National Religious Broadcasters Noncommercial Music License Committee v. CRB

United States Court of Appeals FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT Argued February 17, 2023 Decided July 28, 2023 No. 21-1243 NATIONAL RELIGIOUS BROADCASTERS NONCOMMERCIAL MUSIC LICENSE COMMITTEE, APPELLANT v. COPYRIGHT ROYALTY BOARD AND LIBRARIAN OF CONGRESS, APPELLEES GOOGLE LLC, ET AL., INTERVENORS Consolidated with 21-1244, 21-1245 On Appeals from a Final Determination of the Copyright Royalty Board Samir Deger-Sen argued the cause for appellant National Association of Broadcasters. With him on the briefs were Joseph R. Wetzel, Andrew M. Gass, Sarang V. Damle, and Blake E. Stafford. 2 Karyn K. Ablin argued the cause and filed the briefs for appellant National Religious Broadcasters Noncommercial Music License Committee. John J. Bursch, Rory T. Gray, and Erin M. Hawley entered appearances. Matthew S. Hellman argued the cause and filed the briefs for appellant SoundExchange, Inc. Previn Warren entered an appearance. Jennifer L. Utrecht, Attorney, U.S. Department of Justice, argued the cause for appellees. With her on the brief were Michael D. Granston, Deputy Assistant Attorney General, and Daniel Tenny, Attorney. David P. Mattern argued the cause for intervenors Google LLC, et al. in support of appellees. With him on the brief were Sarang V. Damle, Blake E. Stafford, Kenneth L. Steinthal, Joseph R. Wetzel, Andrew M. Gass, Samir Deger-Sen, Joshua N. Mitchell, and Karyn K. Ablin. John J. Bursch, Jason B. Cunningham, Rory T. Gray, and Erin M. Hawley entered appearances. Matthew S. Hellman was on the brief for intervenor SoundExchange, Inc. in support of appellees. Previn Warren entered an appearance. Before: MILLETT, WILKINS, and PAN, Circuit Judges. Opinion for the Court filed PER CURIAM. Every five years, the Copyright Royalty Board (the “Board”) issues a statutory license that establishes the terms and rates under which certain entities that stream copyrighted songs over the internet make royalty payments to the songs’ copyright owners. The “webcasters” that are subject to the 3 license are “noninteractive” — i.e., they stream music without letting their listeners choose songs on demand. This appeal challenges on various grounds the Board’s most recent noninteractive webcaster license Final Determination, covering calendar years 2021 through 2025. We sustain the Board’s Final Determination in all respects. I The Copyright Act, 17 U.S.C. § 101 et seq., provides the statutory framework for regulating copyrights. Under that framework, a recorded song has two components with distinct rights: (1) the “musical work,” which is the song’s underlying composition (i.e., the lyrics and melody); and (2) the “sound recording,” which is a recorded version of the song. See SoundExchange, Inc. v. Copyright Royalty Board, 904 F.3d 41, 46 (D.C. Cir. 2018). Historically, the owner of a musical work had an exclusive right of public performance but the owner of a sound recording did not. SoundExchange, 904 F.3d at 46. Thus, an FM radio station could broadcast a sound recording without permission from its copyright owner. But in 1995, Congress amended the Copyright Act to grant sound-recording owners the exclusive right of public performance “by means of a digital audio transmission.” Digital Performance Right in Sound Recordings Act of 1995, Pub. L. No. 104-39, § 2, 109 Stat. 336, 336 (codified at 17 U.S.C. § 106(6)). Under the amended statute, a webcaster cannot stream a sound recording without paying royalties to its copyright owner. In defining the scope of this new right, Congress distinguished between webcasters (also known as “digital audio services”) that are “interactive” and “noninteractive.” Interactive services let users choose the particular songs they 4 want to listen to on demand, e.g., Spotify, while noninteractive services do not, e.g., Pandora. See 17 U.S.C. § 114(j)(7). Interactive webcasters must contract directly with copyright owners to obtain public performance rights for their sound recordings. Id. § 114(d)(2)(A)(i). By contrast, Congress tasked the Copyright Royalty Board with creating a compulsory license covering the use of sound recordings by all noninteractive webcasters. Id. § 114(f)(1). The license is “compulsory” because copyright owners cannot opt out of it unless they negotiate individual settlement agreements with noninteractive webcasters. Id. §§ 114(f)(1)–(2). Royalties under the compulsory license are paid to a “nonprofit collective,” which distributes the funds to performing artists or other copyright owners. Id. § 114(g)(2). Meanwhile, traditional AM/FM radio, also known as terrestrial or over-the- air radio, still plays by the old rules: those radio stations pay no royalties to broadcast songs to listeners, and copyright owners instead treat AM/FM radio as a promotional opportunity. The Board must set the rates and terms of the compulsory license for noninteractive webcasters every five years. 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(1)(A). Interested parties may negotiate settlement agreements amongst themselves to opt out of the compulsory license. Id. § 114(f)(2). If a particular record label and a webcaster negotiate a settlement agreement that sets terms for the webcaster’s use of the record label’s copyrighted sound recordings, that agreement controls instead of the Board’s compulsory license. Non-settling parties are subject to the license, and the Board holds an evidentiary proceeding to determine the applicable terms and rates under that license. SoundExchange, 904 F.3d at 46–47. Noninteractive webcasting produces hundreds of billions of streams per year, the vast majority of which are covered by the compulsory license rather than by a settlement. 5 Congress set forth instructions for the Board’s compulsory license determinations in 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(1)(B). The statute directs the Board to “distinguish among the different types of [webcasting] services then in operation” based on, among other factors, the “quantity and nature of the use of sound recordings and the degree to which use of the service may substitute for or may promote the purchase of phonorecords by consumers.” Id. Applying that standard, the Board has previously distinguished between commercial and noncommercial webcasting services and between subscription-based and nonsubscription-based commercial services. See Determination of Royalty Rates and Terms for Ephemeral Recording and Webcasting Digital Performance of Sound Recordings (Web IV), 81 Fed. Reg. 26,316, 26,409 (May 2, 2016). For each different type of service, the Board must establish rates and terms that represent what “would have been negotiated in the marketplace between a willing buyer and a willing seller.” 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(1)(B). This is called the “willing buyer/willing seller” standard. SoundExchange, 904 F.3d at 56. In so doing, the Board must consider factors including the effect of the license’s rates and terms on other sources of sound recording revenue, such as whether a service tends to boost or deflate interactive streaming royalties. 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(1)(B)(i)(I). The Board may also consider voluntary license agreements negotiated for comparable services as “benchmarks” that provide reference points in its analysis. SoundExchange, 904 F.3d at 47; see 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(1)(B)(ii). And the Board’s rates and terms must “include a minimum fee” that each webcaster must pay to use the compulsory license. 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(1)(B). As we have made clear, “the statute does not require that the [hypothetical] market assumed by the [Board] achieve metaphysical perfection.” Intercollegiate Broad. Sys., Inc. v. Copyright Royalty Board (Intercollegiate II), 796 F.3d 111 (D.C. Cir. 2015). 6 This appeal concerns the Board’s fifth noninteractive webcaster rate Final Determination, which set the rates and terms of the statutory license for calendar years 2021 through 2025. Determination of Rates and Terms for Digital Performance of Sound Recordings and Making of Ephemeral Copies To Facilitate Those Performances (Web V), 86 Fed. Reg. 59,452 (Oct. 27, 2021). The Board’s previous four noninteractive webcaster rate determinations were reviewed and largely upheld by this court. See SoundExchange, 904 F.3d 41 (reviewing Web IV); Intercollegiate II, 796 F.3d 111 (reviewing Web III); Intercollegiate Broad. Sys., Inc. v. Copyright Royalty Board (Intercollegiate I), 574 F.3d 748 (D.C. Cir. 2009) (reviewing Web II); Beethoven.com LLC v. Librarian of Cong., 394 F.3d 939 (D.C. Cir. 2005) (reviewing Web I).1 The Web V evidentiary hearing lasted from August 4, 2020, to September 9, 2020. Ten parties participated, including the appellants and intervenors in this consolidated case: (1) the National Association of Broadcasters (the “NAB”), an association of radio and television stations; (2) the National Religious Broadcasters Noncommercial Music License Committee (the “Committee”), an arm of a trade association that represents religious radio and television stations; (3) SoundExchange, Inc., a collective management organization that represents sound-recording copyright holders 1 For the underlying Board determinations, see Web IV, 81 Fed. Reg. 26,316; Determination of Royalty Rates for Digital Performance Right in Sound Recordings and Ephemeral Recordings (Web III), 79 Fed. Reg. 23,102 (April 25, 2014); Digital Performance Right in Sound Recordings and Ephemeral Recordings (Web II), 72 Fed. Reg. 24,084 (May 1, 2007); Determination of Reasonable Rates and Terms for the Digital Performance of Sound Recordings and Ephemeral Recordings (Web I), 67 Fed. Reg. 45,240 (July 8, 2002). 