Slip Op. 17-146
UNITED STATES COURT OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE
____________________________________
:
MAVERICK TUBE CORPORATION, :
:
Plaintiff, :
:
v. :
: Before: Richard K. Eaton, Judge
UNITED STATES, :
: Court No. 15-00303
Defendant, :
:
and :
:
SEAH STEEL CORPORATION, :
:
Defendant-Intervenor. :
____________________________________ :
OPINION
[Plaintiff Maverick Tube Corporation’s motion for judgment on the agency record is denied, and
the United States Department of Commerce’s final negative countervailing duty determination is
sustained.]
Dated: October 27, 2017
Robert E. DeFrancesco and Brett A. Shumate, Wiley Rein, LLP, of Washington, DC, for
plaintiff. With them on the brief were Alan H. Price, Tessa V. Capeloto, Adam M. Teslik.
Loren M. Preheim, Assistant Director, Commercial Litigation Branch, Civil Division, U.S.
Department of Justice, of Washington, DC, for defendant. With him on the brief were Benjamin
C. Mizer, Principal Deputy Assistant Attorney General, Jeanne E. Davidson, Director, Claudia
Burke, Assistant Director, and Ryan M. Majerus, Trial Attorney. Of counsel on the brief was Khalil
Gharbieh, Attorney, Office of the Chief Counsel for Trade Enforcement & Compliance, U.S.
Department of Commerce, of Washington, DC.
Daniel E. Parga, Law Office of Jeffrey M. Winton PLLC, of Washington, DC, for
defendant-intervenor. With him on the brief was Jeffrey M. Winton.
Eaton, Judge:Before the court is Maverick Tube Corporation’s (“Maverick” or “plaintiff”)
motion for judgment on the agency record challenging the final determination of the United States
Court No. 15-00303 Page 2
Department of Commerce (“Commerce” or the “Department”) in Welded Line Pipe From the
Republic of Korea: Final Negative Countervailing Duty Determination, 80 Fed. Reg. 61,365
(Dep’t Commerce Oct. 13, 2015), P.R. 457 and accompanying Issues and Decision Memorandum,
P.R. 450 (“Final Determination”).
Plaintiff objects to the Final Determination on three grounds, claiming that (1) Commerce
acted contrary to law by concluding that the Government of the Republic of Korea’s (“Korean
Government”) provision of electricity to defendant-intervenor SeAH Steel Corporation (“SeAH”)
did not benefit the company; (2) Commerce’s conclusion that the Korean Government’s provision
of electricity did not benefit SeAH was unsupported by substantial evidence; and (3) Commerce’s
determination not to apply adverse facts available 1 (“AFA”) to the Korean Government was
unsupported by substantial evidence. Pl.’s Mem. Supp. Mot. J. Agency R., ECF No. 32 (“Pl.’s
Br.”) 3. Additionally, plaintiff asks the court to “remand the issue of specificity[2] to the agency”
because Commerce’s failure to reach a final determination on specificity “was contingent on its
unlawful and unreasonable finding of no benefit.” Pl.’s Br. 4.
1
If Commerce determines that the use of facts available is warranted under 19 U.S.C.
§ 1677e(a), and makes the additional finding that a party has “failed to cooperate by not acting to
the best of its ability to comply with a request for information,” it may use an adverse inference
“in selecting from among the facts otherwise available.” 19 U.S.C. § 1677e(b) (2012); Artisan
Mfg. Corp. v. United States, 38 CIT __, __, 978 F. Supp. 2d 1334, 1342 (2014). This is generally
referred to as “adverse facts available.”
2
Pursuant to the statute, a subsidy must be “specific” to be countervailable. See 19
U.S.C. § 1677(5)(A). “Specificity” may be established in several ways, one of which is by showing
that a particular industry is favored over others. See 19 U.S.C. § 1677(5A)(D)(iii)(IV) (providing
that a subsidy is specific “as a matter of fact” if “[t]he manner in which the authority providing the
subsidy has exercised discretion in the decision to grant the subsidy indicates that an enterprise or
industry is favored over others”).
Court No. 15-00303 Page 3
Defendant the United States (the “Government” or “defendant”), on behalf of Commerce,
argues that Commerce’s determination that the Korean Government’s provision of electricity
“provides no benefit to [respondent] SeAH . . . because the prices charged to [SeAH] . . . were
consistent with [the Korea Electricity Power Corporation’s (“KEPCO”)] standard pricing
mechanism,” is both in accordance with law and supported by substantial evidence. Final
Determination at 18; see Def.’s Resp. Pl.’s Mot. J. Agency R., ECF No. 39 (“Def.’s Br.”) 10.
Specifically, defendant maintains that, under the regulatory framework, Commerce properly
determined that KEPCO’s electricity prices “were set in accordance with . . . market principles”
based on Commerce’s “analysis of the [KEPCO’s] price-setting philosophy [i.e., standard pricing
mechanism].” Def.’s Br. 10. In addition, the Government maintains that Commerce did not apply
AFA lawfully because the Korean Government “was fully cooperative” by “respond[ing] to
Commerce’s multiple, detailed questionnaires. . . .” Def.’s Br. 23. Defendant’s papers do not
address the issue of specificity. Because the Government argues that Commerce properly
determined that a benefit was not conferred, however, the Government presumably believes the
issue of specificity need not be addressed. This court has jurisdiction pursuant to 28 U.S.C.
§ 1581(c) (2012); 19 U.S.C. § 1516a (a)(1)(A).
Defendant-Intervenor SeAH states that defendant “has provided sufficient justification for
denying Maverick’s motion,” and therefore, determined “it [was] not necessary . . . to explain its
own views of the issues . . . or the reasons that Maverick’s motion should be denied.” Def.-Int.’s
Resp. Pl.’s Mot. J. Agency R., ECF No. 40, 1.
Because the court finds that Commerce’s Final Determination was supported by substantial
evidence and in accordance with law, plaintiff’s motion for judgment on the agency record is
denied.
Court No. 15-00303 Page 4
LEGAL FRAMEWORK
A countervailable subsidy exists where “an authority [i.e. a government or governmental
actor] . . . provides a financial contribution . . . to a person and a benefit is thereby conferred.” 19
U.S.C. § 1677(5)(B). When the financial contribution consists of a provision of goods or services,
a benefit is found when “such goods or services are provided for less than adequate remuneration,”
with the adequacy of remuneration determined “in relation to prevailing market conditions for the
good or service being provided . . . in the country which is subject to the investigation or review.”
