Alenco Comm v. FCC

IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE FIFTH CIRCUIT _______________ m 98-60213 _______________ ALENCO COMMUNICATIONS, INC.; AMANA SOCIETY SERVICE COMPANY; ARROWHEAD COMMUNICATIONS CORPORATION; AYERSVILLE TELEPHONE COMPANY; BARAGA TELEPHONE COMPANY; BARRY COUNTY TELEPHONE COMPANY; BAY SPRINGS TELEPHONE COMPANY, INC.; BENTLEYVILLE TELEPHONE COMPANY; BENTON RIDGE TELEPHONE COMPANY; BLOOMINGDALE HOME TELEPHONE COMPANY; BLUE EARTH VALLEY TELEPHONE COMPANY; BRUCE TELEPHONE COMPANY; CASEY MUTUAL TELEPHONE COMPANY; CFW COMMUNICATIONS COMPANY; CITIZENS TELEPHONE COMPANY OF KECKSBURG; CITIZENS TELEPHONE COMPANY OF HAMMOND; CITIZENS TELEPHONE CORPORATION; CLEMENTS TELEPHONE COMPANY; CLIMAX TELEPHONE COMPANY; COMMUNITY SERVICE TELEPHONE COMPANY; CRAIGVILLE TELEPHONE COMPANY, INC.; CROCKETT TELEPHONE COMPANY; DIXVILLE TELEPHONE COMPANY; DOYLESTOWN TELEPHONE COMPANY; DUNBARTON TELEPHONE COMPANY, INC.; DUNKERTON TELEPHONE COOPERATIVE; EAGLE VALLEY TELEPHONE COMPANY; EASTON TELEPHONE COMPANY; ECKLES TELEPHONE COMPANY; ELKHART TELEPHONE COMPANY; EUSTIS TELEPHONE EXCHANGE; FARMERS COOP TELEPHONE COMPANY; FARMERS MUTUAL TELEPHONE COMPANY-OHIO; FARMERS MUTUAL TELEPHONE COMPANY-MINNESOTA; FLAT ROCK MUTUAL TELEPHONE COMPANY; FORT JENNINGS TELEPHONE COMPANY; FRONTIER COMMUNICATIONS OF DEPUE; GEETINGSVILLE TELEPHONE COMPANY, INC.; GERVAIS TELEPHONE COMPANY; GRACEBA TOTAL COMMUNICATIONS, INC.; GRANADA TELEPHONE COMPANY; GRANBY TELEPHONE & TELEGRAPH COMPANY-MASSACHUSETTS; GULF TELEPHONE COMPANY; HARTINGTON TELEPHONE COMPANY; HICKORY TELEPHONE COMPANY; HINTON TELEPHONE COMPANY OF HINTON, OKLAHOMA, INC.; HOLLIS TELEPHONE COMPANY; HOME TELEPHONE COMPANY-NEBRASKA; HOME TELEPHONE COMPANY-MINNESOTA; HOT SPRINGS TELEPHONE COMPANY; HUXLEY COOPERATIVE TELEPHONE COMPANY; INDIANHEAD TELEPHONE COMPANY; IRONTON TELEPHONE COMPANY; JEFFERSON TELEPHONE COMPANY, INC.; KADOKA TELEPHONE COMPANY; KALEVA TELEPHONE COMPANY; KALIDA TELEPHONE COMPANY, INC.; LAUREL HIGHLAND TELEPHONE COMPANY; LIGONIER TELEPHONE COMPANY; MANKATO CITIZENS TELEPHONE COMPANY; MANTI TELEPHONE COMPANY; MARIANNA & SCENERY HILL TELEPHONE COMPANY; MARSEILLES TELEPHONE COMPANY; MCCLURE TELEPHONE COMPANY; MCDONOUGH TELEPHONE COOP, INC.; MEBTEL COMMUNICATIONS; MERCHANTS & FARMERS TELEPHONE COMPANY; METAMORA TELEPHONE COMPANY; MID CENTURY TELEPHONE COOP, INC.; MID COMMUNICATIONS TELEPHONE COMPANY; MID-IOWA TELEPHONE COOP ASSOCIATION; MIDDLE POINT HOME TELEPHONE COMPANY; MIDSTATE TELEPHONE COMPANY-NORTH DAKOTA; 2 MIDWEST TELEPHONE COMPANY; MILES COOPERATIVE TELEPHONE ASSOCIATION; MILLRY TELEPHONE COMPANY, INC.; MINFORD TELEPHONE COMPANY, INC.; MINNESOTA LAKE TELEPHONE COMPANY; MT. ANGEL TELEPHONE COMPANY; NATIONAL TELEPHONE OF ALABAMA, INC.; NEW LISBON TELEPHONE COMPANY; NORTH-EASTERN PENNSYLVANIA TELEPHONE COMPANY; NORTH ENGLISH COOP TELEPHONE COMPANY; NORTHWESTERN INDIANA TELEPHONE COMPANY, INC.; NOVA TELEPHONE COMPANY; ODIN TELEPHONE EXCHANGE, INC.; ORWELL TELEPHONE COMPANY; OSAKIS TELEPHONE COMPANY; PALMERTON TELEPHONE COMPANY; PANHANDLE TELEPHONE COOP, INC.; PANORA COOPERATIVE TELEPHONE ASSOCIATION; PATTERSONVILLE TELEPHONE COMPANY; PENNSYLVANIA TELEPHONE COMPANY; PEOPLES MUTUAL TELEPHONE COMPANY; PEOPLES TELEPHONE COMPANY, INC.; PIERCE TELEPHONE COMPANY, INC.; PINE ISLAND TELEPHONE COMPANY; PINNACLE COMMUNICATIONS; PRAIRIE GROVE TELEPHONE COMPANY; PYMATUNING INDEPENDENT TELEPHONE COMPANY; REDWOOD COUNTY TELEPHONE COMPANY; ROANOKE TELEPHONE COMPANY, INC.; ROBERTS COUNTY TELEPHONE COOP ASSOCIATION; RONAN TELEPHONE COMPANY; SCHALLER TELEPHONE COMPANY; SEARSBORO TELEPHONE COMPANY; SHELL ROCK TELEPHONE COMPANY; SOUTH CANAAN TELEPHONE COMPANY; SOUTHERN MONTANA TELEPHONE COMPANY; STATE LONG DISTANCE TELEPHONE COMPANY; STATE TELEPHONE COMPANY; STAYTON COOPERATIVE TELEPHONE COMPANY; STOCKHOLM-STRANDBURG TELEPHONE COMPANY; SUMMIT TELEPHONE COMPANY; SWAYZEE TELEPHONE COMPANY; 3 SYCAMORE TELEPHONE COMPANY; TRI COUNTY TELEPHONE COMPANY, INDIANA; TRI-COUNTY TELEPHONE MEMBERSHIP CORPORATION; VALLEY TELEPHONE COOPERATIVE, INC.; VAN HORNE COOPERATIVE TELEPHONE COMPANY; VENUS TELEPHONE CORPORATION; VOLCANO TELEPHONE COMPANY; WEST IOWA TELEPHONE COMPANY; WEST LIBERTY TELEPHONE COMPANY; WEST SIDE TELEPHONE COMPANY; WEST SIDE TELEPHONE COMPANY-PENNSYLVANIA; WEST TENNESSEE TELEPHONE COMPANY, INC.; WESTERN TELEPHONE COMPANY-SOUTH DAKOTA; WIKSTROM TELEPHONE COMPANY, INC.; WILTON TELEPHONE COMPANY-NEW HAMPSHIRE; YADKIN VALLEY TELEPHONE MEMBERSHIP CORPORATION; YUKON-WALTZ TELEPHONE COMPANY; and UNITED STATES TELEPHONE ASSOCIATION, Petitioners, VERSUS FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION and UNITED STATES OF AMERICA, Respondents. _________________________ Petitions for Review of Orders of the Federal Communications Commission _________________________ January 25, 2000 4 Before SMITH, WIENER, and goal of federal telecommunications regulation EMILIO M. GARZA, Circuit Judges. since the passage of the Communications Act of 1934. Indeed, the FCC’s very purpose is JERRY E. SMITH, Circuit Judge: “to make available, so far as possible, to all the people of the United States . . . a rapid, This is a consolidated challenge to two or- efficient, Nation-wide, and world-wide wire ders of the Federal Communications Commis- and communication service with adequate sion (the “FCC,” the “Commission,” or the facilities at reasonable charges.” 47 U.S.C. § “agency”)1 promulgated to satisfy the twin 151 (as amended). See also Texas Office of Congressional mandates articulated in the Tel- Pub. Util. Counsel v. FCC, 183 F.3d 393, ecommunications Act of 1996 (the “Act”)2 of 405-06 & n.2 (5th Cir. 1999) (“TOPUC”), providing universal telecommunications ser- petition for cert. filed (Dec. 23, 1999) (No. vice in the United States and injecting 99-1072). competition into the market for local telephone service. PetitionersSSlocal telephone service Specifically, the Act requires that universal providers who serve predominantly small service support be “explicit and sufficient,” towns and rural areasSSchallenge the orders as 47 U.S.C. § 254(e), and it articulates several inconsistent with the statutory requirements of guiding principles to govern universal the Act; arbitrary and capricious in violation of serviceSSincluding, for example, that “access the Administrative Procedure Act, 5 U.S.C. . . . be provided in all regions of the Nation . . § 706(2)(A); violative of the Takings Clause, . including low-income consumers and those in U.S. CONST. amend. V; and in noncompliance rural, insular, and high cost areas,” that with the Regulatory Flexibility Act, 5 U.S.C. services and rates be “reasonably comparable” § 604. Having jurisdiction to review the or- to those offered “in urban areas,” that “[a]ll ders pursuant to 28 U.S.C. § 2342(1) and providers of telecommunications services . . . 