7 and artists; and (4) Google LLC, a technology company. The Board heard oral testimony from thirty-three witnesses and received written testimony from eight, which together included thirteen qualified experts. The Board admitted 748 exhibits into evidence, comprising more than 900,000 pages of documents. After the hearing, the parties submitted proposed findings and conclusions, and responses thereto, and made closing arguments on November 19, 2020. The Librarian of Congress published the Board’s Final Determination on October 27, 2021. In its Final Determination, the Board identified three relevant categories of webcasters: commercial subscription webcasters, commercial nonsubscription webcasters, and noncommercial webcasters. See Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,589. Commercial subscription webcasters are services like Pandora Plus that collect payments from their listeners. See SoundExchange, 904 F.3d at 48. Commercial nonsubscription, i.e., “ad-supported,” webcasters are services like Free Pandora that collect payment from advertisers rather than listeners. See id. at 48, 58. Noncommercial webcasters are services owned by a government entity or a nonprofit, such as National Public Radio (“NPR”) and certain religious webcasters. See Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,593; 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(4)(E)(i). Besides noncommercial, educational, and public webcasters, all other webcasters are commercial. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,592. For all webcasters, the Board set a minimum fee of $1,000 per channel or station. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,589. Commercial webcaster license fees were capped at $100,000. Id. at 59,589. Payment of the minimum fee grants a webcaster access to the compulsory license. See 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(1)(B). Each licensee can have multiple channels, but with the $100,000 cap, a large commercial webcaster licensee pays the minimum fee only for its first one hundred channels. 8 This provision doubled the prior minimum-fee payment— which was $500 per channel and capped at $50,000 per licensee. See Web IV, 81 Fed. Reg. at 26,409; Web III, 79 Fed. Reg. at 23,132. Beyond the minimum fee, when setting royalty rates for all webcasters, the Board puts forward an amount to be paid “per performance.” One copyrighted song heard by one listener is a performance. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,593. So, for instance, if the Board set a royalty rate at $0.002 per performance, and if a webcaster subject to that rate streamed two copyrighted songs to one thousand listeners each, it would have to pay for two thousand performances, amounting to $4.00 total. For commercial subscription webcasters, the Board set a 2021 royalty rate of $0.0026 per performance, adjusted annually for inflation. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,589. For all commercial webcasters, the minimum fee of $1,000 covers a service’s first $1,000 in royalty payments, id., or about 385,000 performances for commercial subscription webcasters in 2021. For commercial nonsubscription webcasters, the Board set a 2021 royalty rate of $0.0021 per performance, adjusted annually for inflation. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,589. The minimum fee of $1,000 covered roughly 475,000 performances for commercial nonsubscription webcasters in 2021. For noncommercial webcasters, the Board set a payment structure under which the webcaster receives a monthly allowance of 159,140 aggregate tuning hours (“ATH”) by paying the minimum fee; and pays a 2021 royalty rate of $0.0021 per performance above that threshold, adjusted annually for inflation—the same rate that applies to 9 commercial nonsubscription webcasters. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,589. ATH is, essentially, the cumulative time spent listening to copyrighted songs. See id. at 59,592. For instance, if 1,000 individuals each listened to one hour of copyrighted songs, that would amount to 1,000 ATH. See id. Four aspects of the Board’s decision are challenged on appeal. First, the NAB argues that the Board should have adopted its proposal to distinguish simulcasters from other commercial nonsubscription webcasters. Simulcasters are traditional AM/FM stations that simultaneously stream their programming on the internet. The NAB sought a lower rate for those stations. Second, the NAB and the Committee (collectively, the “Services”) argue that the Board should have rejected SoundExchange’s proposal to double the minimum fee to $1,000 per channel and $100,000 per licensee. The Services proposed keeping the incumbent minimum fee structure instead. Third, the Committee argues that the Board should have set a lower rate for noncommercial webcasters, based on a settlement agreement between SoundExchange, NPR, and the Corporation for Public Broadcasting (“CPB”) that the Committee proffered as a benchmark. And fourth, SoundExchange argues that the Board should have set a higher commercial nonsubscription rate, contending that the Board’s rate is lower than copyright owners’ opportunity costs. The NAB, the Committee, and SoundExchange timely appealed the aforementioned aspects of the Board’s Final Determination under 17 U.S.C. § 803(d)(1). SoundExchange intervened on behalf of the government in the appeals brought by the Services, while the Services and Google intervened on behalf of the government in SoundExchange’s appeal. 10 II We review the Board’s rate determinations under Section 706 of the Administrative Procedure Act. See 17 U.S.C. § 803(d)(3). We uphold the results of the Board’s proceedings “unless they are arbitrary, capricious, contrary to law, or not supported by substantial evidence.” Intercollegiate I, 574 F.3d at 755. Our “[r]eview of administratively determined rates is ‘particularly deferential’ because of their ‘highly technical’ nature.” Id. (quoting East Ky. Power Coop. v. FERC, 489 F.3d 1299, 1306 (D.C. Cir. 2007)). Applying that standard, we sustain the Board’s Final Determination against the appellants’ challenges. III A As an association of radio and television stations, the NAB represents hundreds of simulcasters nationwide. Its members range in size from larger broadcasters, such as iHeartMedia— a company operating around 850 radio stations—to smaller broadcasters, such as individuals operating only a handful of stations. Focusing on the three identified categories of webcasters, the NAB contests the Board’s decision to place simulcasters in the broad commercial nonsubscription webcaster category, thus subjecting them to the same rate as what the NAB argues are fundamentally different custom radio services. Custom radio refers to services like Pandora, which allow users to skip songs and to “curate the listening experience.” Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,547. By contrast, simulcasters are traditional AM/FM stations that simultaneously stream their programming on the internet without allowing for customization. 11 During the Board’s proceedings, the NAB put forth a rate structure under which simulcasters would pay $0.0008 per play, and other eligible commercial nonsubscription webcasters would pay $0.0016 per play. If adopted, the Board would have distinguished simulcasters from other webcasters for the first time. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,547. According to the NAB, the Board’s statutory obligation to distinguish between different services, see 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(1)(B), required it to adopt this proposal because simulcasting is critically distinct from other types of commercial webcasting. As support, the NAB offered various voluntary agreements as benchmarks, including “[d]irect license agreements between sound recording rights owners and webcaster iHeart and license agreements for musical compositions between performing rights organizations and webcasters Pandora and iHeart.” Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,547. Ultimately, the Board found that a new distinction was unwarranted based on the record, and more specifically, that “significant evidence” showed “simulcasters and other commercial webcasters compete in the same submarket and therefore should be subject to the same rate.” Id. at 59,565. A second point of contention arose regarding the statutorily mandated minimum fee. See 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(1)(B). Having maintained the same $500 minimum fee since 2006, the Board considered SoundExchange’s proposal to double the fee to $1,000 in order “at least to cover [its] administrative cost.” Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,579 (internal quotation marks omitted). The Services collectively challenged SoundExchange’s request, arguing that, because the fee is solely meant to cover “incremental administrative costs”—meaning fees associated with administering the webcasting license—SoundExchange’s average administrative cost was “irrelevant.” Id. at 59,580 (emphasis omitted). In the Services’ view, what the Board accepted as “average 12 administrative cost” in fact encompasses SoundExchange’s “total costs,” including fees unrelated to license administration. NAB Opening Br. 17–18 (emphasis omitted); see Committee Opening Br. 51–52. Thus, the Services asked the Board to adopt their narrower view of the minimum fee. But finding no statutory basis that supported it doing so, the Board rejected the Services’ proposal and explained why the record justified doubling the minimum fee. On appeal, the NAB advances a two-part theory, arguing the Board’s determination is arbitrary, capricious, or otherwise contrary to law. First, the NAB challenges the Board’s refusal to distinguish simulcasters from other nonsubscription commercial services as violating 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(1)(B)’s plain language. It also argues that the Board’s analysis justifying its decision was arbitrary and capricious. Second, the Services challenge the Board’s decision to double the minimum fee in consideration of SoundExchange’s average administrative costs. Unpersuaded by either theory, we affirm both aspects of the Board’s determination. 1 Looking first to the NAB’s categorization-related arguments, we uphold the Board’s determination, finding this record failed to establish that simulcasters warrant a different royalty rate than other commercial nonsubscription services. According to the NAB, the Board violated its statutory obligation to distinguish services when it acknowledged that simulcasters differ from custom radio, yet still subjected both groups to the same rate. After reviewing this record, however, we confirm that the Board reasonably evaluated the NAB’s differentiation evidence and appropriately exercised its 13 discretion in declining to set a separate, lower rate for simulcasters. Recall that the Board “shall distinguish among the different types of services then in operation” when “establish[ing] rates and terms that most clearly represent” what “would have been negotiated in the marketplace between a willing buyer and a willing seller.” 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(1)(B). The Copyright Act also instructs the Board to base its decision on criteria such as “the quantity and nature of the use of sound recordings and the degree to which use of the service may substitute for or may promote the purchase of phonorecords by consumers.” Id. Here, the Board satisfied 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(1)(B) by maintaining the preexisting rate categories and distinguishing royalty rates for (1) commercial subscription services; (2) commercial nonsubscription services; and (3) noncommercial services. When setting rates, we have explained that the Board has discretion in determining what to use as a starting point, so long as it explains itself. Music Choice v. Copyright Royalty Board, 774 F.3d 1000, 1012 (D.C. Cir. 2014) (finding that the Board “did not err when [it] used the prevailing rate as the starting point of [its] analysis,” given “the lack of creditable benchmarks in the record” and the Board’s “reasoned explanation”). Furthermore, Section 114(f)(1)(B) contemplates the Board will “make adjustments to the prevailing rate” and also “consider prior determinations” in its decisionmaking. Music Choice, 774 F.3d at 1012 (internal quotation marks omitted). The Board has never set a lower rate for simulcasters. So its decision not to here is not an “unexplained presumption in favor of uniform rates.” NAB Opening Br. 29. Rather, the Board was justified in relying on its three preexisting rate 14 category distinctions to at least determine a starting point. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,547; see also Web I, 67 Fed. Reg. at 45,252 (adopting a single rate for commercial webcasters); Web II, 72 Fed. Reg. at 24,095 (refusing to establish a separate rate for simulcasters); Web IV, 81 Fed. Reg. at 26,323 (rejecting arguments for a separate simulcaster rate). It was thus up to the NAB to establish a record showing why, and how, this starting point should be altered to reflect the willing buyer/willing seller standard. See Web IV, 81 Fed. Reg. at 26,320 (“As the proponent of a rate structure that treats simulcasters as a separate class of webcasters, the NAB bears the burden of demonstrating not only that simulcasting differs from other forms of commercial webcasting, but also that it differs in ways that would cause willing buyers and willing sellers to agree to a lower royalty rate in the hypothetical market.”); Web I, 67 Fed. Reg. at 45,254 (referring to “the burden of proof on the broadcasters to present evidence to distinguish between the direct transmission of their programs over the Internet and the retransmission of the same programming made by a third-party”). Our reasoning here also resolves the NAB’s secondary challenges to the Board’s decision, rejecting the new simulcast distinction. First, the NAB argues that the Board improperly made a presumption in favor of uniform rates, which required the NAB to present contrary evidence to rebut the Board’s presumption. The NAB asserts that the Board instead should have supported its decision with substantial evidence. This argument gets things backwards. The Board is allowed to consider its prior determinations, and the NAB failed to meet its burden to show this record warranted something different. Second, the NAB argues that the Board’s analysis discussing competition between simulcasters and other commercial webcasters was “far too generalized to have any relevance” and rendered the determination arbitrary and capricious. NAB 15 Opening Br. 37–40. We disagree because, as explained throughout this section, the Board appropriately exercised its discretion in finding the differentiation evidence failed to support a new simulcast rate category under the willing buyer/willing seller standard. The Board reasonably declined to interpret the NAB’s evidence as supporting a separate rate for simulcasters. The NAB presented benchmark agreements that it claimed were evidence that simulcasters should be subject to a lower rate than custom radio. The Board rejected the NAB’s iHeart/Indie Agreements as benchmarks because they only covered “a small portion of the sound recordings performed by iHeart, and an even smaller portion of the entire market for simulcast, custom radio, and internet radio performances.” Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,549 (emphasis added). The NAB also introduced survey evidence that it argued showed simulcasters should be subject to a lower rate. Importantly, the Board also declined to rely on the NAB’s Hauser Survey—a survey intended to reveal the “percentage of respondents that, in the absence of simulcasts, would consume content from” other alternative activities. Id. at 59,551. Doing so was permissible given the Board’s concerns with the survey’s design, such as its failure to include services like internet radio services covered by the statutory license. Id. at 59,563–59,565. Nevertheless, the NAB insists that the differences between simulcasts and custom radio show the Board was required to distinguish a separate, simulcaster rate. But the Board acted reasonably in taking issue with the fact that “the bulk” of the NAB’s evidence “regarding differentiated use of music versus non-music content” was limited to comparing simulcasts against custom radio services, when the NAB’s proposal was to establish a simulcast rate separate from “the full scope of 16 noninteractive webcasting[.]” Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,551 (emphasis added). Critically, the NAB also failed to show that internet simulcasters constitute a distinct market segment. The absence of distinct market segmentation evidence is detrimental to the NAB’s case because the statutory distinction requirement “mean[s] that distinct segments of webcasters—such as noncommercial services—receive their own rates and terms.” SoundExchange, 904 F.3d at 47 (emphasis added). This emphasis on evidence of competition is rooted in the willing buyer/willing seller standard. It is unclear whether a willing buyer and a willing seller would agree to a new rate for a service, falling under a preexisting rate category, absent evidence showing that the service constitutes a distinct segment of webcasters. In SoundExchange, we shed light on the distinction requirement when discussing how to determine if a service constitutes a distinct segment of webcasters. There, we affirmed the Board’s decision to distinguish between ad- based and subscription-based services because the record showed each service “appeal[ed] to a different segment of the market[.]” Id. at 58. But the NAB never argues that any such market segmentation would actually result in a lower rate for simulcasters based on a rate that a willing buyer and a willing seller would accept. Our SoundExchange decision also addressed the Board’s prior determinations more generally and upheld the process through which it determines how to distinguish between services. 