19 U.S.C. § 1677(5)(E)(iv). Examples of prevailing market conditions include “price, quality,
availability, marketability, transportation, and other conditions of purchase or sale.” 19 U.S.C.
§ 1677(5)(E).
Importantly for plaintiff, § 1677(5)(E)(iv) reflects a change in definition of what amounts
to a “benefit” following the passage of the Uruguay Round Agreements Act (“URAA”).3 See
Certain Softwood Lumber Prods. From Canada, 66 Fed. Reg. 43,186, 43,196 (Dep’t Commerce
Aug. 17, 2001) (preliminary affirmative countervailing duty determination). Prior to the URAA, a
subsidy would have been found present when goods or services were provided “at preferential
rates.” 19 U.S.C. § 1677(5)(A)(ii)(II) (1988). Under the former preferentiality standard,
“preferential” meant “more favorable treatment to some within the relevant jurisdiction than to
others within that jurisdiction,” but not that preferential treatment was necessarily “inconsistent
with commercial considerations.” Countervailing Duties, 54 Fed. Reg. 23,366, 23,372 (Dep’t
Commerce May 31, 1989) (notice of proposed rulemaking and request for public comments)
3
Uruguay Round Agreements Act, Pub. L. No. 103-465, § 101, 108 Stat. 4814
(codified as 19 U.S.C. § 3511 (1994)).
Court No. 15-00303 Page 5
(“1989 Proposed Rule”)4; see also Final Negative Countervailing Duty Determinations; Certain
Softwood Prods. From Canada, 48 Fed. Reg. 24,159, 24,167 (Dep’t Commerce May 31, 1983).
Following the passage of the URAA and the adoption of the “adequate remuneration”
language, Commerce concluded that it wished to “acquire some experience with the new statutory
provision before codifying [its] methodology [for determining the adequacy of remuneration] in
the form of a regulation.” Countervailing Duties: Final Rule, 63 Fed. Reg. 65,348, 65,377 (Dep’t
Commerce Nov. 25, 1998) (“Preamble”). In 1997, Commerce sought guidance as to how to
conform its regulations with the language of the URAA. See Countervailing Duties: Proposed
Rule, 62 Fed. Reg. 8818 (Dep’t Commerce Feb. 26, 1997) (notice of proposed rulemaking and
request for public comments) (“1997 Proposed Rule”). In response to the 1997 request, Commerce
received comments emphasizing the importance of basing the adequate remuneration benchmark
on market prices that have not been distorted by a government’s involvement in the market.
Commerce also received comments regarding its stated intention to continue employing a
preferentiality analysis when the government is the sole provider of goods or services (e.g., for
provisions of electricity, water, or natural gas).5 One commenter urged Commerce to codify a
4
Although not adopted, the 1989 Proposed Rule “codif[ied] much of the
Department’s existing practice with respect to the identification and measurement of subsidies
under the countervailing duty law.” Countervailing Duties, 54 Fed. Reg. at 23,366.
5
In particular, as to the anticipated inclusion of a preferentiality-based analysis in
the regulations, Commerce stated:
We should note, however, that while “adequate remuneration” has replaced
“preferential” as the standard, we do not believe this precludes us from continuing
to apply certain preferentiality-based analyses we have used in the past. See Pure
Magnesium and Alloy Magnesium from Canada, 57 FR 30946, 30949 (1992); and
Certain Fresh Cut Flowers from the Netherlands, 52 FR 3301, 3302 (1987). There
is no indication that Congress intended to change our practice with respect to
government-provided goods and services such as electricity, water, or natural gas;
i.e., goods and services provided to a wide variety of users by a government-owned
company that is usually the sole provider of the good or service.
Court No. 15-00303 Page 6
preferentiality-type analysis for such situations; others argued that this approach would not
“adequately measure the differential between the price paid for the input and the full market value
of the input.” Preamble, 63 Fed. Reg. at 65,377.
Thereafter, based on its experience and the comments it received, Commerce noted that
“[p]articular problems can arise in applying [the adequate remuneration] standard when the
government is the sole supplier of the good or service in the country or within the area where the
respondent is located.” Steel Wire Rod From Trinidad and Tobago, 62 Fed. Reg. 55,003, 55,006
(Dep’t Commerce Oct. 22, 1997) (final affirmative countervailing duty determination).
Commerce reached this conclusion because, when the government is the sole supplier of the good
or service, “there may be no alternative market prices available” to use as a benchmark against
which to measure the supplier’s price. Steel Wire Rod From Trinidad and Tobago, 62 Fed. Reg. at
55,006; see also Steel Wire Rod From Germany, 62 Fed. Reg. 54,990, 54,994 (Dep’t Commerce
Oct. 22, 1997) (final affirmative countervailing duty determination). Thus, when there is no
market-based benchmark to compare the government price to, Commerce found that it was
necessary to “examine other options” for determining whether the goods or services were provided
for adequate remuneration. Steel Wire Rod From Germany, 62 Fed. Reg. at 54,994.
In early investigations under the new statute, Commerce’s “other options” included an
examination of such factors as “whether the government has followed a consistent rate making
policy, whether it has covered its costs, whether it has earned a reasonable rate of return in setting
its rates, and/or whether it applied market principles in determining its rates.” Steel Wire Rod From
Trinidad and Tobago, 62 Fed. Reg. at 55,007; see also Steel Wire Rod From Germany, 62 Fed.
1997 Proposed Rule, 62 Fed. Reg. at 8836.
Court No. 15-00303 Page 7
Reg. 54,994. Commerce made it clear, however, that such considerations “in no way indicate[d] a
departure from [its] preference for relying on market conditions in the relevant country . . . .” Steel
Wire Rod from Trinidad and Tobago, 62 Fed. Reg. at 55,007.
After gaining some further experience with the adequate remuneration standard,
Commerce codified its methodology. See 19 C.F.R. § 351.511 (1999). To conform to the URAA,
and its preference for market-based benchmark prices, Commerce adopted a three-tiered,
hierarchical approach for determining the adequacy of remuneration of an investigated good or
service. See 19 C.F.R. § 351.511.