47 U.S.C. § 402(a), we deny the petitions for make an equitable and nondiscriminatory con- review. tribution to the preservation and advancement of universal service,” and that universal service I. THE STATUTORY MANDATES. support be “specific” and “predictable,” id. Universal service has been a fundamental § 254(b)(2)-(5); Order ¶ 21. While the FCC is required to obey statutory commands, the guiding principles reflect congressional intent 1 In re: Federal-State Joint Board on Universal to delegate difficult policy choices to the Serv.; Report and Order in CC Docket No. 96-45, Commission’s discretion. See TOPUC, 183 12 FCC Rcd. 8776 (1997) (“Order”); Fourth F.3d at 411-12.3 Order on Reconsideration in CC Docket No. 96-45; Report and Order in CC Docket Nos. 96-45, 96-262, 94-1, 91-213, 95-72, 13 FCC 3 Rcd. 5318 (1997); Errata, 13 FCC Rcd. 2372 The Act additionally states that “[i]t shall be (1998) (“Fourth Reconsideration Order”). the policy of the United States to encourage the provision of new technologies and services to the 2 Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. public.” 47 U.S.C. § 157(a). Cf. 47 U.S.C. No. 104-104, 110 Stat. 56 (to be codified as § 254(b)(2) (providing that universal service pro- amended in scattered sections of title 47, United grams be guided by principle of providing access to States Code). (continued...) 5 (...continued) advanced telecommunications and information ser- vices in all regions). Petitioners argue that the orders violate § 157(a). Unlike the express statutory requirement of suf- ficient support of universal service support im- posed by 47 U.S.C. § 254(e), § 157(a) is merely a broad statement of policy conferring substantial discretion on the Commission to determine how best to provide for new technologies and services. To our knowledge, § 157(a) has never been used to invalidate an FCC action. We conclude, therefore, that a universal service program that satisfies the specific statutory requirements of § 254(e) necessarily satisfies the broad policy statement of § 157(a). 6 Alongside the universal service mandate is has followed in making the transition from the directive that local telephone markets be monopolistic to competitive universal service. opened to competition. See 47 U.S.C. §§ 251- First, rates must be based not on historical, 253; AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 525 U.S. booked costs, but rather on forward-looking 366, 371; TOPUC, 183 F.3d at 406, 412. The costs. After all, market prices respond to cur- FCC must see to it that both universal service rent costs; historical investments, by contrast, and local competition are realized; one cannot are sunk costs and thus ignored. be sacrificed in favor of the other. The Commission therefore is responsible for [I]t is current and anticipated cost, rath- making the changes necessary to its universal er than historical cost[,] that is relevant service program to ensure that it survives in to business decisions to enter markets the new world of competition.4 Because and price products. The business Congress has conferred broad discretion on manager makes a decision to enter a the agency to negotiate these dual mandates, new market by comparing anticipated courts ought not lightly interfere with its additional revenues (at a particular reasoned attempt to achieve both objectives. price) with anticipated additional costs. See Chevron U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural Resources If the expected revenues cover all the Defense Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837, 842-44 costs caused by the new product, then a (1984); 5 U.S.C. § 706(2)(A). rational business manager has sound business reasons to enter the new market. The historical costs associated II. THE UNIVERSAL SERVICE ORDERS. with the plant already in place are The orders under review make various essentially irrelevant to this decision changes to universal service deemed necessary since those costs are ‘sunk’ and achieve universal service within a competitive unavoidable and are unaffected by the environment. We describe the general new production decision. This factor principles guiding the Commission’s judgment, may be particularly significant in in- then detail the provisions specifically at issue dustries such as telecommunications in petitioners’ various challenges. which depend heavily on technological innovation, and in which a firm’s ac- A. COMMISSION PRINCIPLES. counting, or sunk, costs may have little To analyze the purpose and effect of the relation to current pricing decisions. FCC’s numerous regulatory changes to its uni- versal service program, we find it useful first MCI Communications Corp. v. American Tel. to articulate three principles the Commission & Tel. Corp., 708 F.2d 1081, 1116-17 (7th Cir. 1983).5 4 See Order ¶¶ 1-4, 20 (stating that it “ensure[s] 5 that this system is sustainable in a competitive See also TOPUC, 183 F.3d at 407 (stating marketplace, thus ensuring that universal service is that “the FCC decided to use the ‘forward-looking’ available at rates that are ‘just, unreasonable, and costs to calculate the relevant costs of a carrier affordable’ for all Americans”). (continued...) 7 (...continued) . . . . To encourage carriers to act efficiently, the agency would base its calculation on the costs an efficient carrier would incur (rather than the costs the incumbent carriers historically have in- curred)”). 