T.C. Memo. 2000-10
UNITED STATES TAX COURT
JOHN T. JORGL AND SHARON ILLI, Petitioners v.
COMMISSIONER OF INTERNAL REVENUE, Respondent
Docket No. 11508-98. Filed January 11, 2000.
Ps, husband and wife, operated a child care business of
which P husband was the sole shareholder. P subsequently
established a charitable remainder unitrust and contributed
all of his shares in the child care business to the trust.
The trust later sold the business and received all proceeds
of the sale. The purchase agreement between the trust and
the buyers contained a covenant not to compete, and Ps
signed a separate document entitled “COVENANT NOT TO
COMPETE” at the time of sale. Ps reported no income as a
result of this transaction, and R determined a deficiency
for taxes attributable to the portion of the sale price
allocated to a covenant not to compete.
Held: Execution of a noncompetition agreement resulted
in taxable income to Ps to the extent of the purchase price
attributable thereto. Although the trust received all
proceeds of the sale, Ps were the true earners of the
income. Commissioner v. Sunnen, 333 U.S. 591, 604 (1948)
and Lucas v. Earl, 281 U.S. 111, 114-115 (1930), applied.
- 2 -
The intentions of the parties involved in the transaction
and the economic reality of Ps’ covenant render a portion of
the consideration paid properly allocable to their promise.
Held, further, Ps, relying upon professional advisers,
acted reasonably and in good faith with respect to their tax
treatment of the sale transaction and are not liable for the
accuracy-related penalty under sec. 6662, I.R.C., for a
substantial understatement of income tax.
William J. Mitchell and Kevin P. Courtney, for petitioners.
Steven Walker, for respondent.
MEMORANDUM FINDINGS OF FACT AND OPINION
NIMS, Judge: Respondent determined a Federal income tax
deficiency for petitioners’ 1993 taxable year in the amount of
$120,439. Respondent also determined an accuracy-related penalty
of $24,088 for 1993, pursuant to section 6662(a).
The issues for decision are as follows:
(1) Whether the sale of a business by a charitable remainder
unitrust resulted in taxable income to petitioners by reason of a
covenant not to compete executed in connection with the sale; and
(2) whether petitioners are liable for the section 6662(a)
accuracy-related penalty on account of a substantial
understatement of income tax.
- 3 -
Unless otherwise indicated, all section references are to
sections of the Internal Revenue Code in effect for the year in
issue, and all Rule references are to the Tax Court Rules of
Practice and Procedure.
FINDINGS OF FACT
Some of the facts have been stipulated and are so found.
The stipulations of the parties, with accompanying exhibits, are
incorporated herein by this reference.
John T. Jorgl and Sharon Illi (petitioners) are married and
resided in Orange Park, Florida, at the time of filing their
petition in this case.
The Business--Little Rascals Child Care Centers, Inc.
Mr. Jorgl (petitioner) collaborated with Ms. Melanie Biggs
to found a licensed day care center and school in Sunnyvale,
California. An architect by profession, petitioner designed the
facility. The business was incorporated under the laws of
California in June of 1980 as Little Rascals Child Care Centers,
Inc. (Little Rascals), and opened the following September.
Petitioner and Ms. Biggs also founded a second child care center
in Milpitas, California, which was sold in 1986 or 1987.
In 1985, petitioner purchased the stock owned by Ms. Biggs
in Little Rascals and became the sole shareholder. He maintained
an office on the center’s premises, managed the business
operations of the enterprise, served as president, and was a
- 4 -
member of the board of directors. Petitioner Ms. Illi became
director of the school as well as a corporate officer. Both were
employees of the corporation and were compensated for their
services.
Little Rascals provided child care and development services
for children ranging in age from 3 months to school age. Such
services included direct care and supervision; resource and
referral programs; and instructional programs in academics,
social skills, arts, and athletics. The center met all
governmental requirements for licensing and had an excellent
reputation in the community as a quality child care center.
Petitioners developed and maintained close interpersonal
relationships with parents, teachers, and staff. This hands-on
approach engendered a trust and confidence which frequently led
parents to return with their later children.
Transfer of the Business to a Charitable Unitrust
In November of 1990, petitioners met with attorney Richard
Polse and informed him that they were considering the sale of the
Little Rascals business and were interested in achieving estate
planning and charitable giving goals. Petitioners were concerned
with establishing an income source for support during retirement
years. They also desired to contribute to Project Grant a Wish
after witnessing the generosity of the charity toward a child in
their center who had died of leukemia. Mr. Polse advised
- 5 -
petitioners of the way in which a charitable remainder unitrust
could facilitate these aims. He, as well as petitioners’
accountant, Tim Kehl, also explained the tax consequences of such
an arrangement.
