase in the $10 filing fee.
We understand from conversations with officials in your Department
that under the options now being considered, the increase would be
justified by the increased cost of administering the SOG procedures.
Congress has declared generally that any “privilege, authority, use,
franchise, license, permit, certificate, registration or similar thing of
value” issued by a federal agency shall be “self-sustaining to the full
extent possible”; and to that end Congress has authorized the head of
each federal agency to prescribe uniform fees to be charged in connec
tion with the issuance of “things of value.” See 131 U.S.C. § 483a. In
fixing the amount of such a fee, the agency head is entitled to take into
account a number of factors, including the direct and indirect cost to
the government, the value of the thing to the recipient, and the public
policy or interest to be served in charging the fee. Id.
We are unaware of any specific statutory limitation that would super
sede this general authority in the case of fees charged for SOG applica
tions. In the absence of a specific statutory limitation, we believe the
Secretary is authorized by 31 U.S.C. § 483a to increase the present $10
fee to a level that more adequately reflects the actual cost of adminis
tering the SOG system, a system which, in its present form, is author
ized by the leasing statute. We do not believe that an increase would be
held to violate the anti-lottery laws if it is rationally related to the
administrative costs by the system and to the purpose of finding quali
fied applicants, and is not adopted for the purpose of enriching the
federal government.
T h e o d o r e B. O l s o n
Assistant Attorney General
Office o f Legal Counsel
157