8 The FCC additionally defends the orders as Second, the old regime of implicit reasonable interim regulations. The shift from subsidiesSSthat is, “the manipulation of rates monopoly to competition is indeed dramatic. for some customers to subsidize more Congress thus expressly contemplated that the affordable rates for others”SSmust be phased Commission would adopt an incremental ap- out and replaced with explicit universal service proach to retooling universal service for a subsidiesSSgovernment grants that cause no world of competition.6 Because the distortion to market pricesSSbecause a provisions under review are competitive market can bear only the latter. merely transitional, our review is especially deferential.7 TOPUC, 183 F.3d at 406. For obvious reasons, this system of im- plicit subsidies can work well only under regulated conditions. In a competitive environment, a carrier that tries to subsidize below-cost rates to rural customers with above-cost rates to urban customers is vulnerable to a 6 competitor that offers at-cost rates to It requires the Commission to adopt rules urban customers. Because opening local opening the local services market to competition telephone markets to competition is a “within 6 months.” 47 U.S.C. § 251(d)(1). By contrast, the Commission need only adopt rules principal objective of the Act, Congress establishing a “specific timetable for recognized that the universal service implementation” of universal service, and even system of implicit subsidies would have then, it has “15 months” to do so. 47 U.S.C. § to be re-examined. 254(a)(2). See also TOPUC, 183 F.3d at 436 (“By instructing the FCC to establish a ‘timetable Id. Indeed, the Act requires that all universal for implementation’ by the statutory deadline, service support be explicit. See 47 U.S.C. Congress assumed the implementation process § 254(e). would occur over a transition period after the fifteen-month deadline.”). Finally, the program must treat all market 7 participants equallySSfor example, subsidies See TOPUC, 183 F.3d at 437 (“Where the must be portableSSso that the market, and not statutory language does not explicitly command local or federal government regulators, otherwise, we defer to the agency’s reasonable judgment about what will constitute ‘sufficient’ determines who shall compete for and deliver support during the transition period from one uni- services to customers. Again, this principle is versal service system to another.”); id. at 440 n.85 made necessary not only by the economic re- (acknowledging that “we extend the FCC greater alities of competitive markets but also by stat- discretion in deciding what will be ‘sufficient’ ute. See 47 U.S.C. § 214(e)(1) (requiring that during the transition period”); MCI Telecomm. all “eligible telecommunications carrier[s] . . . Corp. v. FCC, 750 F.2d 135, 140 (D.C. Cir. 1984) shall be eligible to receive universal service (noting that “substantial deference by courts is support”). accorded to an agency when the issue concerns interim relief”). 9 B. PROVISIONS. First, they oppose various Telephone service is jointly changes to the universal provided by two sets of service support fund for high carriers. Local exchange cost loops. Second, before carriers (“LEC’s”) provide issuing the Order, the FCC local telephone service in a allowed certain small, given geographical calling area generally rural LEC’s to weight through monopoly networks, or specially the amount of time “exchanges,” each comprising a spent by their telephone series of “local loops” al- switching equipment on lowing for interconnection switching long distance calls, within the exchange.8 Inter- for purposes of calculating the exchange carriers (“IXC’s”) access charges those LEC’s may provide long distance service collect from IXC’s. The Order by connecting callers served by would eliminate this effective different LEC’s; such service subsidy and replace it with a is called “exchange access.”9 new, explicit support fund. Petitioners are LEC’s serving 1. HIGH-COST LOOPS. predominantly small towns and Rural LEC’s face special rural areas.10 Intervenor Bell obstacles. The cost of Atlantic, supporting the FCC providing telephone service and opposing petitioners, is varies with population density, also an LEC. Intervenor MCI is because dispersed populations an IXC and also supports the require longer wires and permit FCC. lesser economies in installation, service, and The FCC has established a maintenance. Also relevant are number of universal service geographic characteristics, for programs involving LEC’s and climate and certain types of IXC’s. The Order implements a terrain make service calls and myriad of amendments to bring repairs more costly. Rural those programs into compliance areas where telephone customers with competition in the LEC are dispersed and terrain is market, but petitioners object unaccommodating are therefore to amendments to two of them. the most expensive to serve. To meet its historic mandate 8 of universal service, the FCC See 47 U.S.C. § 153(26) (defining “local ex- has established a universal change carrier”); 47 U.S.C. § 153(47) (defining service fund to subsidize high- “telephone exchange service”). cost rural LEC’s to reduce the 9 rates they must charge their See 47 U.S.C. § 153(16) (defining “exchange customers. An LEC is eligible access”); 47 U.S.C. § 153(48) (defining “telephone for a subsidy if its operating toll service”). expensesSSits “loop costs”SSare fifteen percent or more above 10 See 47 U.S.C. § 153(37) (defining “rural the national average. Loop telephone company”). 