Petitioners decided to form a charitable remainder unitrust,
and the trust instrument was prepared by Mr. Polse. Petitioners
were designated as the income beneficiaries of the Jorgl Unitrust
(the trust), and Project Grant a Wish was named the charitable
remainder beneficiary. For their lifetimes, petitioners were to
receive annual distributions totaling the lesser of the trust
income for the taxable year or 9 percent of the fair market value
of the trust assets. The trust was irrevocable, and petitioners
were given no rights to or control over trust assets beyond
receipt of the above-specified distributions. Following their
deaths, the trust would terminate and Project Grant a Wish would
receive the trust corpus. Cupertino National Bank was named as
the trustee.
On June 26, 1991, petitioner as grantor and Cupertino
National Bank as trustee executed a “Charitable Remainder
Unitrust Agreement”. On June 27, 1991, the stock certificate
transferring all of petitioner’s shares in Little Rascals to
Cupertino National Bank as trustee for the Jorgl Unitrust was
signed. Petitioners continued to serve as employees, officers,
and directors of Little Rascals.
- 6 -
Sale of the Business to the Shahs
A meeting of the Little Rascals board of directors was held
on June 27, 1991. The board resolved to proceed with having the
corporation listed for sale with a business broker, subject to
the signing of the listing by the trustee owner. The brokerage
firm so engaged subsequently prepared an extensive prospectus to
market Little Rascals. This document erroneously stated that the
center “was established in 1980 by the current owner, an
architect”. One of the “TERMS” recited in the document was
“COVENANT 5 years 100 miles”.
In early 1993, this prospectus was presented to Divyesh and
Priti Shah by Art Withop, their business broker. The Shahs
understood from reading the prospectus that the current owner was
an architect and the founder of the center, and that the covenant
was being offered by him. The Shahs and their broker met with
petitioners and the listing broker in April of 1993 to discuss
the possible sale of the business. After a series of offers and
counteroffers passing between the brokers, the Shahs prepared a
“Purchase Agreement for Corporate Stock”. It was at this time
that they first learned of the existence of the trust. The
trustee had not been involved in prior meetings or in the
negotiation of the sale price. On May 24, 1993, Mr. Shah
executed the purchase agreement as “buyer”, and on May 26, 1993,
- 7 -
an officer of Cupertino National Bank as trustee for the Jorgl
Unitrust signed as “seller”. Petitioners were neither named in
nor signatories to this document.
The purchase agreement designated $650,000 as the “purchase
price of the stock and any covenant not to compete”. Paragraph
16 then contained the following language regarding a covenant not
to compete:
COVENANT NOT TO COMPETE: For a period of 5 consecutive
years from COE [closing of the agreed escrow], seller
shall not directly or indirectly carry on a similar
business within a radius of 100 miles of the business
being sold, nor assist anyone else except the
corporation and buyer to do so within these limits: nor
shall seller have any interest, directly or indirectly,
in such business, except as an employee of the business
being sold. Paragraph 19 will not prevent injunctive
relief to enforce this covenant pending arbitration.
Any part of the purchase price to be allocated to this
covenant shall be agreed upon by the parties and
submitted to escrow prior to COE.
In addition, a handwritten amendment stating “and officers” was
inserted by the Shahs’ broker after the first “seller” in the
printed paragraph.
Mr. Shah subsequently drafted a covenant not to compete for
petitioners and the Shahs to sign. When Mr. Shah then called
petitioner to inform him that the draft had been prepared,
petitioner requested that the document be sent to his attorney,
Mr. Kehl, for review. On July 29, 1993, Mr. Kehl received a fax
of a noncompetition agreement “between John Jorgl and Sharon Illi
* * * and Divyesh P. Shah and Priti D. Shah”. Mr. Kehl advised
- 8 -
petitioners not to sign the document in the form presented. He
told petitioners that “they would be okay with signing it if the
Shahs’ name [sic] were removed”. Thereafter, in a subsequent
draft, Mr. Shah deleted any reference to himself and his wife.
This latter document provided that instead of not competing with
the Shahs, petitioners would not compete with Little Rascals.
The closing of the sale took place on July 30, 1993, in San
Jose, California. Closing documents signed by the Shahs and the
trustee stated: “Purchase price of stock (pay to Seller):
350,000.00" and “Purchase price of Covenant Not to Compete (pay
to Seller): 300,000.00". Also at the closing, petitioners alone
signed a separate document entitled “COVENANT NOT TO COMPETE” and
reading in its entirety as follows:
This agreement is between John Jorgl and Sharon Illi,
who were officer’s [sic] of Little Rascals Child Care
Centers, Inc. and Little Rascals Child Care Centers,
Inc. regarding the sale of Little Rascals Child Care
Centers signed on the 30th of July, 1993.
The agreement is as follows:
1) John Jorgl and Sharon Illi will not compete with
Little Rascals in the preschool/day care/school age
children business; nor assist anyone else except the
corporation and the buyer of Little Rascals within
limits defined herein; nor have any interest, directly
or indirectly, in such business except as an employee
of the business being sold for a total of 5 consecutive
years within a 100 mile radius of the business (Little
Rascals).