Under this methodology, Commerce generally begins by identifying a proper benchmark
price, which is “the price that could have constituted adequate remuneration,” and then compares
that price with the government-determined price paid by respondents. Fine Furniture (Shanghai)
Ltd. v. United States, 748 F.3d 1365, 1368 (Fed. Cir. 2014); see 19 C.F.R. § 351.511. The preferred
method is to “compar[e] the government price to a market-determined price for the good or service
resulting from actual transactions in the country in question” (a “tier one” benchmark analysis).
See 19 C.F.R. § 351.511(a)(2)(i). If no useable market-determined price can be traced to actual
transactions within the country, Commerce will then compare “the government price to a world
market price where it is reasonable to conclude that such price would be available to purchasers in
the country in question” (a “tier two” benchmark analysis). 19 C.F.R. § 351.511(a)(2)(ii). If no
world market price is available to in-country purchasers, however, Commerce will then determine
the adequacy of remuneration by “assessing whether the government price is consistent with
market principles” (thus, Commerce’s regulations provide for a “tier three” benchmark analysis).
19 C.F.R. § 351.511(a)(2)(iii).
Court No. 15-00303 Page 8
The preamble to § 351.511 states that a tier three benchmark analysis will involve an
examination of “such factors as the government’s price-setting philosophy [(i.e., standard pricing
mechanism)6], costs (including rates of return sufficient to ensure future operations), or possible
price discrimination.” Preamble, 63 Fed. Reg. at 65,378. Notably, however, Commerce stated that
it need not “put[] these factors in any hierarchy, and [it] may rely on one or more of these factors
in any particular case.” Preamble, 63 Fed. Reg. at 65,378. The Preamble then cites Pure
Magnesium and Alloy Magnesium From Canada (“Magnesium from Canada”) as an example of
a useful tier three benchmark analysis for measuring the adequacy of remuneration with respect to
government-provided goods or services when the government entity is the sole provider of the
good or service. Preamble, 63 Fed. Reg. at 65,378 (citing Magnesium from Canada, 57 Fed. Reg.
30,946 (Dep’t Commerce July 13, 1992) (final affirmative countervailing duty determination));
see also 1997 Proposed Rule, 62 Fed. Reg. at 8836 (“There is no indication that Congress intended
to change our practice [i.e., of using the Magnesium from Canada analysis,] with respect to
government-provided goods and services such as electricity . . . .”).
In Magnesium from Canada, the Department found that
the first step the Department takes in analyzing the potential preferential provision
of electricity—assuming a finding of specificity[7]—is to compare the price charged
with the applicable rate on the power company’s non-specific rate schedule. . . . If
the rate charged is consistent with the standard pricing mechanism and the company
under investigation is, in all other respects, essentially treated no differently than
6
As Commerce did in its Final Determination, the court uses the terms “price-setting
philosophy” and “standard pricing mechanism” interchangeably. See Final Determination at 26.
(“[T]he Department may rely on either the use of a standard pricing mechanism (‘price-setting
philosophy’) or a utility company’s costs . . . .”).
7
It can be presumed that specificity, in this context, means “domestic subsidies . . .
provided or required by government action to a specific enterprise or industry, or group of
enterprises or industries.” 19 U.S.C. § 1677(5)(A)(ii) (1988).
Court No. 15-00303 Page 9
other industries which purchase comparable amounts of electricity, we would
probably not find a countervailable subsidy.
Magnesium from Canada, 57 Fed. Reg. at 30,949. In other words, under the Magnesium from
Canada analysis, the Department first examines how the government-owned utility company sets
its rates and then determines whether a respondent receives a price that is better than that afforded
other companies or industries purchasing comparable amounts of electricity.
BACKGROUND
On October 16, 2014, Maverick filed a countervailing duty petition covering imports of
welded line pipe from the Republic of Korea (“Korea”) and on November 5, 2014, Commerce
initiated a countervailing duty investigation.8 Welded Line Pipe From the Rep. of Korea and the
Rep. of Turkey, 79 Fed. Reg. 67,419 (Dep’t Commerce Nov. 13, 2014) (initiation of countervailing
duty investigations). Commerce selected SeAH and NEXTEEL Co., Ltd. (“NEXTEEL”) as
mandatory respondents for individual examination. The period of investigation (“POI”) was from
January 1, 2013, through December 31, 2013. Commerce investigated, among other things,
whether KEPCO, a state-owned and controlled entity that supplied “substantially all of the
8
The scope of this investigation covered
circular welded carbon and alloy steel (other than stainless steel) pipe of a kind used
for oil or gas pipelines (welded line pipe), not more than 24 inches in nominal
outside diameter, regardless of wall thickness, length, surface finish, end finish, or
stenciling. Welded line pipe is normally produced to the American Petroleum
Institute (API) specification 5L, but can be produced to comparable foreign
specifications, to proprietary grades, or can be non-graded material.
Welded Line Pipe From the Rep. of Korea and the Rep. of Turkey, 79 Fed. Reg. 67,419, 67,423,
App. 1.
Court No. 15-00303 Page 10
electricity in Korea,” provided respondents with a countervailable subsidy in the form of the
provision of electricity for less than adequate remuneration. Final Determination at 13, 14-17.
On March 20, 2015, Commerce issued a negative preliminary determination, finding that
the Korean Government and KEPCO provided producers and exporters of welded line pipe from
Korea only de minimis countervailable subsidies.9 See Welded Line Pipe From the Rep. of Korea,
80 Fed. Reg. 14,907, 14,908 (Dep’t Commerce Mar. 20, 2015) (“Preliminary Determination”).
Following the Preliminary Determination, the Department issued supplemental
questionnaires to the Korean Government. See Letter from Yoon & Yang LLC to Sec’y
Commerce: Resp. to the Suppl. Questionnaire, C.R. 316-322, P.R. 380-386, ECF Nos. 35-2, 34-
10 (April 14, 2015) (“Suppl. Questionnaire Resp.”). In order to determine how the electricity rates
were set, the Department asked for copies of the applications KEPCO actually filed with the
Ministry of Trade, Industry and Energy (“Trade Ministry”) for the electricity tariffs in effect from
January 1 through January 13 and January 14 through November 20, 2013, which the Korean
Government had not provided during the Preliminary Determination.10 Suppl. Questionnaire Resp.
at 6-12. In response, the Korean Government submitted copies of the appropriate applications as
well as data summaries supporting the relevant tariff increases. See Suppl. Questionnaire Resp. at
6-12; see also Suppl. Questionnaire Resp., Exs. GSQ4RE-2, GSQ4RE-4, GSQ4RE-5, GSQ4RE-
9
Under 19 U.S.C. § 1671b(b)(4)(A), if the “aggregate of the net countervailable
subsidies is less than 1 percent ad valorem,” then Commerce will disregard such de minimis
countervailable subsidies.