904 F.3d at 58–59. The Board’s process began in Web II, when it established that “the key question in ascertaining the propriety of differentiation is whether the services occupy ‘distinct segment[s]’ of the market or instead compete for listeners.” Id. at 58 (quoting Web II, 72 Fed. Reg. at 24,097–24,098). To answer this question, the Board 17 assesses service competition by “examin[ing] whether the services compete with each other for listeners, or whether one service instead operate[d] in a submarket separate from and noncompetitive with the other[.]” Id. (internal quotation marks and citation omitted). And as for market segmentation, the Board considers various factors, “including whether comparable agreements have been negotiated in which one service paid a lower rate than the other.” Id. In short, our precedent counsels that when evaluating categorization challenges under 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(1)(B), we consider whether the record shows the Board reasonably distinguished between the “types of services then in operation[,]” id., and established rates for each “distinct segment[,]” SoundExchange, 904 F.3d at 58, under the willing buyer/willing seller standard. See Intercollegiate II, 796 F.3d at 128 (emphasizing that the minimum fee distinction requirement applies to each “type of service,” 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(1)(B)—“not for each individual webcaster”). Instead of structuring its position around why simulcasters constitute a distinct segment of the market from all other commercial nonsubscription services, the NAB dedicated most of its argument to distinguishing simulcasters from a mere subset of other commercial webcasters—custom internet radio. In doing so, the NAB argued that the Board failed to justify its refusal to establish a separate rate for simulcasters despite its acknowledgment of certain differences between simulcasters and custom radio. But the NAB does not argue that simulcasting is different from commercial webcasting more generally—only that it differs from custom radio. There are other types of commercial webcasting that may not have the same features as custom radio, but the NAB does not argue that a willing buyer and a willing seller would agree to a lower rate for simulcasting than for any other types of commercial webcasting. Although such an argument could succeed if the 18 record showed that willing buyers and willing sellers would agree to lower royalty rates for simulcasting than for other types of commercial webcasting, the NAB did not do so here. Moreover, we underscore the “technical nature” of rate determinations and find the NAB failed to meet its burden here. Intercollegiate II, 796 F.3d at 127 (quoting Intercollegiate I, 574 F.3d at 755). We acknowledge, however, that future records may warrant new rate category distinctions. SoundExchange, 904 F.3d at 58 (describing evidence appropriately distinguishing between ad-based and subscription-based services). 2 Together, the Services contest the minimum fee, arguing the Board erroneously raised the fee to account for costs other than the incremental cost of administering webcasting licenses. As explained below, we reject the Services’ challenge and uphold the $1,000 minimum fee as reasonable. Although Congress requires the Board to establish a minimum fee for each service under 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(1)(B), it never enumerated a list of specific costs that such a fee should cover. Starting in 2006, the Board has continuously maintained the annual minimum fee at $500 for each channel, including an aggregate cap of $50,000 per commercial webcaster. Here, the Board accepted SoundExchange’s proposal to raise the minimum fee to $1,000 per channel and raise the aggregate cap to $100,000. In doing so, it reasonably relied upon three evidentiary findings. Most importantly, the Board was persuaded by SoundExchange’s evidence demonstrating an increase in its average administrative costs. SoundExchange calculated this increased average “by dividing its total administrative costs by 19 its total number of licensees” and dividing that amount “by the estimated number of channels or stations per licensee.” Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,582. This calculation revealed that SoundExchange’s estimated average administrative cost per channel “increased from approximately $1,900 to approximately $4,448 between 2013 and 2018, an increase of 2.34 times.” Id. While acknowledging that this was an estimate, the Board concluded that the “relative increase in average administrative costs”—134%—“would yield a minimum fee of $1170[,]” and noted that this amount exceeded SoundExchange’s proposed $1000 minimum fee. Id. The other two points that the Board found supported increasing the minimum fee included: (1) a settlement between SoundExchange and College Broadcasters, Inc. (“CBI”), agreeing to a minimum fee of $750 by 2025; and (2) inflation. As relevant here, the Board concluded that the CBI settlement generally indicated willing buyers and willing sellers would agree to a higher minimum fee. And to the second point, the record utilized the Bureau of Labor Statistics’ Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers to show that a minimum fee of $656.77 would be necessary to account for general inflation since the minimum fee was set at $500 in 2006. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,583. The Board considered this evidence in finding that the record supported a “zone of reasonable minimum fees” from $656.77 to $1,170. Id. Ultimately, the Board adopted the proposed $1,000 minimum fee because it was most persuaded by SoundExchange’s average administrative cost evidence, and because the proposed fee fell within the reasonable zone. Id. at 59,583–59,584. On appeal, the Services again contest the Board’s consideration of SoundExchange’s average administrative costs, arguing that the minimum fee should be limited to the 20 incremental cost of administering the webcasting license. We disagree. The Services point to nothing in either the statutory scheme, or in the Board’s prior determinations, that requires the Board to adopt such a restrictive view of 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(1)(B). Indeed, the statute only instructs that the statutory rates and terms “shall include a minimum fee for each such type of service,” and that such a fee will reflect the willing buyer/willing seller standard. Id. § 114(f)(1)(B); see Intercollegiate II, 796 F.3d at 128 (“[T]he Board must set a fee that both a willing buyer and a willing seller would negotiate, not just one that is acceptable to the buyer (the webcaster).”) (emphasis omitted). And as the Board explained, it has consistently rejected the interpretations of the minimum fee as limited to incremental administrative costs. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,581 (“To be sure, the Services have made that [incremental administrative costs] argument consistently since Web I. However, the Judges and their predecessors have never embraced it.”). Not only does the Services’ minimum fee challenge lack support based on the statute, as well as from the Board’s prior determinations, but the Services’ position also conflicts with our precedent under which we have held that the minimum fee may reflect average—as opposed to incremental— administrative costs. Intercollegiate II, 796 F.3d at 131 (noting that “the Board did not set the [minimum] fee based solely on SoundExchange’s administrative costs” but also “relied on the evidence of industry-wide average administrative cost”). In Intercollegiate II, we concluded that while “[e]vidence of average cost may not be perfect,” nothing prohibited us from upholding its use. Id. (“This court’s task is ‘only [to] assess the reasonableness of the [Board’s] interpretation of the 21 inherent ambiguity’ in Congress’ directive.”) (quoting Intercollegiate I, 574 F.3d at 757). So too here. The Services have demonstrated no reason to bar the Board’s consideration of SoundExchange’s increased average administrative cost, and the Board’s determination comports with our precedent as well as with the Board’s prior determinations. Given the evidence of (1) SoundExchange’s estimated increase in average administrative cost, (2) a voluntary agreement to a higher minimum fee between SoundExchange and CBI, and (3) general inflation since 2006, we find the Board had substantial evidence to support its decision that a $1,000 minimum fee reasonably satisfied the willing buyer/willing seller standard. Thus, we uphold the increased minimum fee. B The Committee is the arm of a trade association that “represent[s] the interests of religious noncommercial radio stations in issues of music licensing.” Committee Opening Br. v. “Many of the [radio] stations represented by the [Committee] simultaneously transmit their broadcast programming online” under the terms of the statutory license at issue in this appeal. Committee Opening Br. v. The Committee challenges the Board’s rate determination for all noncommercial webcasters, including the nonprofit religious stations that are its members. The Committee proposed two alternative rate structures that would have lowered the rates paid by noncommercial webcasters. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,567. The Board, however, rejected the Committee’s proposals and instead accepted SoundExchange’s recommendation to essentially maintain the incumbent rate structure that had been in effect 22 from 2006 to 2020. Id. at 59,579. In support of its decision, the Board noted that “SoundExchange relies on the same reasoning adopted by the Judges in webcasting proceedings going back to Web II to support its proposed rate structure.” Id. at 59,573. The Board adopted that long-standing reasoning in the absence of “persuasive counterarguments” from the Committee. Id. at 59,573, 59,579. Under the preexisting rate structure, a noncommercial webcast station paid the minimum fee to gain access to 159,140 ATH of monthly usage. See Web IV, 81 Fed. Reg. at 26,405– 26,406. Above that usage threshold, noncommercial webcasters paid the same rates as commercial nonsubscription webcasters. See id. The Committee proposed alternative rates that (1) would have maintained the same usage allowance and minimum fee, while allowing noncommercial webcasters to pay one-third of the commercial rate for above-threshold usage; or (2) would have allowed certain Committee- designated noncommercial webcasters to pay a lump sum for an aggregate usage allowance. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,567.2 2 The Committee’s proposed rate structures for noncommercial webcasters were deemed “Alternative 1” and “Alternative 2.” Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,567. Under Alternative 1, noncommercial webcasters would pay an annual minimum fee of $500 that would entitle them to 1,909,680 ATH of usage per year. For usage above that threshold, noncommercial webcasters would pay one-third of the rate for commercial webcasters for the same type of transmission (subscription versus nonsubscription). Under Alternative 2, the Committee would pay a flat annual fee of $1.2 million to SoundExchange, for a group of up to 795 noncommercial religious radio stations designated by the Committee. Those stations would have an aggregate usage cap of 540 million ATH in 2021, increasing by 15 million ATH per year. The proposal set no terms for usage above that cap. Meanwhile, stations not designated for inclusion in that group would be subject to the terms of Alternative 1. Id. 23 The Committee’s rate proposals were based on a settlement agreement between NPR, CPB, and SoundExchange (the “NPR Agreement”) that covered the years 2021 through 2025. The Committee sought to introduce the NPR Agreement as a benchmark to support its rate proposals for noncommercial webcasters. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,567–59,569. But the Board rejected the NPR Agreement as a benchmark and rejected the Committee’s rate proposals. The Board provided three primary reasons for its decision: (1) the Committee neglected to offer any expert testimony to establish that the NPR Agreement was “comparable” to a compulsory license for noncommercial webcasters; (2) the Committee’s rate proposals failed to make adjustments for economically significant aspects of the NPR Agreement; and (3) one aspect of the Committee’s proposal was based on dated information that the Board was statutorily barred from considering. See id. at 59,569–59,573. On appeal, the Committee argues that the Board (1) violated the APA by arbitrarily and capriciously rejecting the NPR Agreement as a benchmark; (2) violated the APA by arbitrarily and capriciously setting the noncommercial webcaster royalty rate too high; and (3) violated the federal Religious Freedom Restoration Act (“RFRA”), 42 U.S.C. § 2000bb et seq., and the First Amendment by setting a rate that was less favorable to large, predominantly religious webcasters than the rate enjoyed by secular NPR affiliates under the NPR Agreement.3 3 The Committee also joined the NAB’s challenge to the Board’s minimum fee, and essentially relied on the NAB’s briefing and oral argument. Its only additional argument was that the Board should have adjusted the $500 minimum fee for inflation from 2020 rather 24 We sustain the Board’s rate determination for noncommercial webcasters and its rejection of the Committee’s proposals. 1 The Board’s decision to reject the NPR Agreement as a benchmark, as well as the Committee’s rate proposals that were based on the NPR Agreement, was reasonable and supported by substantial evidence. We note that appellants face[] an uphill battle in challenging the Board’s selection of its benchmarks. We have repeatedly recognized that it is “within the discretion of the [Board] to assess evidence of an agreement’s comparability and to decide whether to look to its rates and terms for guidance.” The Board’s “broad discretion” encompasses its selection or rejection of benchmarks, as well as its adjustment of benchmarks to “render them useful.” SoundExchange, 904 F.3d at 50–51 (first quoting Intercollegiate I, 574 F.3d at 759; then quoting Music Choice, 774 F.3d at 1009). Here, the Board properly exercised its discretion. than from 2006, because the $500 figure was last set in 2020. That argument did not affect the Board’s ultimate determination of the minimum fee. See Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,583 (using the inflation-adjusted minimum fee as a lower bound of the “zone of reasonable minimum fees” and relying primarily on SoundExchange’s rising administrative costs to set a new minimum fee). The NAB’s proposal to maintain the lower minimum fee is addressed Part III.A, supra. 25 First, the Board reasonably concluded that the Committee presented insufficient evidence to establish the NPR Agreement’s comparability to the compulsory license for noncommercial webcasters. In a benchmark analysis, the Board “may consider the rates and terms for comparable types of audio transmission services and comparable circumstances under voluntary license agreements.” 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(1)(B)(ii) (emphasis added). Yet, the Committee presented no expert testimony on comparability; it addressed the issue only in arguments made by its attorneys in post- hearing briefing. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,570. Moreover, SoundExchange disputed whether the NPR Agreement was comparable. The Board reasonably decided that expert testimony was necessary to establish comparability. See id. Requiring expert testimony in this case was consistent with the “highly technical nature” of administrative rate determinations. SoundExchange, 904 F.3d at 50 (quoting Intercollegiate II, 796 F.3d at 127). Although the Committee argues that the Board has never explicitly announced an expert-testimony requirement, that does not render the Board’s decision in this case arbitrary, particularly where the Board has previously demanded expert testimony in an analogous situation. See Web IV, 81 Fed. Reg. at 26,327 (rejecting lay testimony and considering only expert testimony to determine whether to adjust a benchmark). Second, the Board reasonably rejected the Committee’s rate proposals due to their failure to account for economically significant aspects of the NPR Agreement. When a party derives a proposed rate from a benchmark agreement, it is required to account for economically significant, non-rate aspects of the benchmark. See SoundExchange, 904 F.3d at 47. For instance, if a benchmark contains a relatively low royalty rate but imposes other costs on webcasters, the rate derived from that benchmark should be adjusted upward to capture 26 those costs. The Board properly placed the burden on the Committee to make the appropriate adjustments to its rate proposals derived from the NPR Agreement. See Music Choice, 774 F.3d at 1009 (“While the Judges might have made further adjustments to [a proponent’s] benchmarks to render them useful, the Judges were not required to do so.” (citation omitted)); see also id. at 1012 (“The Judges were under no obligation to salvage benchmarks they found to have fundamental problems.”). The Board faulted the Committee for failing to account for the following aspects of the NPR Agreement that benefited one or both of the settling parties but were not reflected in the Committee’s proposed rates: (1) the avoidance of litigation costs by the parties to the NPR Agreement; (2) the value of NPR’s advance, lump-sum payments to SoundExchange; and (3) NPR’s consolidated reporting of data from individual stations to SoundExchange. See Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,570, 59,572–59,573. The Board’s determination that those adjustments were necessary to adequately capture the value of the Agreement reflected rational economic reasoning, even though the Board did not determine the precise amount by which each of these factors distorted the Agreement’s pricing.4 The Committee argues that 4 See Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,570 (“[S]ettlement agreements, unlike voluntary agreements reached outside the context of litigation, are not ‘free from trade-offs motivated by litigation cost, as distinguished from the underlying economics of the transaction.’” (quoting Determination of Royalty Rates and Terms for Making and Distributing Phonorecords (Phonorecords III), 84 Fed. Reg. 1918, 1935 (Feb. 5, 2019))); id. at 59,572 (The NPR Agreement’s “rate reflects * * * [a] discount that reflects the administrative convenience to [SoundExchange] of receiving annual lump sum payments that cover a large number of separate entities, as well as the protection from bad debt that arises from being paid in advance.”); id. at 59,573 (“The record reflects that consolidated 27 the Board acted contrary to agency precedent and the statutory scheme, but its citations are all inapposite.5 Third, the Board appropriately concluded that it was statutorily barred from considering the royalty rates contained in the “NPR Analysis,” an internal SoundExchange document created in 2015. See Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,570–59,572. In the NPR Analysis, SoundExchange performed calculations using a royalty-rate structure that included per-performance payments at one-third the commercial rate. The Board found, reporting has value to SoundExchange. * * * ‘[O]ne of the things that NPR does is it collects together the messy data of the individual stations and reports it as part of the agreement.’” (quoting 8/17/20 Tr. 2232 (Professor Catherine Tucker))). 