- 9 -
2) John Jorgl and Sharon Illi are signing this document
with full understanding that competing with Little
Rascals would be a breach of contract and both John and
Sharon could be severly [sic] liable.
The Shahs discussed their reasons for the above document
during the closing, expressing concern that petitioners might
personally open another child care center, yet all sales
instruments were being signed by the bank on behalf of the trust.
Petitioners had indicated that they were leaving the area to
travel, but the Shahs perceived the possibility of petitioners’
returning and using their reputation to start another center as a
continuing threat. Petitioners were 50 and 37 years of age and
in good health at the time of the sale. Although petitioners
viewed the separate covenant as a voluntary accommodation to the
Shahs, they signed in good faith and have never engaged in
proscribed competitive activities. They departed from California
shortly after the closing and have since resided elsewhere.
The $300,000 allocated to a covenant not to compete was
never discussed. Mr. Shah calculated the value and had it
included in the closing documents. None involved objected, so no
negotiations took place. Mr. Shah prepared a document basing the
value of the covenant not to compete on tuition that would be
lost if 10 to 15 children left the center due to competition.
His computations resulted in a $600,000 figure which he then
multiplied by a 50-percent “fudge factor”. He was aware that, as
buyer, allocating value to a covenant not to compete would be
- 10 -
advantageous from a tax standpoint. For reasons undisclosed at
trial, respondent now concedes that the value of the covenant was
$200,000 and not $300,000 as allocated in the closing statements.
The full $650,000 price was deposited directly from escrow into
the trust’s account, and petitioners received no additional
compensation for signing the separate document.
Following the closing, the Shahs received from petitioners
the business training referenced in the prospectus and the
purchase agreement. The prospectus had indicated that “TRAINING
2 weeks @ 20 hrs.” was included in the sale price. Section 15 of
the purchase agreement similarly stated: “TRAINING: Seller
shall train buyer in the operation of the business”. On August
14, 1993, petitioners sent a letter to memorialize completion of
this training which reads in part: “As of August 13, 1993,
Sharon has completed the training with Priti in accordance with
the requirements of our Purchase Agreement dated May 24, 1993,
Section 15.”
Petitioners’ Federal income tax return for 1993 did not
reflect any income as a consequence of the above transactions.
OPINION
We must decide whether the sale of a business operated by
petitioners, after petitioner had transferred all stock in the
- 11 -
business to a charitable remainder unitrust, resulted in taxable
income to petitioners by reason of a covenant not to compete
executed at the time of the sale.
Petitioners contend that because ownership of the business
had been irrevocably transferred to the trust, because they were
not parties to the purchase agreement between the trust and the
buyers, and because the trust received the entire proceeds of the
sale, the covenant not to compete contained in such agreement can
have no tax consequences for them. Petitioners further assert
that the separate document entitled “COVENANT NOT TO COMPETE” was
signed by them only as an accommodation and cannot result in
taxable income because it is without true economic value,
unsupported by consideration, and unenforceable under California
covenant law.
Conversely, respondent argues that the portion of the
purchase price attributable to a covenant not to compete is
taxable to petitioners. Respondent contends that because
petitioners executed a personal covenant in conjunction with the
sale of the Little Rascals business and because they, not the
trust, posed the only real threat of competition, they cannot
escape tax on the income apportioned to such a covenant by
anticipatorily assigning that income to the trust. Respondent
- 12 -
also alleges that the covenant has significant economic value, is
supported by consideration, and is enforceable under California
covenant law.
We conclude that a portion of the consideration paid can
properly be allocated to the promise made by petitioners. The
intentions of the parties involved in the transaction and the
economic reality of petitioners’ agreement support such an
allocation. Hence, petitioners must be deemed to have earned
income by agreeing not to compete and to have anticipatorily
assigned such income to the trust. They therefore are required
to recognize taxable income, to the extent of the value of the
covenant, in connection with the sale of Little Rascals.
Deficiency Issue
General Rules
As a general rule, section 61 defines gross income as “all
income from whatever source derived”. Case law then specifies
that consideration paid for a covenant not to compete is included
within this broad definition. See, e.g., Sonnleitner v.
Commissioner, 598 F.2d 464, 466 (5th Cir. 1979), affg. T.C. Memo.
1976-249; Montesi v. Commissioner, 340 F.2d 97, 100 (6th Cir.
1965), affg. 40 T.C. 511 (1963). A charitable remainder
unitrust, however, is not subject to income tax by reason of
section 664(c) unless it has unrelated business income, which is
not the case here.
- 13 -
In the present matter, the parties do not contest these
basic propositions but differ as to whether any portion of the
purchase price received by the trust can be attributed and taxed
to petitioners on the grounds of a covenant not to compete.