10
According to answers submitted by the Korean Government in response to
Commerce’s supplemental questionnaires “[t]he calculation of costs provided [to Commerce
during earlier responses] are KEPCO cost[s] . . . for the entire POI [i.e., the entirety of 2013].”
Suppl. Questionnaire Resp. at 12. Nevertheless, Commerce found that the Korean Government’s
supplemental questionnaire responses “provided the necessary information to be used in
[Commerce’s] analysis as to whether the prices are in accord with a standard pricing mechanism.”
Final Determination at 30.
Court No. 15-00303 Page 11
9, GSQ4RE-10. In June, Commerce conducted a verification of the questionnaire responses.
Verification Questionnaire Resp., ECF Nos. 35-2, 42, C.R. 385, P.R. 430 (Aug. 17, 2015)
(summary of verification responses). Although Commerce ultimately found that the Korean
Government had “adequately responded to all of the Department’s detailed questions” involving
its provision of electricity to the respondents, plaintiff raised several concerns involving the
information the Korean Government submitted to Commerce regarding KEPCO’s price-setting
procedures. Final Determination at 24-26.
On October 13, 2015, Commerce issued its final negative countervailing determination.
See Final Determination. As it had in the Preliminary Determination, the Department began its
analysis by determining the proper tier under 19 C.F.R. § 351.511(a)(2) (2014). Commerce found
a tier one benchmark analysis was inappropriate because KEPCO “is the primary utility company
in Korea providing electricity to Korean consumers, and the [Korean Government] regulates the
rates that KEPCO charges for electricity.” Final Determination at 15. In other words, there was no
competitive-market determined price that could provide an adequate benchmark. In addition,
Commerce declined to use a tier two benchmark analysis because “[t]he [Korean Government] has
stated that there is no cross-border transmission or distribution of electricity in Korea,” and “the
Department will only use world market prices if the good or service is actually available to the
purchaser in the country under investigation.” Final Determination at 16. Therefore, Commerce
elected to use its “final alternative,” a tier three benchmark analysis, in which “the Department
will assess whether the prices charged by KEPCO are set in accordance with market principles
through an analysis of such factors as KEPCO’s [standard pricing mechanism], costs . . . , or
possible price discrimination.” Final Determination at 16.
Court No. 15-00303 Page 12
Based on the information used by KEPCO “to develop the tariff schedules that were
applicable during the POI,” Commerce found that the company’s prices were consistent with
market principles solely through an analysis of KEPCO’s standard pricing mechanism. Final
Determination at 17-18. In other words, Commerce did not depend on facts otherwise available,11
as it had in the Preliminary Determination, to determine how KEPCO set its rates, but rather it
relied on questionnaire responses. Specifically, Commerce first determined how KEPCO set its
rates and if they were consistent with a standard pricing mechanism. Next, the Department
“examine[d] the electricity rates charged to [the] investigated respondents to determine whether
the price charged is consistent with the power company’s standard pricing mechanism.” Final
Determination at 17. Using the analysis found in Magnesium from Canada, Commerce found that
because the rates charged to respondents were consistent with KEPCO’s standard pricing
mechanism, and the companies were “in all other respects essentially treated no differently than
other companies and industries which purchase[d] comparable amounts of electricity,”
respondents received no benefit. Final Determination at 17-18 (citing Magnesium from Canada,
57 Fed. Reg. at 30,946). That is, Commerce first determined if KEPCO had a standard pricing
mechanism and how it worked, and then examined whether this same method was employed to set
the rates for respondents and other companies and industries purchasing similar amounts of
electricity.
With respect to KEPCO’s standard pricing mechanism, Commerce verified that the utility
company developed its electricity rates based on annual cost data obtained from an independent
11
Under 19 U.S.C. § 1677e(a), if “necessary information is not available on the
record” or “an interested party or any other person . . . withholds information that has been
requested by the administering authority . . . or . . . provides such information but the information
cannot be verified,” then Commerce shall use “the facts otherwise available” in making its
determination.
Court No. 15-00303 Page 13
accounting firm that audited KEPCO’s costs and calculated its annual cost of electricity. Final
Determination at 17. Those figures were later used to calculate the tariff for each customer
classification. Final Determination at 17. Thus, the Department found:
To develop the electricity tariff schedules that were applicable during the POI,
KEPCO first calculated its overall cost including an amount for investment return.
This cost includes the operational cost for generating and supplying electricity to
the consumers as well as taxes. The cost for each electricity classification was
calculated by (1) distributing the overall cost according to the stages of providing
electricity (generation, transmission, distribution, and sales); (2) dividing each cost
into fixed cost, variable cost, and the consumer management fee; and (3) then
calculating the cost by applying the electricity load level, peak level, and the
patterns of consuming electricity. Each cost was then distributed into the fixed
charge and the variable charge. KEPCO then divided each cost taking into
consideration the electricity load level, the usage pattern of electricity,[12] and the
volume of the electricity consumed. Costs were then distributed according to the
number of consumers for each classification of electricity.
Final Determination at 17. Commerce “verified that KEPCO applied this same . . . standard pricing
mechanism to determine the electricity tariffs for each tariff classification including the industrial
tariff that was paid by the respondents during the POI” and thus found that “the [Korean
Government] provided the necessary information to be used in [the Department’s] analysis as to
whether the prices are in accord with a standard pricing mechanism” pursuant to
§ 351.511(a)(2)(iii). Final Determination at 17-18, 30. Commerce also found that there was “no
information on the record that SeAH . . . [was] treated differently from other industrial users of
electricity that purchase comparable amounts of electricity.” Final Determination at 18. Next, the
Department rejected plaintiff’s arguments that the Korean Government did not cooperate with
12
For instance, if a classification consumed most of its electricity at night when
demand was low, it would be charged less. See Detailed Approval Standards for Power Generation
Business, Standards for Calculation of Electricity Charges, Tolerance of Electricity Meters and
Electric Power System Operation (Apr. 1, 2012), ECF No. 42, Art. 9(2) (“In principle, the
electricity charges consist of basic charges, electricity volume charges and fuel cost adjustment
charges.”).