5 For example, the Committee misstates that Board precedent required SoundExchange to make the necessary adjustments. Although Web IV required the challenger of an “otherwise proper and reasonable benchmark” to quantify further proposed adjustments, Web IV, 81 Fed. Reg. at 26,387, that case is distinguishable because the NPR Agreement was not an “otherwise proper and reasonable” benchmark. Moreover, the Committee notes that Web IV accepted a settlement-based benchmark without litigation cost adjustments; but Web IV accepted that benchmark only as “support for some elements of SoundExchange’s rate proposal” and “not for the proposed rate for usage beyond the ATH threshold,” id. at 26,394 (emphasis added), which is exactly what the Committee attempted here. The Committee’s remaining citations, see Committee Opening Br. 29–32, are similarly off point. See Web III, 79 Fed. Reg. at 23,123–23,124; Determination of Rates and Terms for Preexisting Subscription Services and Satellite Digital Audio Radio Services (SDARS II), 78 Fed. Reg. 23,054, 23,068–23,069 (April 17, 2013); Digital Millennium Copyright Act, Pub. L. No. 105-304, § 405, 112 Stat. 2860, 2895–2896 (1998); 17 U.S.C. § 801(b)(7)(A). 28 however, that the rate structure came from an old settlement agreement negotiated pursuant to the Webcaster Settlement Act (“WSA”) of 2009, Pub. L. No. 111-36, 123 Stat. 1926. See Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,572. The Board properly determined that it was statutorily barred from considering that rate structure under 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(4)(C), which prohibits “admi[tting] as evidence or otherwise tak[ing] into account” the “provisions of any agreement entered into pursuant to [the WSA], including any rate structure * * * set forth therein.” Id. The Committee argued that the Board could rely on the rate structure because the NPR Analysis was prepared for use in future, non-WSA settlement negotiations. But the Board was not required to accept the Committee’s inference that the rates were actually used in the non-WSA settlement agreement relied upon by the Committee. See Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,571. We disagree with the Committee’s contention that the Board’s decision contradicted a binding opinion issued by the Register of Copyrights, as set forth in Scope of the Copyright Royalty Judges’ Continuing Jurisdiction, 80 Fed. Reg. 58,300 (Sept. 28, 2015). Although the Register’s opinion allows the Board to consider voluntary license agreements that incorporate WSA settlement terms, as well as the effect of the WSA on private-settlement negotiations, it does not require or even allow the Board to consider documents like the NPR Analysis. See id. at 58,305. The Register found that, if parties incorporate terms from their WSA settlements into subsequent agreements, those are fair game for the Board’s consideration. But the NPR analysis does not fall into that category; it documents WSA rates that may have been used to propose terms for a subsequent agreement. It does not document any post-WSA terms. Without the NPR Analysis, the Committee lacked support for a discounted above-threshold rate for noncommercial webcasters, which became a critical flaw in its proposal. 29 2 We are unpersuaded by the Committee’s argument that the Board arbitrarily and capriciously set the noncommercial webcaster rate. In the absence of acceptable benchmarks, the Board properly used the incumbent rate structure as the starting point in its analysis. See Music Choice, 774 F.3d at 1012 (“[G]iven the lack of creditable benchmarks in the record, the Judges did not err when they used the prevailing rate as the starting point of their Section 801(b) analysis.”). Moreover, substantial evidence supported the Board’s decision to maintain the prevailing rate structure. The incumbent rate structure originated in Web II. It reflected an “economic insight” that noncommercial webcasters that compete with the commercial market tend to be larger, so that size is “a ‘proxy’ for determining when a noncommercial webcaster poses a competitive threat[.]” Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,565–59,566 (“[L]arger noncommercial webcasters have the same or similar competitive impact in the marketplace as similarly sized commercial webcasters.”). Because large noncommercial webcasters can divert listeners away from commercial webcasters, the Board found that copyright holders would not willingly license sound recordings to large noncommercial webcasters at a discount, because that would decrease overall royalty revenue by cannibalizing commercial royalty revenue. See Web II, 72 Fed. Reg. at 24,097–24,100. The noncommercial webcasters that exceed the ATH threshold tend to be larger ones, and they are charged the same rates as commercial webcasters for above-threshold usage. In the instant rate-setting proceeding, the Board relied on expert testimony to conclude that the same competitive dynamics remained in effect and justified retaining the pre- existing rate structure. See Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,575 30 (discussing testimony of Mr. Jon Orszag, Professor Joseph Cordes, and Professor Richard Steinberg).6 The Board appropriately rejected the Committee’s attempts to undermine the analysis that justified the previous rate structure. The Committee argued that cannibalization was unlikely because noncommercial webcasters’ missions differed from those of commercial webcasters. But the Board reasonably declined to rely on the webcasters’ motivations in evaluating market dynamics. See Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,575 (“The concerns about cannibalization that the Judges articulated in past webcasting proceedings focus on potential displacement in listenership from commercial to noncommercial webcasters and is independent of noncommercial webcasters’ motivations.”). Moreover, the Board permissibly relied on an “overlap study” and other evidence to reject the Committee’s argument that noncommercial webcasting would not cannibalize commercial webcasters because they each offer different programming. The overlap study compared the songs played by commercial and noncommercial Christian Adult Contemporary radio stations. Id. at 59,576. It revealed that “commercial and noncommercial stations broadcasting in the Christian [Adult Contemporary] format play many of the same songs.” Id.7 The 6 The Committee’s argument that this expert testimony is mere “ipse dixit” that cannot constitute substantial evidence to maintain the incumbent rate, Committee Opening Br. 40, understates the Board’s reasoned analysis of the expert testimony and overlooks our precedent allowing the Board to start with the incumbent rate in the absence of a suitable benchmark. See Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,575–59,578; Music Choice, 774 F.3d at 1012. 7 The Committee argues that the overlap study should not have been admitted under 37 CFR § 351.10(e). As an initial matter, it is unclear 31 Board also pointed to competition between two Atlanta-based commercial and noncommercial religious radio stations. See id. at 59,575.8 The Board permissibly inferred from that evidence that noncommercial and commercial webcasters’ programming did not differ enough that cannibalization was unlikely. Finally, the Board reasonably rejected the Committee’s argument that the incumbent rate structure failed to consider noncommercial webcasters’ lower willingness to pay, thus violating the Copyright Act’s willing buyer/willing seller standard. According to the Committee, the Board overlooked whether willing buyers would negotiate “above-threshold commercial-level rates,” and accounted for only what willing sellers would negotiate. Committee Opening Br. 40. That argument, however, unduly focuses on the above-threshold rates without considering the entire rate structure. The Board noted that the minimum-fee rate structure gives whether the Committee actually moved to exclude the study, or only the testimony of SoundExchange’s witnesses about the study. See Committee Mot. to Strike Test. Written Rebuttal Test. Related to Mediabase Study. In any event, the Board reasonably concluded that both the study and the witnesses’ testimony were admissible. See Order Denying Committee Mot. to Strike 2–3 (noting that the study simply compiled data “that industry participants rely on and that the Judges have relied upon in past proceedings when presented by lay witnesses,” and relying on the Board’s discretion to admit hearsay testimony from witnesses about such data). 