Because all payments flowing from the sale of the Little Rascals
business were made directly to the trust, and because respondent
does not contend that the trust failed to satisfy the
requirements set forth in section 664 for the creation of a valid
charitable remainder unitrust, resolution of this question turns
on whether petitioners can be said to have actually earned
income, which they anticipatorily assigned to the trust, by
reason of a promise not to compete.
The principle that substance should govern over form is well
established in tax law. See, e.g., Higgins v. Smith, 308 U.S.
473, 477 (1940); Turner Broad. Sys., Inc. & Subs. v.
Commissioner, 111 T.C. 315, 326 (1998); Palmer v. Commissioner,
62 T.C. 684, 691 (1974), affd. 523 F.2d 1308 (8th Cir. 1975). A
corollary to this principle is the assignment of income theory,
under which mere assignment of a right to receive income is
insufficient to insulate the assignor from tax liability. See,
e.g., Commissioner v. Sunnen, 333 U.S. 591, 604 (1948); Lucas v.
Earl, 281 U.S. 111, 114-115 (1930); Palmer v. Commissioner, supra
at 692. The true earner of income must bear the tax
consequences. See, e.g., Commissioner v. Sunnen, supra at 604;
- 14 -
Lucas v. Earl, supra at 114-115; Palmer v. Commissioner, supra at
692. Thus, if a portion of the consideration paid for Little
Rascals is properly allocable to petitioners’ promise, they will
be deemed to have assigned to the trust income they earned by
agreeing not to compete.
In determining whether such a “tax-enforceable” allocation
to a covenant has been or should be made, courts have articulated
various standards for evaluating sales agreements. See Lazisky
v. Commissioner, 72 T.C. 495, 500-502 (1979), affd. sub nom.
Magnolia Surf, Inc. v. Commissioner, 636 F.2d 11 (1st Cir. 1980).
When a written contract specifies the portion of the purchase
price to be allocated to a covenant not to compete and one of the
parties seeks to deviate therefrom, two tests frequently adhered
to in deciding whether such deviation is warranted are the strong
proof rule and the so-called Danielson rule. See, e.g.,
Commissioner v. Danielson, 378 F.2d 771, 775 (3d Cir. 1967),
vacating and remanding 44 T.C. 549 (1965); Elrod v. Commissioner,
87 T.C. 1046, 1065-1066 (1986); Smith v. Commissioner, 82 T.C.
705, 712-714 (1984); Lazisky v. Commissioner, supra at 500-502.
Under the strong proof rule, a taxpayer attempting to
challenge a contractual allocation must adduce “strong proof”,
meaning more than a preponderance of the evidence, that the terms
of the written instrument do not reflect the actual intentions of
- 15 -
the contracting parties. See, e.g., Elrod v. Commissioner, supra
at 1066; Smith v. Commissioner, supra at 713 n.8. Under the more
stringent Danielson rule,
a party can challenge the tax consequences of his
agreement as construed by the Commissioner only by
adducing proof which in an action between the parties
to the agreement would be admissible to alter that
construction or to show its unenforceability because of
mistake, undue influence, fraud, duress, etc. * * *
[Commissioner v. Danielson, supra at 775.]
This Court typically applies the strong proof rule but will
apply the Danielson rule when the circuit to which appeal would
normally lie has adopted that test. See Golsen v. Commissioner,
54 T.C. 742, 756-757 (1970), affd. 445 F.2d 985 (10th Cir. 1971);
see also Elrod v. Commissioner, supra at 1065-1066; Smith v.
Commissioner, supra at 712 n.6. However, when a contract fails
to make an allocation of purchase price to a covenant not to
compete or does so in an ambiguous manner, neither the strong
proof rule nor the Danielson rule is applicable. See, e.g.,
Elrod v. Commissioner, supra at 1066; Smith v. Commissioner,
supra at 713-714. Instead, the taxpayer must establish by a
preponderance of the evidence that respondent’s determination of
a deficiency is erroneous. See Rule 142(a); Peterson Mach. Tool,
Inc. v. Commissioner, 79 T.C. 72, 81-82 (1982), affd. per order
(10th Cir., April 2, 1984).
There are two primary elements to which the taxpayer’s
burden of proof relates. See Peterson Mach. Tool, Inc. v.
- 16 -
Commissioner, supra at 81. The threshold inquiry is whether the
parties mutually intended that an allocation of purchase price be
made to the covenant at issue. See, e.g., Patterson v.
Commissioner, 810 F.2d 562, 570-571 (6th Cir. 1987), affg. T.C.
Memo. 1985-53; Better Beverages, Inc. v. United States, 619 F.2d
424, 430 (5th Cir. 1980); Peterson Mach. Tool, Inc. v.
Commissioner, supra at 81, 83. Such mutual intent will typically
be deemed to exist where “the parties considered the covenant as
a valuable part of the entire consideration for the agreement.”