Court No. 15-00303 Page 14
Commerce and that AFA should therefore be applied because Commerce found that the Korean
Government had not failed to cooperate to the best of its ability in the proceeding. Final
Determination at 29 (“The [Korean Government] adequately responded to all of the Department’s
extensive and detailed questions in its responses . . . . Our detailed supplemental questions on
electricity were not the general result of the [Korean Government’s] unwillingness to respond to
our questions but rather, were due to the complicated nature of an analysis of market principles
required under the 19 CFR 351.[5]11(a)(2)(iii). Therefore, we disagree with the petitioner’s
argument that the [Korean Government] has prevented or forestalled the Department’s attempt to
collect the appropriate information to conduct an analysis under 19 CFR 351.[5]11(a)(2)(iii).”).
As a result, Commerce found that “consistent with 19 CFR 351.511 and Magnesium from
Canada . . . [KEPCO’s] program provides no benefit to SeAH . . . because the prices charged to
[SeAH] under the applicable industrial tariff were consistent with KEPCO’s standard pricing
mechanism” and thus, that the Korean Government provided no countervailable subsidy. Final
Determination at 18.
This action followed.
STANDARD OF REVIEW
“The court shall hold unlawful any determination, finding, or conclusion found . . . to be
unsupported by substantial evidence on the record, or otherwise not in accordance with law.” 19
U.S.C. § 1516a(b)(1)(B)(i). “Substantial evidence is defined as ‘more than a mere scintilla,’ as
well as evidence that a ‘reasonable mind might accept as adequate to support a conclusion.’”
Mukand, Ltd. v. United States, 767 F.3d 1300, 1306 (Fed. Cir. 2014) (quoting Consol. Edison Co.
of N.Y. v. NLRB, 305 U.S. 197, 229 (1938)).
Court No. 15-00303 Page 15
DISCUSSION
I. COMMERCE’S DETERMINATION THAT THE KOREAN GOVERNMENT’S PROVISION
OF ELECTRICITY DID NOT BENEFIT RESPONDENTS IS IN ACCORDANCE WITH LAW
AND SUPPORTED BY SUBSTANTIAL EVIDENCE
A. Commerce’s Use of the Standard Pricing Mechanism Analysis was in Accordance
with Law
Plaintiff’s primary argument is that Commerce, in reaching its determination, unlawfully
relied on a factor “‘which Congress has not intended it to consider.’” Pl.’s Br. 24 (quoting Motor
Vehicle Mfrs. Ass’n of U.S., Inc. v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 463 U.S. 29, 43 (1983)).
Specifically, plaintiff argues that Commerce’s use of the standard pricing mechanism analysis
found in Magnesium from Canada merely “measured price discrimination,” and thus, only
demonstrated that the Korean Government did not “provide electricity at ‘preferential’ rates.” Pl.’s
Br. 23. According to plaintiff, by “limit[ing] its examination to whether prices were consistent
with KEPCO’s standard pricing mechanism . . . Commerce failed to meaningfully consider the
question posed by the statute,” (i.e., whether the Korean Government received adequate
remuneration for its electricity) and therefore unlawfully “equated the lack of preferentiality with
adequate remuneration.” Reply Br. Pl.’s (“Pl.’s Reply Br.”) 2, 4.
Plaintiff maintains that Commerce was required by the statute to do more. It insists that
although “Congress had amended the [Tariff] Act to replace the former ‘preferential’ standard with
the current ‘adequate remuneration’ standard,” the Magnesium from Canada determination, which
Commerce relied upon, is bad precedent because it was decided prior to the statutory amendment.
Pl.’s Br. 24. (“When Commerce issued its determination in Magnesium from Canada, the Act
provided that subsidies include ‘[t]he provision of goods or services at preferential rates.’” (citing
19 U.S.C. § 1677(5)(A)(ii)(II) (1988))). For Maverick, the statutory amendment providing for
“adequate remuneration” requires Commerce to analyze whether government prices are “market-
Court No. 15-00303 Page 16
based”—a determination plaintiff asserts cannot be made solely by examining whether
respondents received a rate outside of what it would have received if the rate were set by the
standard pricing mechanism. See Pl.’s Reply Br. 3, 6 (“[A] lack of preferential pricing in and of
itself does not show that prices are market based.”). Thus, according to Maverick, Commerce’s
use of the standard pricing mechanism analysis “elevates a single citation in the [Preamble] above
what is required by the statute” and “eliminates the distinction between the preferentiality standard
and the adequacy of remuneration standard.” Pl.’s Reply Br. 3, 6.
For Commerce, however, “[d]etermining whether a government-set price for electricity is
in accordance with market principles by examining whether the electricity prices are set using the
utility company’s standard pricing [mechanism] is consistent with [its] regulations and precedent.”
Final Determination at 23 (citing Preamble, 63 Fed. Reg. at 65,378). As for the URAA’s change
to the adequate remuneration standard, defendant maintains Commerce’s regulations found at 19
C.F.R. § 351.511 complied with the statute because the regulation “flipped the regulatory
hierarchy, with market prices from the country under investigation and world market prices
moving up the hierarchy, and other considerations, including price discrimination, remaining
potentially relevant only if the preferred data are unavailable.” Def.’s Br. 20. In other words, for
Commerce, what constitutes adequate remuneration depends on the nature of the marketplace, and
where the marketplace is a government-controlled monopoly, there is a role for a preferentiality-
based test.
Defendant then contends that, contrary to plaintiff’s characterization, the concept
developed in Magnesium from Canada was “an analytical methodology distinct from simple price
discrimination.” Def.’s Br. 21; see also Final Determination at 23 (“The petitioner misinterprets
19 CFR 351.511 regarding the benefit analysis of the government provision of a good or service.”).
Court No. 15-00303 Page 17
Defendant argues that the standard pricing mechanism analysis was created “to account for the
commercial market conditions by which electricity is provided to consumers,” by implicitly
recognizing that “electricity tariffs are generally based upon the type and amount of consumption
of electricity and that utility rates vary depending on the size and classification of the electricity
consumer.” Def.’s Br. 22; see also Final Determination at 17 n.79 (“The principle of the standard
pricing mechanism recognizes the commercial and market practices and conditions for the
provision of electricity.”). Thus, factors such as amount of electricity consumed and the time of
day that it is consumed can affect the price of electricity where a government monopoly controls
the supply.