10 costs include the costs of the depreciated cable, wire, and circuit equipment used to provide local service, the depreciation and maintenance expenses associated with that local plant, and the corporate operations expenses related to the provision of local service. “Corporate operations ex- that can be included in the penses” include the costs loop cost calculation. The incurred in formulating Order allows LEC’s to report corporate policy, providing corporate operations expenses overall administration and man- only up to 115% of the industry agement, and hiring average for LEC’s of like size. accountants, consultants, and See Order ¶¶ 283-285, 307. lawyers to understand and comply with FCC, state, and Third, the Order makes the local regulations. To de- subsidy portable, following the termine the amount of corporate customer who switches service operations expense that is from one LEC to another. properly chargeable to the pro- Petitioners claim that vision of local service (and portability violates the therefore included in total principle of predictable loop costs for purposes of funding. See Order ¶ 311. determining eligibility for a Fourth, beginning January 1, subsidy), an LEC must reduce 2000, the Order imposes an its total corporate operations annual inflation index on the expenses to correspond to the loop cost eligibility proportion of its entire plant benchmarkSSthe minimum amount a that is local exchange plant. loop must cost to be awarded a subsidySSreplacing the former Petitioners object to a approach of recalculating a variety of changes the Order fresh benchmark periodically, effects to the administration based on updated estimates of of the fund. First, they industry averages. See Order oppose the continued imposition ¶¶ 300-301; 47 C.F.R. § of a cap on growth in fund 36.622(d) (1997). Finally, the expenditures, which cap limits Order disallows additional total available support to the universal service support when previous year’s level, adjusted a rural LEC acquires and for growth in the number of upgrades another exchange, see working loops. See Order Order ¶ 308, despite ¶ 302. Second, they object to petitioners’ claim that such a new cap on the amount of mergers are efficient and corporate operations expenses should be encouraged. 11 The cumulative result of all those used to switch intrastate these changes, petitioners say, calls. is that the Commission has ren- dered LEC’s unable to earn a Before the orders under fair return and has discouraged review, the FCC allowed certain future investment in small, generally rural LEC’s to telecommunications, and thereby weight their DEM totals with a has acted arbitrarily and “toll weighting factor,” capriciously and has violated thereby providing LEC’s with a the Act’s sufficient funding higher cost basis on which requirement and the Takings their federal access charge Clause. would be based. Petitioners maintain that the practice of 2. SWITCHING COSTS. DEM weighting reflects the IXC’s pay “access charges” to higher cost of switching a long LEC’s for the right to have distance or “toll” call than access to an LEC’s local that of switching a local call, exchange to connect long- because certain network distance calls to and from that functions required by inter- exchange. Jurisdiction to exchange carriersSSsuch as regulate access charges is equal access, intra-LATA toll shared between federal and dialing parity, toll screening, state governments. To toll blocking, Signaling System implement rate-of-return reg- 7 (SS7), expanded carrier ulation, state and federal identification codes, and 800 regulators must allocate the number portabilitySSrequire costs of operating an LEC additional central processing between the delivery of hardware and software. intrastate, interexchange telephone service (which is The FCC has long held, regulated by state entities) however, that the disparity and the provision of interstate between intrastate and service (which is subject to interstate call switching is a the FCC’s jurisdiction). To relic of old, electromechanical determine how the allocations technology and that modern are to be made, the agency has digital switching equipment promulgated a number of cost largely eliminates the cost separation rules. differential.11 Toll-weighting The separation rules for costs associated with 11 connecting callsSSa process As the Commission stated in 1987, known as “switching”SSare based on “dial equipment minutes of The Mountain States Telephone and use” (“DEM’s”). Under the Telegraph Company, Northwestern Bell rules, an LEC divides its total Telephone Company, Pacific Northwest Bell DEM’s between those used to Telephone Company (US West), which switch interstate calls and originally supported the use of weighted (continued...) 12 continues today, not out of First, they claim the Order adherence to principles of cost arbitrarily and capriciously causationSSwhich provide that abandons cost-causation costs be charged to the source principles. Second, because it of the costSSbut rather to would be financed by all provide an implicit subsidy for telecommunications carriers, rural LEC’s.12 including small LEC’s such as petitioners, the new fund con- The Order replaces toll- stitutes an unlawful subsidy by weighting with a new universal small LEC’s in favor of IXC’s service fund (separate from the because it effectively saves fund for high-cost loops). See IXC’s from having to pay for Order ¶¶ 303-304. Petitioners the more expensive cost of object for three reasons. switching their long-distance calls. Finally, just as they do with respect to the high- cost loop fund, petitioners object on the ground that (...continued) portability violates the DEM in its comments, changed its position principle of predictability and to support measured DEM in reply the statutory command of comments because it believes the ongoing sufficient funding. process of replacing older technology with Specifically, they claim that digital switches will eliminate the need for if just 25% of the revenue that any toll weighting. We believe that modern the FCC has made portable is digital switching equipment has greatly re- lost by a typical small LEC, duced, if not eliminated, the additional cost the annual rate of return for of toll switching. . . . [W]e believe that the interstate access service will, need for toll weighting will continue to di- in many cases, fall to minus minish and will eventually be eliminated as 10.53%. the exchange carriers continue to replace older technology equipment with digital III. COMMUNICATIONS ACT AND switches. ADMINISTRATIVE PROCEDURE ACT CHALLENGES. In the Matter of Amendment of Part 67 of the Petitioners’ main challenge is that the orders are Commission’s Rules and Establishment of a Joint inconsistent with the statutory Board, Recommended Decision and Order in CC mandates of the Act. Docket No. 80-286, 2 FCC Rcd. 2551, ¶ 49 Therefore, they claim, the (1987). See also In the Matter of MTS and WATS orders constitute arbitrary and Market Structure, Amendments of Part 67 (New capricious regulation. Part 36) of the Commission's Rules and Establishment of a Federal-State Joint Board, A. STANDARD OF REVIEW. Report and Order in CC Docket Nos. 78-72, Courts review agency conduct 80-286, 86-297, 2 FCC Rcd. 2639, ¶ 5 (1987). in two ways. First, we review 12 agency interpretation of their See TOPUC, 183 F.3d at 425 (noting “the statutory authority under the sorts of implicit subsidies currently used by the familiar Chevron two-step FCC in its [DEM] weighting program”). 