Illinois Cereal Mills, Inc. v. Commissioner, T.C. Memo. 1983-469,
affd. 789 F.2d 1234 (7th Cir. 1986). Relevant factors for
ascertaining intent include both the language of the contract
itself and the circumstances surrounding its negotiation. See,
e.g., Patterson v. Commissioner, supra at 570; Peterson Mach.
Tool, Inc. v. Commissioner, supra at 83-84.
If such mutual intent is found, courts then proceed to
evaluate whether an allocation comports with “economic reality”.
See, e.g., Patterson v. Commissioner, supra at 571; Peterson
Mach. Tool, Inc. v. Commissioner, supra at 84. Economic reality
is defined as “‘some independent basis in fact or some arguable
relationship with business reality such that reasonable men,
genuinely concerned with their economic future, might bargain for
such an agreement.’” Patterson v. Commissioner, supra at 571
(quoting Schulz v. Commissioner, 294 F.2d 52, 55 (9th Cir. 1961),
- 17 -
affg. 34 T.C. 235 (1960)). An allocation will generally be given
effect where “the covenants had independent economic significance
such that * * * [the Court] might conclude that they were a
separately bargained-for element of the agreement.” Peterson
Mach. Tool, Inc. v. Commissioner, supra at 81.
Application
The instant case involves two documents purporting to
establish a covenant not to compete: The purchase agreement and
the separate covenant document. Paragraph 16 of the purchase
agreement dated May 24, 1993, is labeled “COVENANT NOT TO
COMPETE”. The printed language of the paragraph states, in
pertinent part, that “seller shall not directly or indirectly
carry on a similar business”. A handwritten amendment “and
officers” has been added after “seller”. The parties to the
agreement are the Shahs, designated as “buyer”, and the Jorgl
Unitrust, designated as “seller”. The agreement was signed by
Mr. Shah and by an officer of Cupertino National Bank as sole
trustee for the Jorgl Unitrust. It was not signed by
petitioners.
Petitioners alone also signed a separate document entitled
“COVENANT NOT TO COMPETE” at the closing on July 30, 1993. This
document states that it is “between John Jorgl and Sharon Illi,
who were officer’s [sic] of Little Rascals Child Care Centers,
- 18 -
Inc. and Little Rascals Child Care Centers, Inc.” It provides
that “John Jorgl and Sharon Illi will not compete with Little
Rascals”.
The allocation of purchase price at issue here was made in a
second pair of documents. The BUYER’S CLOSING STATEMENT, signed
by Mr. Shah, and the SELLER’S CLOSING STATEMENT, signed by the
trustee, each state: “Purchase price of Covenant Not to Compete
(pay to Seller): 300,000.00". The separate covenant document
signed by petitioners makes no reference to price or payment.
The purchase agreement provides that $650,000 is the “purchase
price of the stock and any covenant not to compete”.
Applicability of the Danielson Rule or the Strong Proof Rule
Given this scenario, the first question that must be
addressed is whether either the Danielson rule or the strong
proof rule applies. We note as a threshold matter that appeal
would normally lie to the Court of Appeals for the Eleventh
Circuit, where decisions handed down by the Court of Appeals for
the Fifth Circuit prior to October 1, 1981, are precedential.
See Bonner v. City of Prichard, 661 F.2d 1206, 1209 (11th Cir.
1981). Since the Court of Appeals for the Fifth Circuit adopted
the Danielson rule in Spector v. Commissioner, 641 F.2d 376, 384,
386 (5th Cir. 1981), revg. 71 T.C. 1017 (1979), we shall examine
- 19 -
the above agreements in light of its dictates to the extent
applicable. However, we conclude that ambiguities render
adherence to the Danielson standard inappropriate here.
An allocation of $300,000 to “Covenant Not to Compete” was
made in the closing statements. Yet documents relating to the
transaction can be read, at least facially, as establishing two
such covenants. Both petitioners and the trust, an independent
legal entity, signed agreements apparently promising not to
compete. It is thus unclear from the face of the documents what
part of the price was paid for which promise. Hence, the
relevant instruments do not evidence an unequivocal allocation of
payment to a specific covenant that would justify application of
the Danielson rule or, in the alternative, the strong proof rule.
Petitioners’ burden is therefore to establish by a preponderance
of the evidence that the parties lacked mutual intent to allocate
any portion of the consideration paid to petitioners’ promise or
that the allocation had no basis in economic reality.
Existence of Mutual Intent Regarding Allocation
Having determined the appropriate standard of proof, we next
address the question of whether those involved in the sale
process mutually intended to allocate consideration to the
agreement made by petitioners. As a threshold matter, it should
be noted that to view the separate document signed by petitioners
as entirely independent from and unrelated to the sales
- 20 -
instruments executed by the trust would be to introduce a level
of artificiality warranted neither by the terms of the documents
nor by the attendant circumstances. Although petitioners urge
such a narrow perspective, a reading of all documents together as
evidencing a single, composite transaction appears to be more
consistent with the parties’ mind-sets at the time of the sale.