The Department also insists that it took into account acquisition costs, specifically finding
that
[t]he petitioner is correct that we did not request the cost information from
KEPCO’s generating subsidiaries. This information was not requested because the
information from the generating subsidiaries was not relevant to our analysis.
Electricity generators, including subsidiaries of KEPCO, sell electricity to the
Korea Power Exchange [(“KPX”)] and KEPCO purchases the electricity that it
distributes to all of its customers from KPX. . . . Therefore, the cost of this
electricity is identical for all the tariff classes (residential, general, industry, etc.)
within Korea. The cost of electricity is based upon the purchase price of electricity
from the KPX; therefore, this is the cost that is relevant for determining whether
KEPCO’s industrial tariff schedule is developed using a standard pricing
mechanism. We also note that the cost data underlying the tariff rate calculations
were prepared by an independent accounting firm.
Final Determination at 23-24; see also Def.’s Br. 18 (“KEPCO’s costs for electricity are based
upon the purchase price from the Korea Power Exchange, which is the cost that was relevant to
Commerce’s evaluation of whether the power company’s rates were developed using a standard
pricing mechanism.”).
In addition, Commerce claims that the standard pricing mechanism analysis is in accord
with the adequate remuneration standard found in the statute. According to defendant, its
Court No. 15-00303 Page 18
Magnesium from Canada analysis works as follows: first, the Department determines whether the
government’s standard pricing mechanism is in accordance with market-principles, and second, it
considers whether the respondents are treated any differently from other consumers. See Transcript
of Oral Argument at 13-14, Maverick Tube Corp. v. United States (No. 15-00303). Therefore,
defendant argues that it is wrong to simply call Commerce’s approach a preferentiality test. See
Def.’s Br. 21.
The court finds that (1) Commerce’s regulation is a reasonable interpretation of the statute
and (2) the Department lawfully interpreted its regulation to determine the adequacy of
remuneration for the electricity provided to respondents during the POI.
“When reviewing Commerce’s construction of the trade statute, this Court is directed by
the two-step framework set forth by Chevron.” Xiping Opeck Food Co. v. United States, 38 CIT
__, __, 34 F. Supp. 3d 1331, 1342 (2014) (citing Fine Furniture, 748 F.3d at 1369); see also
Chevron, U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837, 842-43 (1983).
The first step requires the court to determine whether Congress’ intent under the statute is clear.
Chevron, 467 U.S. at 842-43; see also Robinson v. Shell Oil Co., 519 U.S. 337, 341 (“The plainness
or ambiguity of statutory language is determined by reference to the language itself, the specific
context in which that language is used, and the broader context of the statute as a whole.”). If
Congress’ intent is clear, the court “must give effect to the unambiguously expressed intent of
Congress.” Chevron, 467 U.S. at 842-43. Should the court determine that Congress has not directly
addressed the question at issue, that is, if “the statute is silent or ambiguous with respect to the
specific issue, the question for the court is whether the agency’s answer is based on a permissible
construction of the statute.” Id. (footnote omitted). Under this second step, provided that
Court No. 15-00303 Page 19
Commerce’s construction of the statute is reasonable, it will be found to be in accordance with
law. See United States v. Eurodif S.A., 555 U.S. 305, 317 (2009).
Here, the court finds Commerce’s interpretation of the statute—namely, that when a
government is the sole, or nearly sole, provider of a good or service, Commerce may determine
the adequacy of remuneration through its standard pricing mechanism analysis (including use of a
preferentiality-based test)—to be a reasonable construction of the statute.
As an initial matter, despite plaintiff’s arguments to the contrary, Congress’ intent in
adopting the URAA amendment is unclear as to the proper method for determining the adequacy
of remuneration. Section 1677(5)(E) simply states that the adequacy of remuneration “shall be
determined in relation to prevailing market conditions for the good or service being provided . . .
in the country which is subject to the investigation or review.” 19 U.S.C. § 1677(5)(E). The statute
then gives a non-exhaustive list of “prevailing market conditions,” which include “price, quality,
availability, marketability, transportation, and other conditions of purchase or sale.” Id. Aside from
this list of conditions, the statute gives no guidance as to how the Department should interpret the
adequacy of remuneration language. It is worth noting, however, that cost of production is absent
from the list.
An examination of the Statement of Administrative Action (“SAA”)13 accompanying the
URAA reveals that 19 U.S.C. § 1677(5)(E)’s language comes almost verbatim from the guidelines
13
The SAA, which “shall be regarded as an authoritative expression by the United
States concerning the interpretation and application of the [URAA],” 19 U.S.C. § 3512(d), states:
Article 14 of the Agreement sets guidelines for methods used to calculate benefit. . . .
The guidelines set out in Article 14 are that: . . . the provision of goods or services . . .
by a government confers a benefit where the provision is made for less than
adequate remuneration . . . with the adequacy of remuneration determined in
relation to prevailing market conditions for the good or service in question in the
Court No. 15-00303 Page 20
set out in Article 14 of the Subsidies Agreement, a part of the Uruguay Round Agreement. See
Uruguay Round Agreements Act, Statement of Administrative Action, H.R. Doc. No. 103–316, at
912-13 (1994), reprinted in 1994 U.S.C.C.A.N. 4040, 4239. Therefore, while the source of the
adequacy of remuneration language is known, neither the statute, nor the SAA gives guidance as
to Congress’ intent when the words were enacted. Nor does there appear to be any legislative
history that provides guidance.
Once it has been established that the definition of “adequate remuneration” is unclear, step
two of Chevron comes into play. Under step two, the court must determine whether Commerce’s
construction of the statute is reasonable. See Chevron, 467 U.S. at 843.
The court finds that Commerce’s construction of the statute is reasonable. In a state-
controlled monopolistic market, it is reasonable to determine the adequacy of remuneration by first
examining how the state sets its rates, as the state (and not necessarily supply-and-demand)14
controls price and availability. If the state does use a standard pricing mechanism to set its rates
(i.e., if its prices are set by a consistent discernable method), it is also reasonable for Commerce to
determine the adequacy of remuneration by examining whether respondents received a preferential
rate when compared to those entities receiving a rate set by the standard pricing mechanism.
As noted, the statute directs Commerce to determine if a benefit is present by determining
whether a good or service is provided “for less than adequate remuneration.” Adequate
remuneration is to be measured by “prevailing market conditions . . . in the country which is subject
country of provision or purchase (including price, quality, availability,
marketability, transportation, and other conditions of purchase or sale).