13 inquiry. See Chevron, 467 U.S. step-two, APA arbitrary and at 842-44. capricious review is narrow and deferential, requiring only Under step one, where that the agency “articulate[] a “Congress has directly spoken rational relationship between to the precise question at the facts found and the choice issue,” we must “give effect to made.” Harris, 19 F.3d at 1096 the unambiguously expressed (quoting Motor Vehicles Mfrs. intent of Congress,” reversing Ass’n of the United States v. an agency’s interpretation that State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., does not conform to the 463 U.S. 29, 43 (1983)). statute’s plain meaning. Id. “[T]he agency’s decision need at 842-43. Under step two, not be ideal.” Id. Moreover, which addresses situations in our review here is especially which the statute is either deferential, because the silent or ambiguous, “the provisions under review are question for the court is merely transitional, as whether the agency’s answer is expressly contemplated by the based on a permissible con- Act.13 struction of the statute.” Id. at 843. We reverse only if the B. ANALYSIS. agency’s construction is “ar- Petitioners assert two bitrary, capricious or general themes. First, the manifestly contrary to the challenges go directly to the statute.” Id. at 844. If, on heart of FCC expertiseSSwhether the other hand, the the Commission has sufficiently interpretation “is based on a and explicitly supported permissible construction of the universal service in an open, statute,” we defer to the agen- competitive marketSSand thus cy’s construction. must overcome substantial judicial deference. Examining In addition, the the Act through the lens of Administrative Procedure Act Chevron, we note that Congress (“APA”) empowers courts to obviously intended to rely reverse agency action that is primarily on FCC discretion, arbitrary and capricious. See and not vigorous judicial 5 U.S.C. § 706(2)(A); Harris v. review, to ensure satisfaction United States, 19 F.3d 1090 of the Act’s dual mandates. As (5th Cir. 1994). Chevron step- we noted in a prior challenge two focuses on the agency’s to an FCC universal service interpretation of its statutory regulation, power, while APA arbitrary-and- capricious review focuses on [t]o be sure, the FCC’s the reasonableness of the reason for adopting this agency’s decision-making methodology is not just to process pursuant to that interpretation. See TOPUC, 183 F.3d at 410. Like Chevron 13 See note 7, supra. 14 preserve universal service. ensure sufficient funding of Rather, it is also trying every local telephone provider to encourage local as well. competition . . . . As long as it can reasonably Moreover, excessive funding argue that the methodology may itself violate the will provide sufficient sufficiency requirements of the support for universal Act. Because universal service service, however, it is is funded by a general pool free, under the deference subsidized by all we afford it under Chevron t e l e c o m m u n i c a t i o n s step-two, to adopt a meth- providersSSand thus indirectly odology that serves its by the customersSSexcess other goal of encouraging subsidization in some cases may local competition. detract from universal service by causing rates unnecessarily TOPUC, 183 F.3d at 412. to rise, thereby pricing some Petitioners do not satisfy the consumers out of the market. high evidentiary standard necessary to establish that the 1. HIGH-COST LOOPS. Commission acted arbitrarily Petitioners fail to show that and capriciously when it the FCC’s various changes to produced its interim rules. the universal service support fund for high-cost loops Second, petitioners’ unreasonably fails to provide sufficiency challenge sufficient funding for fundamentally misses the goal universal service or otherwise of the Act. The Act does not constitutes an arbitrary and guarantee all local telephone capricious regulation under the service providers a sufficient Act. First, they object to return on investment; quite to the agency’s continuation of a the contrary, it is intended to cap on growth in the fund, introduce competition into the adjusted only for changes in market. Competition the total number of working necessarily brings the risk loops. The cap’s track record, that some telephone service however, reflects a reasonable providers will be unable to balance between the compete. The Act only promises Commission’s mandate to ensure universal service, and that is sufficient support for a goal that requires sufficient universal service and the need funding of customers, not to combat wasteful spending. providers. So long as there is The agency’s broad discretion sufficient and competitively- to provide sufficient universal neutral funding to enable all service funding includes the customers to receive basic decision to impose cost telecommunications services, controls to avoid excessive the FCC has satisfied the Act expenditures that will detract and is not further required to from universal service. 