The purchase agreement makes reference to covenants from
“seller” and, through conscious addition by the buyers’ agent,
“officers”. The agreement further states that $650,000 is the
purchase price for the stock and “any covenant not to compete”
(emphasis added); it does not preclude apportionment to covenants
other than those stated therein. Moreover, the separate covenant
executed by petitioners then explicitly sets forth that it is an
agreement “regarding the sale of Little Rascals Child Care
Centers signed on the 30th of July, 1993.” It thus seems
reasonable to construe the separate document as carrying out the
“and officers” annotation in the purchase agreement.
In addition, the letter written by petitioners to the Shahs
only 2 weeks after the sale reveals that they did not view the
components of the transaction with the degree of isolation for
which they now contend. The letter reads: “As of August 13,
1993, Sharon has completed the training with Priti in accordance
with the requirements of our Purchase Agreement dated May 24,
1993, Section 15.” The use of “our Purchase Agreement”, combined
- 21 -
with the fact that section 15 says “TRAINING: Seller shall train
buyer”, indicates that petitioners saw themselves as material
participants in aspects of the sale other than their separate
agreement not to compete. They also apparently recognized that,
legal obligations aside, only they could meaningfully act upon
certain provisions in the unique situation where a commercial
bank sells a child care center. A similar inference can be drawn
from the fact that only petitioners, and not the trustee, were
involved in the meetings and negotiations with the Shahs which
preceded the signing of the purchase agreement. Hence, in
seeking to ascertain the parties’ intentions with respect to
price allocation, we likewise shall view the various participants
and documents as interrelated parts of an overall transaction.
Turning then to the substantive issue of mutual intent, we
conclude, again by reference to both written instruments and
attendant circumstances, that neither the documents themselves
nor the surrounding negotiations negate the existence of such
intent. The language used (1) in the prospectus advertising
Little Rascals for sale, (2) in the purchase agreement, and (3)
in the separate covenant document is in each case consistent with
an understanding that a noncompetition agreement from petitioners
was to form a component of the sales price. The prospectus
describes the business as “established in 1980 by the current
owner, an architect”, makes no mention of the trust, states the
- 22 -
asking price, and lists “COVENANT 5 years 100 miles” under
“TERMS”. The purchase agreement, as indicated above, has been
amended to make reference to a covenant from “officers” and sets
forth the total price of the stock and “any covenant”. The
separate covenant document identifies that it is an agreement
“regarding the sale of Little Rascals”. These three instruments,
collectively, thus cannot sustain petitioners’ burden of proving
that no part of the $300,000 allocated to “Covenant Not to
Compete” in the closing statements was intended as consideration
for petitioners’ promise.
Furthermore, the surrounding negotiations and circumstances
do not require a different conclusion. Although the prospectus
was technically erroneous, Mr. Shah testified that he understood
the document to mean that petitioner, as founder and seller, was
offering the covenant. Petitioners did nothing to correct Mr.
Shah’s understanding throughout the initial negotiations premised
on the prospectus, and the Shahs were not made aware of the
existence of the trust until the purchase agreement was drafted.
Petitioners subsequently did not object to the addition of the
“and officers” language to the purchase agreement. Their
reference to “our Purchase Agreement dated May 24, 1993, Section
15" in the letter they sent to the Shahs shortly after the sale,
however, shows that they had read the agreement and were aware of
its terms. They then complied with the Shahs’ request to execute
- 23 -
a separate covenant not to compete despite this awareness of the
terms of a purchase agreement which contemplated allocation of
price to the stock and to any covenant. Moreover, they signed
their covenant at the closing where statements explicitly
allocating $300,000 to a covenant not to compete were executed,
so if they did not in fact read these closing documents, they
certainly had the opportunity to do so.
In addition, petitioners were aware at the time they signed
that it was their agreement, not the trust’s, upon which the
Shahs placed importance. Petitioners’ own witness testified that
the Shahs’ concerns about competition from petitioners and
reasons for the separate covenant were discussed at the closing.
Hence, petitioners had reason to realize that any significant
value the Shahs paid for a covenant not to compete would be
attributable to their promise, not to that given by the trust.
In that context, they executed a covenant document. In these
circumstances, knowledge of a purchase contract which
contemplated an allocation of price to a covenant not to compete,
combined with knowledge that their agreement was the only such
covenant of substantial importance to the buyer, adds up to the
type of objective contractual intent to allocate necessary for an
allocation to be given effect.
- 24 -
The fact that petitioners did not intend to be taxed on
their agreement and sought to avoid that result by refusing to
permit the document they signed to refer to the buyers is
irrelevant. As explained by this Court:
What is important in the facts herein is whether the
sellers intended that the covenants actually be a part
of the agreement (i.e., whether * * * [the buyer]
slipped the covenants into the contract without their
knowledge). The facts unquestionably show that the
sellers were aware of the terms. Moreover, the sellers
were represented by counsel who read the contract and
approved of its contents. That the sellers and/or
their counsel did not intend, and were not aware of,
the tax consequences of the disputed language is not
significant. As stated in Hamlin’s Trust v.