SAA, at 912-13.
14
The provision of electricity, in particular, is often subject to state control. See, e.g.,
N.Y. POWER AUTH., ANNUAL REPORT 53 (2015).
Court No. 15-00303 Page 21
to the investigation or review.” 19 U.S.C. § 1677(5)(E). The statute does not direct Commerce to
create a fictional model market or (as shall be seen) to audit KEPCO’s books to determine if it
covers its costs. The statute directs Commerce to judge the adequacy of remuneration based on
market conditions that actually exist in Korea. That the Korean electricity market is controlled by
a state run monopoly does not change the statute.
The court, moreover, is unconvinced that simply because Magnesium from Canada was
guided by a different statutory standard, its standard pricing mechanism analysis cannot be used
to determine the adequacy of remuneration under a tier three benchmark analysis. Although the
statutory change marked a departure from defining a benefit in terms of preferentiality, that does
not mean that Magnesium from Canada’s standard pricing mechanism analysis is not relevant to
determine the adequacy of remuneration when market-based prices are unavailable. There is no
evidence in the legislative history that Congress intended the dramatic change in law plaintiff
suggests. In fact, the legislative history seems to indicate that Congress simply chose to enact the
language contained in the Uruguay Round Agreement.
Commerce’s past experience shows that, in certain situations, preferentiality-like tests may
be useful when determining the adequacy of remuneration. See, e.g., Steel Wire Rod From
Germany, 62 Fed. Reg. at 54,994.15 Indeed, in a monopolistic situation, such as the electricity
market in Korea, the state-controlled market provides the only source from which Commerce can
15
In Steel Wire Rod From Germany, Commerce determined that the Government of
the Free and Hanseatic City of Hamburg (“GOH”), which leased land to producers and exporters
of steel wire rod from Germany, used a “standard lease for all enterprises in the port area” and that
“[t]here are no special provisions made for different industries.” Steel Wire Rod From Germany,
62 Fed. Reg. at 54,994. Therefore, because the respondent “pa[id] a standard rate charged by the
GOH to all enterprises leasing land similar to [respondent’s], and because these prices are set in
reference to market conditions, [Commerce] determine[d] that [respondent’s] lease rate is not
countervailable.” Steel Wire Rod From Germany, 62 Fed. Reg. at 54,994.
Court No. 15-00303 Page 22
obtain a price. That is, in situations involving the state-controlled provision of electricity, finding
that electricity rates are based on a standard pricing mechanism and then examining if a company
or industry receives a preferential rate is a reasonable way to determine whether a state-controlled
supplier received adequate remuneration.
Plaintiff spends a great deal of time in its papers claiming that Commerce unlawfully
applied a preferential analysis in reaching its determination. In doing so, plaintiff appears to argue
that Commerce was somehow prohibited from assembling information as to whether the
respondents were charged less for their electricity than other consumers. Why this should be the
case is a bit of a mystery. Should it have developed that respondents were paying less than others
similarly situated for the provision of electrical service, this would be evidence that the rate paid
by respondents was not arrived at by the application of KEPCO’s standard pricing mechanism
(i.e., that the rate was not based on the electricity “market” in Korea). In other words, plaintiff’s
assertions fail to consider that Commerce first examined how the rates were set, and only then
asked if the market-based rates (albeit a monopolistic market) were calculated the same as the rates
respondents paid for electricity. Merely because Commerce employed an analysis it used for other
purposes elsewhere to make this comparison does not (1) prohibit Commerce from collecting
evidence of the existence (or lack thereof) of a cheap rate for respondents or (2) prohibit Commerce
from using this information to make a determination as to whether respondents’ rate was set by
the principles used to determine the rate of others purchasing electricity in the Korean market.
Plaintiff also maintains that Commerce’s explanation for its determination “is insufficient
and patently unreasonable.” Pl.’s Br. 30. The court, though, agrees with the defendant that
Maverick “cannot substitute [various third party reports] for the benchmark analysis Commerce is
required to perform pursuant to 19 C.F.R. § 351.511(a)(2).” Def.’s Br. 22. Here, Commerce found
Court No. 15-00303 Page 23
that KEPCO’s standard pricing mechanism was developed based on its annual cost data as
calculated by an independent accounting firm. Final Determination at 17. In addition, Commerce
found that KEPCO used these figures to “calculate the tariff for each customer classification”
based on standard methodologies set forth in the standards for calculation of electricity charges
issued by the Korean Ministry of Knowledge Economy. Final Determination at 17 (citing Detailed
Approval Standards for Power Generation Business, Standards for Calculation of Electricity
Charges, Tolerance of Electricity Meters and Electric Power System Operation (Apr. 1, 2012),
ECF No. 42). Commerce then found that KEPCO applied this same standard pricing mechanism
to determine respondents’ tariff rates and that respondents were not treated any differently from
“other industrial users of electricity that purchase comparable amounts of electricity.” Final
Determination at 18. Finally, as Commerce noted in its Final Determination, “[t]he principle of
the standard pricing mechanism recognizes the commercial and market practices and conditions
for the provision of electricity.” Final Determination 17 n.79. In other words, under the tier three
benchmark analysis Commerce takes the market as it finds it, even if it is, for all practical purposes,
a monopoly.
Accordingly, the court holds that Commerce’s construction of the statute—that Commerce
may determine the adequacy of remuneration based on the standard pricing mechanism analysis
developed in Magnesium from Canada—is reasonable, and thus, in accordance with law.
B. Commerce’s Interpretation of “Adequate Remuneration” was in Accordance with
Law
Maverick’s second, and related, argument is that the Department’s interpretation of
“adequate remuneration” is not in accordance with law. Pl.’s Br. 20. Specifically, plaintiff
maintains that Commerce “erred in its interpretation of ‘adequate’ because failing to recover costs
can never be adequate.” Pl.’s Br. 20. In support of its position, plaintiff cites to Webster’s II New
Court No. 15-00303 Page 24
College Dictionary, which defines “adequate” as “able to satisfy a requirement” and “remunerate”
as “to pay one for goods provided, services rendered, or losses incurred.” Pl.’s Br. 21 (quoting
Webster’s II New College Dictionary (2001)). Plaintiff maintains that, in accordance with these
definitions, the plain meaning of § 1677(5)(E) requires that adequate remuneration mean, at a
minimum, that “the seller is able to cover its costs to provide a good.” Pl.’s Br. 21.