15 Petitioners do not show how the discretion to impose a cap FCC has abused that discretion. rather than to undertake the more costly alternative of Second, petitioners object to intensive auditing. the introduction of a cap on the amount of corporate oper- Petitioners additionally ations expenses that may be claim that the cap on review is reported to determine excessively burdensome, driving eligibility for high-cost loop interstate rates of return to support. The Order limits 2.81% for rural LEC’s. Even LEC’s to 115% of the industry assuming that this statistic average for corporate proves that customers have operations expenses accrued by failed to receive sufficient carriers of like size. See universe service support, this Order ¶¶ 283-285, 307. statistic is based on the experience of only a single Petitioners claim that providerSSthe Bay Springs corporate operations expenses Telephone CompanySSand not a are already capped and that statistically valid sample. there is no need for a second Petitioners’ evidence therefore cap.14 It is true that, even does not establish that the cap before the Order, the amount of unreasonably fails to provide reportable corporate operations sufficient service; at most it expenses was determined by presents an anomaly that can be multiplying an LEC’s total addressed by a request for a corporate operations expenses waiver.15 by the percentage of its total plant that is local exchange Moreover, the statistic plant. This is no cap, ignores the Fourth however, but rather a Reconsideration Order, in which reasonable method of allocating the FCC responded to costs. The proposed 115% rule petitioners’ concerns by, inter is thus a wholly reasonable alia, establishing a minimum exercise of the Commission’s cap of $300,000. See Fourth legitimate power to combat Reconsideration Order ¶¶ 85- abusive spending; absent the 109. Petitioners present no proposed rule, the regulations evidence disputing the suf- provide no incentive to keep ficiency of the currently costs down. Moreover, given operative cap. its legitimate cost concerns, the agency was well within its Third, the order provides that the universal service subsidy be portable so that it 14 moves with the customer, See Alltel Corp. v. FCC, 838 F.2d 551, 561 (D.C. Cir. 1988) (“A regulation perfectly reasonable and appropriate in the face of a given 15 problem may be highly capricious if that problem See 47 C.F.R. § 1.3; Fourth Reconsideration does not exist.”). Order ¶¶ 93, 102, 108. 16 rather than stay with the The methodology governing subsidy incumbent LEC, whenever a disbursements is plainly stated and made customer makes the decision to available to LEC’s. What petitioners seek is switch local service providers. not merely predictable funding mechanisms, Petitioners claim that portability violates the but predictable market outcomes. Indeed, statutory principle of what they wish is protection from competition, predictability, see 47 U.S.C. § the very antithesis of the Act. 254(b)(5), and the statutory command of sufficient funding. To the extent petitioners argue that Congress recognized the precarious We reiterate that competitive positions of rural LEC’s, their predictability is only a prin- concerns are addressed by 47 U.S.C. § 214(e), ciple, not a statutory command. which empowers state commissions to regulate To satisfy a countervailing statutory principle, therefore, entry into rural markets.18 Furthermore, the FCC may exercise reasoned portability is not only consistent with discretion to ignore predictability, but also is dictated by principles predictability. See TOPUC, 183 of competitive neutrality and the statutory F.3d at 411-12. command that universal service support be spent “only for the provision, maintenance, Moreover, petitioners cannot and upgrading of facilities and services for even show that portability which the [universal service] support is in- violates sufficiency or tended.” 47 U.S.C. § 254(e). predictability. The purpose of universal service is to benefit the customer, not the Fourth, rather than continue to determine carrier.16 “Sufficient” the eligibility threshold for high-cost loop sup- funding of the customer’s right port by recalculating the national average loop to adequate telephone service cost, the FCC now simply will adjust the pre- can be achieved regardless of viously-calculated national average by an an- which carrier ultimately nual inflation index. Even assuming, as receives the subsidy.17 petitioners contend, that inflation adjustments to historical averages in fact would render fewer LEC’s eligible for universal service subsidies than would be the case under the 16 See, e.g., 47 U.S.C. § 254(b)(3) (stating that former approach, petitioners nevertheless fail “Consumers in all regions of the Nation” shall to show how this interim approach is receive comparable telephone service). unreasonable. Given the eventual transition 17 Petitioners estimate that the introduction of competition will result in a loss of approximately 18 25% of the customer base. The FCC counters with See 47 U.S.C. § 254(e)(2) (“Before historical trends that would predict market share designating an additional eligible losses of only 3%. Because we conclude that the telecommunications carrier for an area served by a sufficiency requirement is intended to benefit the rural telephone company, the State commission customer, not the provider, we need not resolve this shall find that the designation is in the public particular dispute. interest.”). 17 from historic cost to forward-looking cost, as they are not an issue for judicial review. For required by competition, the FCC reasonably our purposes, a waiver provision is legitimate concluded that the effort of collecting historic if the underlying rule is rational, see National cost data no longer was justified. Rural Telecomm. Ass’n v. FCC, 988 F.2d 174, 181 (D.C. Cir. 1993), and cannot save a rule Finally, petitioners claim that sales and that on its own has no rational basis, see Alltel transfers of exchanges by rural providers are Corp, 838 F.2d at 561-62. We therefore can efficient and ought to be encouraged and sub- uphold these amendments relating to the high- sidized. The Order, by contrast, denies cost loop fund without addressing the wisdom additional universal service support in cases in of allowing waivers. which a rural LEC purchases another exchange. 