Commissioner, 209 F.2d 761, 765 (10th Cir. 1954), affg.
19 T.C. 718 (1953):
It is true that there was very little
discussion of the suggested allocation. But
the effectiveness taxwise of an agreement is
not measured by the amount of preliminary
discussion had respecting it. It is enough
if parties understand the contract and
understandingly enter into it. * * * where
parties enter into an agreement with a clear
understanding of its substance and content,
they cannot be heard to say later that they
overlooked possible tax consequences. * * *
[Peterson Mach. Tool, Inc. v. Commissioner, 79 T.C. 72,
83-84 (1982).]
Here, petitioners intended that their covenants be a part of
the overall sale transaction, they understood from the contents
of the documents that they were promising not to compete and that
consideration was being allocated to a covenant not to compete,
and they knew that in substance the buyers attributed importance
to their agreement. These facts regarding the actions of
- 25 -
petitioners and the Shahs convince us that there existed, on the
part of petitioners, either a subjective intent to allocate or,
at the very least, a conscious acquiescence in the allocation
proposed by the Shahs, both of which will support a finding of
objective contractual intent. We therefore conclude that
petitioners have failed to carry their burden of showing that
those involved in the Little Rascals transaction did not mutually
intend that an allocation of purchase price be made to their
agreement.
Economic Reality of Allocation
The question then becomes whether such an intended
allocation must nonetheless be disregarded because it would lack
economic reality. However, petitioners’ past performance, their
present ability, and the actual negotiations reveal a separately
bargained-for agreement with a sufficient nexus to prudent
business practice to conclude that their agreement had
independent economic significance.
As to past performance, petitioner had founded two day care
centers and had approximately 13 years of experience in the
business. Little Rascals was uncontestedly a successful
enterprise with an excellent reputation. Petitioners had
developed close interpersonal relationships with parents,
teachers, and staff. In addition, their hands-on approach to
- 26 -
involvement in the child care business had often resulted in
repeat patronage, as parents returned to enroll younger siblings.
With regard to present ability, petitioners were only 50 and
37 years of age and in good health at the time of the sale.
Furthermore, although petitioners mentioned that they planned to
travel following the sale, they did not indicate a permanent
departure from the geographic area.
Given these circumstances, a prudent business person might
reasonably perceive competition from petitioners as a threat to
the continued success of Little Rascals, and negotiations related
to the sale reveal that the Shahs did in fact have such a
concern. Beginning with the conscious addition of the “and
officers” language to the purchase agreement and continuing
through the requests for a separately executed covenant and the
discussion of its importance at the closing, the record bears
repeated evidence of the independent significance placed by the
Shahs on this covenant. Mr. Shah even testified that he would
not have gone through with the sale absent such an agreement.
Hence, petitioners’ covenant was in fact a critical and
separately bargained-for component of the transaction. When
faced with the unusual scenario of a bank trustee selling a child
care center, the Shahs prudently sought some form of assurance
from the founder, operators, and true threat of competition.
- 27 -
In contrast, an allocation of price to the covenant entered
by the trust would lack economic reality. As an officer of the
bank testified, the bank lacked the expertise and credentials to
open a competing child care center. Moreover, such a move would
likely be otherwise precluded by the bank’s fiduciary duties as
trustee, thus making the agreement superfluous. Finally, no
facts indicate that the Shahs placed significance on or
separately bargained for a promise from the trust.
Therefore, of the two potential covenants to which
consideration could be allocated, it appears that only an
apportionment to petitioners’ agreement would have a basis in
economic reality. It is also to be noted that whether an
agreement is enforceable under State law is not necessarily
determinative of tax consequences when the record shows that the
buyer in fact bargained and paid for a covenant. See Standard
Lumber & Hardware Co. v. Commissioner, T.C. Memo. 1958-159. When
faced with a situation where the Commissioner attempted to
disallow a buyer’s deductions taken for payments attributed to a
covenant not to compete, on grounds that the covenant would be
void under State law, this Court responded:
The Commissioner argues that an oral agreement not
to compete for 5 years would be void in Colorado. The
Commissioner cites no authority for his contention that
the deduction would not be allowable if the agreement
could not be enforced. * * * The fact is that a large
sum was actually paid on this arm’s-length agreement
and the evidence indicates that the agreement was
carried out. [Id.]
- 28 -
Consequently, we need not reach the parties’ contentions
here regarding the enforceability of a covenant against
petitioners. In unusual circumstances, such as those present in
this case, seeking even an unenforceable agreement made in good
faith may be consistent with prudent business practice. This is
particularly true where, as here, the issue of enforceability is
debatable and arguments exist to support both sides.