8 The Committee’s arguments against this evidence are meritless. Contrary to the Committee’s suggestions, an expert witness need not have “first-hand knowledge of the asserted facts,” Committee Opening Br. 50, to testify about an issue, and the evidence fell well within the proper scope of rebuttal. Moreover, the Board expressly acknowledged the anecdotal nature of the evidence and treated it with appropriate restraint. See Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,575. 32 noncommercial webcasters of all sizes a hefty discount through the monthly ATH allowance. See Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,566 (discussing testimony of Professor Catherine Tucker); id. at 59,574 (discussing effective discount for noncommercial webcasters). For instance, if the average copyrighted song is four minutes long, see id. at 59,570–59,571, then 159,140 ATH per month would let a noncommercial webcaster play roughly 28.5 million performances in a year for the $1,000 minimum fee. That same number of performances would cost a commercial subscription webcaster roughly $75,000 and a commercial nonsubscription webcaster roughly $60,000. Thus, the significant benefit conferred on noncommercial webcasters by their access to the ATH allowance takes account of their unwillingness to pay the same rates as commercial webcasters. The Board justifiably concluded that the incumbent rate structure adequately balanced noncommercial webcasters’ lower willingness to pay with the risk of large noncommercial webcasters cannibalizing copyright owners’ royalty revenue from commercial webcasters, thereby satisfying the willing buyer/willing seller standard. See id. at 59,573–59,574. 3 The Committee argues that the Board’s rate determination violates the First Amendment’s Free Exercise Clause and the federal RFRA, because the terms that it adopts for noncommercial religious webcasters are less favorable than the terms enjoyed by NPR, a noncommercial secular webcaster. We disagree. The Free Exercise Clause provides that “Congress shall make no law * * * prohibiting the free exercise” of religion. U.S. CONST. Amend. I. Under that clause, a government entity may not “burden[] [a person’s] sincere religious practice 33 pursuant to a policy that is not ‘neutral’ or ‘generally applicable’” unless the action is “narrowly tailored in pursuit of” a “compelling state interest.” Kennedy v. Bremerton Sch. Dist., 142 S. Ct. 2407, 2422 (2022) (quoting Employment Div., Dep’t of Hum. Res. of Ore. v. Smith, 494 U.S. 872, 881 (1990)). “But the First Amendment is not the only potential refuge for [a litigant’s] religious claim—the RFRA offers religious exercise greater protection from intrusion by religion-neutral federal laws.” Kaemmerling v. Lappin, 553 F.3d 669, 677 (D.C. Cir. 2008). Under the RFRA, federal government action cannot “substantially burden a person’s exercise of religion even if the burden results from a rule of general applicability,” unless it is “the least restrictive means of furthering [a] compelling governmental interest.” 42 U.S.C. §§ 2000bb- 1(a)–(b). The statute’s protection reaches “any exercise of religion, whether or not compelled by, or central to, a system of religious belief.” Id. § 2000cc-5(7)(A). The Committee’s RFRA and Free Exercise arguments are premised on a factual assertion that the rate for noncommercial webcasters under the compulsory license is higher than the rate enjoyed by NPR under the NPR Agreement. See Committee Opening Br. 53–54. But there is no record finding to support that assertion. As we have explained, the Board reasonably rejected the NPR Agreement as a benchmark for noncommercial webcasters and faulted the Committee’s proposals based on the NPR Agreement for failing to make necessary adjustments to account for economically significant features of the Agreement. The Board also appropriately refused to consider the NPR Analysis proffered by the Committee, thereby eliminating the evidence that enabled the Board to compare the above-threshold per-play royalty rates of the compulsory license with the NPR Agreement’s lump-sum payments. The record therefore contains no basis for the Board, or this court, to effectively determine whether 34 noncommercial webcasters subject to the compulsory license are paying higher rates than the NPR stations covered by the NPR Agreement. Without making that initial showing of unfavorable treatment of religious webcasters, the Committee cannot establish a violation of the RFRA or the First Amendment. We note that the Committee’s arguments are also problematic in other respects. For example, the Committee attempts to challenge the rates paid by the religious broadcasters that are members of its trade association, but the compulsory license applies to all noncommercial webcasters. Even if the above-threshold noncommercial webcasters are “almost exclusively religious,” as the Committee asserts, Committee Opening Br. 8, the Committee does not explain why it does not have to consider the overall rate structure, which applies to all noncommercial webcasters. Indeed, the Committee fails to cite any precedent that would give the Board the power to impose a statutory license that, like the Committee’s Alternative 2, would be available only to select members of a particular trade organization, rather than to a category of webcasters. See Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,567. We are aware of none. Nor did the Committee argue to the Board that the religious broadcasters it represents form a distinct market segment for purposes of the 2021–2025 proceeding. We need not address that substantial and open question, given the absence of any factual basis to compare the rates at issue. C Finally, SoundExchange challenges as arbitrary and capricious the royalty rate the Board set for commercial, nonsubscription “ad-supported” webcasters, i.e., noninteractive streaming services like Free Pandora that collect 35 payment from advertisers. Specifically, SoundExchange argues that the Board acted arbitrarily and capriciously by making an express finding that the opportunity cost for sellers was a particular value, but then adopting a royalty rate that falls below that opportunity cost without further explanation. The very premise of SoundExchange’s argument is wrong. The Board never found as fact the opportunity cost value on which SoundExchange hangs its argument. As a result, its arbitrary and capricious challenge fails before it even starts. 1 To understand SoundExchange’s argument and the Board’s conclusions, some background on the Board’s analytical process for setting royalty rates. The Board’s statutory obligation is to “establish rates and terms that most clearly represent the rates and terms that would have been negotiated in the marketplace between a willing buyer and a willing seller.” 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(1)(B). The Board views this hypothetical market to be one that is “effectively competitive.” SoundExchange, 904 F.3d at 56. To determine rates under that standard, the Board has relied on various modes of economic analysis to best approximate the price at which a willing seller would sell and at which a willing buyer would buy. See Intercollegiate I, 574 F.3d at 757; Music Choice, 774 F.3d at 1010. One approach is to consider “the rates and terms negotiated for comparable services and ‘comparable circumstances under voluntary license agreements.’” SoundExchange, 904 F.3d at 47 (quoting 17 U.S.C. § 114(f)(2)(B)). To that end, parties in a proceeding may submit examples of voluntary license agreements that they argue are sufficiently analogous to inform 36 the appropriate statutory royalty rate for ad-supported, non- interactive services. Because those proposed benchmarks come from real-world markets that may not map perfectly onto the Board’s hypothetical market, the parties commonly submit expert economic analyses with their proposed benchmarks that propose adjustments to account for any potential variance. The Board then evaluates each license agreement’s economic merits to determine which proposals, if any, could be a useful touchstone in setting the statutory rate. In some instances, the Board has accepted multiple proffered benchmarks, and used the array to establish a “zone of reasonableness” into which the final rate should fall. Web III, 79 Fed. Reg. at 23,110–23,115. Another approach the Board uses is economic modeling submitted by parties and their experts that are designed to produce an appropriate rate. These models often employ game theory to make and justify certain assumptions about the hypothetical market, comb relevant data to calculate inputs, and essentially solve for what parties contend is an appropriate royalty rate. See, e.g., Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,522–59,546 (Evaluation of Game Theoretic Modelling Evidence); Johnson v. Copyright Royalty Board, 969 F.3d 363, 372 (D.C. Cir. 2020) (discussing the Board’s use of specific game theoretic model known as Shapley Analysis).9 9 Game theory “uses equations to model the behavior of decision- makers whose choices affect one another.” Peter H. Huang, Strategic Behavior and the Law, 36 JURIMETRICS J. 99, 100 (1995) (quoting Rob Norton, A New Tool to Help Managers, FORTUNE, May 30, 1994, at 136). Most relevant here, game theory can help model the likely, hypothetical behavior of both negotiating buyers and sellers in an effectively competitive market. 