2. SWITCHING COSTS. Petitioners also fail to show that the FCC’s When the permanent rules for universal various changes to the treatment of switching access within the context of local competition equipment costs unreasonably fail to provide are in place, all exchanges will be governed by sufficient and explicit funding for universal ser- uniform rules with respect to universal service vice or otherwise constitute an arbitrary and support, without regard to the rural or non- capricious exercise of agency powers under rural status of the LEC. In the interim, the Act. First, petitioners claim that the however, the rules continue to treat rural and changes arbitrarily and capriciously abandon other LEC’s differently, in recognition of the cost-causation principles. They insist on re- continued greater need of rural LEC’s. The taining special weighting on the assumption opportunity thus exists for gaming the that it is in fact more costly to switch long- different universal service support regimes by distance calls than local calls. Therefore, un- transferring ownership to a rural LEC. The der cost-causative principles, IXC’s should FCC acted within its discretion to combat such pay higher access charges, because they are gaming by keying regulatory treatment to an responsible for a greater proportion of exchange’s original ownership status, without switching costs. regard to any subsequent transfer in ownership. As we have said, however, the Commission has long abandoned this assumption. Instead, The Commission argues that, as a last re- special weighting has been allowed to continue sort, the availability of waivers cures its orders solely to provide an additional subsidy to rural of any deficiency with respect to sufficiency LEC’s, an interest that would be equally and predictability.19 Even if the waiver served by the new universal service support provisions were debatable as a policy matter, fund. Indeed, the Order makes plain that the new fund shall provide support “corresponding in amount to that generated formerly by DEM 19 See 47 C.F.R. § 1.3 (general waiver provision weighting.” Order ¶ 303. Moreover, by for all FCC regulations); Fourth Reconsideration mandating that all universal service support be Order ¶ 38 (providing for waiver of indexed cap on “explicit,” 47 U.S.C. § 254(e) requires that growth in high cost loop fund); Id. at ¶¶ 93, 102, this special weighting be eliminated. 108 (providing for waiver of cap on corporate operations expenses). 18 Petitioners’ second objection simply misconstrues the requirement of “explicit” funding. They argue that, because the new fund would be financed by all telecommunications carriers, including small LEC’s such as petitioners, the new fund constitutes an unlawful subsidy in favor for IXC’s. Again, petitioners rest their argument on the same assumption deemed obsolete by the FCCSSthat long-distance switching is more costly than local switching. Even so, we made clear in TOPUC that the implicit/explicit dis- tinction turns on the difference between direct subsidies from support funds and recovery through access charges and rate structures. “The statute provides little guidance on wheth- er ‘explicit’ means ‘explicit to the consumer’ . . . or ‘explicit to the carrier’ . . . [but it] does state, however, that all universal service support should be ‘explicit.’ . . . By forcing GTE to recover its universal service contributions from its access charges, the FCC’s interpretation maintains an implicit subsidy for ILEC’s such as GTE.” 183 F.3d at 425. (d). The Commission reasonably applied the Petitioners thus misconstrue the meaning of principle of equitable and nondiscriminatory the explicit funding requirement. The fact that contribution by requiring contributions from all the fund is subsidized by contributions from all telecommunications providers. telecommunications providers, including LEC’s, does not make it an implicit subsidy Finally, petitioners object on the ground under § 254(e), even if it effectively that portability violates the principle of redistributes resources among predictability and the statutory command of telecommunications providers. sufficient funding. Specifically, they claim that, if just 25% of the revenue that the FCC Moreover, § 254(b)(4) requires “[a]ll pro- has made portable is lost by a typical small viders of telecommunications services [to] LEC, the annual rate of return for interstate make an equitable and nondiscriminatory con- access service will, in many cases, fall to minus tribution to the preservation and advancement 10.53%. of universal service.” 47 U.S.C. § 254(b)(4) (emphasis added); see also 47 U.S.C. § 254- 19 As we have said, the Commission IV. TAKINGS CHALLENGE. reasonably construed the predi ctability Notwithstanding the above analysis, principle to require only predictable rules that petitioners request us to read the Act to avoid govern distribution of the subsidies, and not to a violation of the Takings Clause. See Edward require predictable funding amounts. Indeed, J. DeBartolo Corp. v. Florida Gulf Coast to construe the predictability principle to Building & Constr. Trades Council, 485 U.S. require the latter would amount to protection 568, 575 (1988). We see no reason to invoke from competition and thereby would run the canon of avoidance, however, because we contrary to one of the primary purposes of the are simply not presented with a constitutional Act. violation. Moreover, petitioners’ approach to the pre- The Fifth Amendment protects utilities dictability principle would prohibit also the from regulations that are “so unjust as to be current subsidy effect of weighting switching confiscatory.” Duquesne Light Co. v. Bar- costs. Under the current plan, LEC’s receive asch, 488 U.S. 299, 307 (1989). Petitioners the subsidy implicitly through access therefore must show that a regulation will chargesSScosts that are realized only when “jeopardize the financial integrity of the customers make telephone calls. The old sys- companies, either by leaving them insufficient tem of implicit subsidies is no less portable operating capital or by impeding their ability to than is the explicit subsidies contemplated by raise future capital,” or they must demonstrate the new fund, for an LEC cannot assess access that the reduced subsidies “are inadequate to charges against IXC’s for the costs of a compensate current equity holders for the risk customer who has left that LEC for another associated with their investments under a mod- provider. We therefore uphold the Order over ified prudent investment scheme.” Duquesne, petitioners’ APA and Chevron challenges. 