Furthermore, since the Shahs apparently assumed that petitioners
were bound by their signatures, it is also reasonable to believe
that the Shahs in fact bargained and paid for petitioners’
promise. We therefore conclude that petitioners have failed to
carry their burden of establishing that an allocation of any
value to their covenant not to compete would be devoid of
economic reality.
Amount of Allocation
Where, as here, an allocation of some value has been found
to comport with economic reality in a general sense, the final
question necessary to resolve a deficiency issue asks what
specific amount of the consideration paid should be allocated to
the subject agreement. We note that the amount allocated to a
covenant by a taxpayer is not always controlling for tax
purposes. See Lemery v. Commissioner, 52 T.C. 367, 375 (1969),
affd. 451 F.2d 173 (9th Cir. 1971).
- 29 -
In the matter at hand, closing statements apportioned
$300,000, based on calculations by Mr. Shah, to a covenant not to
compete. Respondent now concedes on brief that the proper
valuation is $200,000. Petitioners have offered no evidence by
which a different value may be calculated and have instead merely
contended that the proper value is zero. Although we agree with
petitioners that the valuations computed by Mr. Shah and
respondent are in some respects arbitrary, we have decided that
allocation of some value to petitioners’ agreement is appropriate
and have not been given sufficient information upon which to base
an alternative measurement. We therefore sustain the deficiency
based upon the $200,000 value advocated by respondent.
Penalty Issue
Section 6662(a) and (b)(2) imposes an accuracy-related
penalty in the amount of 20 percent of any underpayment that is
attributable to a substantial understatement of income tax. A
“substantial understatement” is defined by section 6662(d)(1) to
exist where the amount of the understatement exceeds the greater
of 10 percent of the tax required to be shown on the return for
the taxable year or $5,000.
An exception to the section 6662(a) penalty is set forth in
section 6664(c)(1) and reads: “No penalty shall be imposed under
this part with respect to any portion of an underpayment if it is
shown that there was a reasonable cause for such portion and that
- 30 -
the taxpayer acted in good faith with respect to such portion.”
The taxpayer bears the burden of establishing that this
reasonable cause exception is applicable, as respondent’s
determination of an accuracy-related penalty is presumed correct.
See Rule 142(a).
Regulations interpreting section 6664(c) state:
The determination of whether a taxpayer acted with
reasonable cause and in good faith is made on a case-
by-case basis, taking into account all pertinent facts
and circumstances. * * * Generally, the most important
factor is the extent of the taxpayer’s effort to assess
the taxpayer’s proper tax liability. * * * [Sec.
1.6664-4(b)(1), Income Tax. Regs.]
Furthermore, reliance upon the advice of a tax professional
may, but does not necessarily, demonstrate reasonable cause and
good faith for purposes of avoiding the section 6662(a) penalty.
See id.; see also Freytag v. Commissioner, 89 T.C. 849, 888
(1987), affd. 904 F.2d 1011 (5th Cir. 1990), affd. 501 U.S. 868
(1991). Such reliance is not an absolute defense, but it is a
factor to be considered. See Freytag v. Commissioner, supra at
888. In order for this factor to be given dispositive weight,
the taxpayer claiming reliance on a tax professional must show,
at minimum, that (1) the adviser was supplied with correct
information and (2) the incorrect return was a result of the
adviser’s error. See, e.g., Ma-Tran Corp. v. Commissioner, 70
- 31 -
T.C. 158, 173 (1978); Pessin v. Commissioner, 59 T.C. 473, 489
(1972); Garcia v. Commissioner, T.C. Memo. 1998-203, affd.
without published opinion 190 F.3d 538 (5th Cir. 1999).
Applying these principles to the instant case, we conclude
that petitioners have sustained their burden of establishing
reasonable cause and good faith for their failure to report
income related to the Little Rascals transaction. Petitioners
consulted with both their attorney, Mr. Polse, and their
accountant, Mr. Kehl, regarding tax implications prior to forming
the charitable remainder unitrust. Furthermore, Mr. Polse
suggested and drafted the trust agreement only after being
apprised by petitioners of their goals and intentions with regard
to the sale of their business. In addition, petitioners signed
the separate covenant document only after it had been reviewed by
Mr. Kehl and modified to comply with his specifications.
Petitioners were thus clearly relying on professional advisers
throughout the transfer of their business, and these
professionals were supplied both with subjective information such
as financial goals and with objective data such as physical
documentation. Finally, we note that reported decisions
addressing treatment of noncompetition agreements generally
involve a case-by-case analysis of intentions and offer few
bright lines to guide taxpayers and tax practitioners. Given
- 32 -
these circumstances, we hold that petitioners acted reasonably
and in good faith reliance on their advisers. Respondent’s
determination of an accuracy-related penalty is denied.
Decision will be entered
under Rule 155.