37 In assessing economic models and their outputs, the Board evaluates a model’s utility as well as its flaws, and decides whether a model can reasonably assist the Board’s calculation of the statutory willing buyer/willing seller rate. See, e.g., Phonorecords III, 84 Fed. Reg. at 1947–1950. 2 In this case, the Board considered both benchmarking analyses and economic models utilizing game-theory concepts. With respect to benchmarking analyses, the Board reviewed benchmarks submitted by SoundExchange, Pandora, and Google, along with supplemental submissions by the parties’ experts. See Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,491–59,522. Making relevant adjustments, the Board found that both SoundExchange’s and Pandora’s analyses yielded a royalty rate of $0.0023 per play, while Google’s analysis yielded a rate of $0.0021 per play. Id. at 59,589. The Board also discussed the “Game Theoretic Modelling Evidence” submitted by SoundExchange through its expert, Professor Willig, and by the Services through their expert, Professor Shapiro. As relevant here, the Board evaluated Professor Willig’s “Shapley Value Model,” a game-theoretic model that focused on “how to apportion among the members of a multi-party bargaining group the surplus created by their productive cooperation with each other.” Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,522 (internal quotation marks omitted). That is, when the parties get together and work out a deal, there is an independent value derived from that agreement that is greater than the sum of what every party could get on its own. The Willig model sought to divide up this surplus. The Willig model also assumed a small number of actors would get together to split 38 up market share, presupposing a state of limited competition otherwise known as an oligopoly. One of the inputs that the Willig model used was the “fallback value,” or the money a record company could make with its repertoire through avenues beyond entering into a voluntary licensing agreement with the streaming services. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,522. That fallback value was the party’s “opportunity cost”: The party forgoes these alternative money-making options when it enters into a specific licensing agreement. “The opportunity cost of anything of value is what you must give up to get it[.]” Id. at 59,522 n.220 (quoting JOHN QUIGGIN, ECONOMICS IN TWO LESSONS: WHY MARKETS WORK SO WELL, AND WHY THEY CAN FAIL SO BADLY 15 (2019)) (internal quotation marks omitted). Because opportunity cost represents what a party gives up in taking a particular option, that opportunity cost necessarily sets a floor for the statutory rate under the willing buyer/willing seller standard. That is because no willing buyer or seller would agree to a rate below the cost borne for the choice made. As part of its overall review of Professor Willig’s model, the Board evaluated his opportunity cost figure, and found salient Professor Shapiro’s criticism that the Willig model’s opportunity cost input was artificially inflated. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,538–59,539. As a result, the Board adjusted the Willig model estimate of the opportunity cost down, and recalculated a proposed royalty rate using that new number. Id.10 Even with those adjustments, however, the Board ultimately found that Professor Willig’s model was fatally 10 The precise numbers are sealed as proprietary commercial information. 39 flawed because it baked in certain oligopoly power of the major record labels. Oligopolies, of course, are not present in effectively competitive markets. So a model premised on oligopoly power by definition did not produce a royalty rate reflective of what a willing buyer and seller would agree to in an effectively competitive environment. As a result, the Board concluded that the Willig model and the rate it produced could only serve as a “limited guidepost” in determining a statutory royalty rate. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,540 (“[T]he evidentiary record only allows the Judges to state with regard to the royalty rates they have determined [from Professor Willig’s model] that those 2021 rates * * * exceed an effectively competitive rate by an indeterminate amount.”). The Board likewise rejected Professor Shapiro’s game theoretic modeling. The Board found that “new evidence” Professor Shapiro relied on in his model was fundamentally flawed in multiple ways and some key information was absent. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,540–59,546. Because the missing evidence was the “sine qua non” of Professor Shapiro’s modelling, its absence made Professor Shapiro’s models “unusable.” Id. at 59,546. Having found both game theoretic models to be fundamentally unsound, the Board determined that the separate benchmarking analyses submitted by the parties provided more reliable evidence of an appropriate royalty rate on this record, and that Google’s proposed benchmark in particular was the most convincing. The Board emphasized that Google’s benchmark provided “more granular, [record] label-specific, analysis,” as well as a more reliable application of adjustments to account for known concerns, all of which ultimately lent more weight to Google’s proposed rate. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,589. 40 On that basis, the Board set the commercial ad-supported, noninteractive royalty rate at Google’s proposed adjusted benchmark of $0.0021 per play. Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,589. In so finding, the Board noted that its chosen royalty rate was only slightly below that produced by Professor Willig’s adjusted model, which served as a relevant, though quite limited, guidepost. That further buttressed the Board’s judgment that its final royalty rate accurately reflected the willing buyer/willing seller standard in a hypothetical, effectively competitive market. 3 SoundExchange’s entire argument is premised on the contention that the Board necessarily erred because it specifically adopted the Willig model’s adjusted opportunity cost for the ad-supported, noninteractive market, and yet set a royalty rate that fell below that amount. But the factual premise on which SoundExchange’s argument rests is no fact at all. The Board never made a definitive finding that the true opportunity cost was the adjusted Willig value. In fact, the Board ultimately rejected the Willig model, and the game theoretic models more generally, for use in calculating the appropriate royalty rate, opportunity cost and all. Remember, the Board rejected Professor Willig’s opportunity cost figure as inflated. The Board then noted Professor Shapiro’s proposed downward adjustment of the Willig model’s number. The Board took that into account and concluded that, “[b]ased on the foregoing adjustments accepted by the Judges, Professor Willig’s opportunity cost calculation must be adjusted, as set forth [below in Figure 8].” Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,538. 41 SoundExchange argues that this one sentence renders the Board’s entire rate-setting arbitrary and capricious. But all the Board said was that it accepted Professor Shapiro’s specific adjustments to Professor Willig’s calculations in the broader context of Professor Willig’s game theoretic model. The Board did not go further and make a definitive determination that the adjusted Willig model number was, in fact, the actual opportunity cost for sellers that would govern the entire rate- setting procedure. Especially not since the Board ultimately abandoned altogether the use of economic models like Professors Shapiro’s and Willig’s as a reliable basis for calculating the royalty rate. On top of that, the statement on which SoundExchange relies only addressed one of the Board’s multiple critiques of the Willig model’s initial opportunity cost calculation. The Board, for instance, repeatedly objected to Professor Willig’s failure to factor opportunity benefits into his opportunity cost calculation. See Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,523, 59,537. Notably, SoundExchange lodges no criticism of the Board’s decision to use, instead, the benchmarking process to set the royalty rate. That benchmarking process itself accounted for opportunity cost, as the voluntary agreements naturally involve a party’s own estimation of its opportunity cost. And the Board considered that opportunity cost where relevant in adjusting the benchmark proffered. See Web V, 86 Fed. Reg. at 59,496–59,497. In sum, because the Board never found as fact that the opportunity cost input to Professor Willig’s model, even as adjusted, represented the record companies’ true opportunity cost, the Board’s decision to set a royalty rate that was slightly below the Willig model’s flawed opportunity-cost measure is 42 neither here nor there. And so this court has no occasion to decide, as SoundExchange urges, whether it would, as a matter of law, violate the willing buyer/willing seller standard for the Board to set a royalty rate below some definitive measure of opportunity cost. IV For the foregoing reasons, we affirm the Final Determination of the Copyright Royalty Board. So ordered.