488 U.S. at 312. It is not enough that a party merely speculates that a government action will cause it harm. Rather, a taking must “‘necessarily’ result from the regulatory actions.” TOPUC, 183 F.3d at 437 (citing United States v. Riverside Bayview Homes, 474 U.S. 121, 128 n.5 (1985)). Such a showing cannot be made here “until the administrative agency has arrived at a final, definitive position regarding how it will apply the regulations at issue to the particular [property right] in question.” Williamson County Regional Planning Comm’n v. Hamilton Bank, 473 U.S. 172, 191 (1985). At the very least, therefore, petitioners must wait to experience the actual 20 consequences of the Order before a court may even begin to consider whether the FCC has 5 U.S.C. § 604(a)(5). In 1996, Congress effected a constitutional taking. Until it is provided for judicial review of agency known what level of universal service funding compliance with the RFA. See 5 U.S.C. § each petitioner will receive under the Order, 611(a)(1). We review only to determine and under what circumstances the Commission whether an agency has made a “reasonable, will grant a waiver, we cannot seriously good-faith effort” to carry out the mandate of entertain a Takings Clause challenge. the RFA. Associated Fisheries, Inc. v. Daley, 127 F.3d 104, 114 (1st Cir. 1997). Furthermore, petitioners do not present credible evidence that the Order ever will Petitioners’ RFA argument amounts to little cause the drastic consequences for rural LEC’s more than a redressing of its earlier Chevron articulated in Duquesne. The mere fact that, and APA claims. The RFA is a procedural “[f]or many rural carriers, universal service rather than substantive agency mandate, to be support provides a large share of the carriers’ sure,20 but petitioners fail to articulate specific revenues,” Order ¶ 294, is not enough to procedural flaws in the FCC’s promulgation of establish that the orders constitute a taking. the orders. In fact, both orders are The Fifth Amendment protects against takings; accompanied by substantial discussion and it does not confer a constitutional right to gov- deliberation, including consideration and ernment-subsidized profits. The Takings reasoned rejection of significant alternatives Clause thus erects no barrier to our Chevron which, in the Commission’s judgment, would and APA analysis. not have achieved with equivalent success its twin statutory mandates of universal service V. REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY ACT and local competition. The RFA requires no CHALLENGE. more.21 Under the Regulatory Flexibility Act (“RFA”), final agency rules must contain a Petitioners come closest to stating a merito- “final regulatory flexibility analysis” (“FRFA”), rious procedural objection when they assert 5 U.S.C. § 604(a), which must include that the FCC failed either to undertake or to present economic analysis. Even assuming a description of the steps the agency has that that were so, the RFA plainly does not re- taken to minimize the significant quire economic analysis, but mandates only economic impact on small entities that the agency describe the steps it took “to consistent with the stated objectives of applicable statutes, including a statement 20 of the factual, policy, and legal reasons See Associated Fisheries, 127 F.3d at 114 for selecting the alternative adopted in (stating that “section 604 does not command an agency to take specific substantive measures, but, the final rule and why each one of the rather, only to give explicit consideration to less other significant alternatives to the rule onerous options”). considered by the agency which affect the impact on small entities was re- 21 See Associated Fisheries, 127 F.3d at 115 jected. (noting that “section 604 does not require that an FRFA address every alternative, but only that it address significant ones.”). 21 minimize the significant economic impact on competition in local markets. They do not small entities consistent with the stated effect a cognizable, unconstitutional taking. objectives of applicable statutes.” 5 U.S.C. § And they were promulgated in reasonable 604(a)(5). compliance with the requirements of the RFA. We therefore DENY the petitions for review. The RFA specifically requires “a statement of the factual, policy, and legal reasons for se- Judge WIENER concurs in the judgment lecting the alternative adopted in the final only. rule.” Id. Nowhere does it require, however, cost-benefit analysis or economic modeling. Indeed, the RFA expressly states that, “[i]n complying with [section 604], an agency may provide either a quantifiable or numerical de- scription of the effects of a proposed rule or alternatives to the proposed rule, or more general descriptive statements if quantification is not practicable or reliable.” 5 U.S.C. § 607.22 We therefore conclude that the FCC reasonably complied with the requirements of the RFA. CONCLUSION. Petitioners’ various challenges fail because they fundamentally misunderstand a primary purpose of the Communications ActSSto her- ald and realize a new era of competition in the market for local telephone service while continuing to pursue the goal of universal service. They therefore confuse the requirement of sufficient support for universal service within a market in which telephone service providers compete for customers, which federal law mandates, with a guarantee of economic success for all providers, a guarantee that conflicts with competition. The FCC interim orders are reasonably tai- lored to achieving universal service and 22 See also Associated Fisheries, 127 F.3d at 115 (“Section 604 prescribes the content of an FRFA, but it does not demand a particular mode of presentation.”). 22