The court, however, finds that defendant’s interpretation of “adequate remuneration” is in
accordance with law. Although plaintiff argues that Commerce misinterpreted the statute, the real
thrust of its argument is that Commerce did not look at the right information. Specifically, plaintiff
seems to argue that the only appropriate way to determine the adequacy of remuneration in this
case would be to examine KEPCO’s suppliers’ costs. See, e.g., Pl.’s Br. 22 (“[W]ithout a complete
cost build up from Korean electricity generators, beginning with fuel costs, there was no way for
the Department to determine whether [KEPCO’s] prices were set according to market
principles.”). As discussed previously, however, the preamble to § 351.511 reasonably provides
that Commerce may look solely at a government’s price-setting philosophy (i.e., its standard
pricing mechanism) under a tier three benchmark analysis. Preamble, 63 Fed. Reg. at 65,378
(“Where the government is the sole provider of a good or service, and there are no world market
prices available or accessible to the purchaser, we will assess whether the government price was
set in accordance with market principles through an analysis of such factors as the government’s
price-setting philosophy, costs . . . or possible price discrimination. We are not putting these
factors in any hierarchy, and we may rely on one or more of these factors in any particular case.”).
Indeed, § 351.511 accomplishes the post-URAA preference for market-based prices
through its hierarchical approach. When market-based prices (i.e., prices derived from actual
transactions in the country under investigation or available on the world market) are available,
Court No. 15-00303 Page 25
Commerce must compare the government price to these benchmarks. See 19 C.F.R.
§ 351.511(a)(2)(i)-(ii). When the government is the “sole supplier of a good or service,” however,
three factors are useful in determining whether a government provision of goods or services is
provided for less than adequate remuneration: the standard pricing mechanism, costs, and possible
price discrimination. Preamble, 63 Fed. Reg. at 65,378. Here, Commerce reasonably examined
KEPCO’s standard pricing mechanism and found that the Korean Government received adequate
remuneration for its electricity because it determined the respondent’s rate in the same manner it
did other industrial consumers.
While these prices were not set by what would normally be thought of as free market
principles (i.e., prices set by supply and demand), they were not the result of guesswork. In this
case, the “market” is not some hypothetical world market for electricity or even an imagined
regional one. Rather, it is the actual market for electricity in Korea. Accordingly, Commerce
verified how KEPCO developed its electricity tariffs during the POI:
KEPCO first calculated its overall cost including an amount for investment return.
This cost includes the operational cost for generating and supplying electricity[16]
to the consumers as well as taxes. The cost for each electricity classification was
calculated by (1) distributing the overall cost according to the stages of providing
electricity (generation, transmission, distribution, and sales); (2) dividing each cost
into fixed cost, variable cost, and the consumer management fee; and (3) then
16
As Commerce later clarified in its Final Determination,
[e]lectricity generators, including subsidiaries of KEPCO, sell electricity to the
KPX and KEPCO purchases the electricity that it distributes from the KPX. . . .
Therefore, the cost of this electricity is identical for all the tariff classes . . . within
Korea. Although [Maverick] is correct that the [Korean Government] did not
provide the individual generating costs for KEPCO’s generating subsidiaries, the
Department did not request this information. The costs for electricity are based
upon the purchase price of electricity from the KPX; therefore this is the cost that
is relevant for determining whether KEPCO’s industrial tariff schedule is
developed using a standard pricing mechanism.
Final Determination at 27.
Court No. 15-00303 Page 26
calculating the cost by applying the electricity load level, peak level, and the
patterns of consuming electricity. Each cost was then distributed into the fixed
charge and the variable charge. KEPCO then divided each cost taking into
consideration the electricity load level, the usage pattern of electricity, and the
volume of the electricity consumed. Costs were then distributed according to the
number of consumers for each classification of electricity.
Final Determination at 17. Commerce verified that KEPCO’s annual costs were calculated by an
independent accounting firm. Final Determination at 17. Thus, although Commerce itself did not
make a detailed analysis of KEPCO’s costs, it verified KEPCO’s costs and how they were used to
set the rates.
Commerce then focused on whether respondents were treated the same as other industrial
consumers. The Department found that respondents were not “treated differently from other
industrial users of electricity that purchase comparable amounts of electricity,” and they were
charged in accordance with KEPCO’s standard pricing mechanism. Final Determination at 18.
Commerce then reasonably determined that KEPCO’s prices reflected the Korean electricity
market, and thus, that respondents were not receiving a better price than other consumers in the
Korean market.
Plaintiff insists, however, that the Department was required to determine if the price
respondents paid covered the costs to provide electricity in all market conditions. Pl.’s Br. 21-22.
Not only is this finding not directed by the dictionary definitions of “adequate” and “remuneration”
plaintiff provides in its papers (i.e., “able to satisfy a requirement” and “pay one for goods provided”
does not equal cover costs), but it is elemental that the functioning of a free market guided by the
law of supply and demand sometimes results in sales below cost. Since covering costs would not
be required in a tier one or tier two benchmark analysis, it is difficult to see how it should be
required here.
Court No. 15-00303 Page 27
Accordingly, Commerce’s interpretation of “adequate remuneration,” namely, that in a tier
three benchmark analysis, the adequacy of remuneration may be determined by taking into account
a standard pricing mechanism analysis, was reasonable and thus in accordance with law.
C. Commerce Has Supported its Benefit Analysis with Substantial Evidence
Plaintiff argues that “Commerce failed to provide a satisfactory explanation for concluding
that Korean electricity prices are set in accordance with market principles” as required by 19 C.F.R.
§ 351.511(a)(2)(iii). Pl.’s Br. 28. Specifically, plaintiff contends that, because there is record
evidence that KEPCO’s electricity tariffs were not set by supply and demand and may be below
cost, there are therefore “significant pricing distortions throughout the Korean electricity market.”
Pl.’s Br. 28. For plaintiff, Commerce must explain why such evidence does not undermine its
determination that the KEPCO’s prices were set in accordance with market principles under the
regulation. Pl.’s Br. 30. Accordingly, plaintiff argues that Commerce’s conclusion unlawfully
“‘suggest[s] a result contrary to clear weight of the evidence’” and thus is not supported by
substantial evidence. Pl.’s Br. 18 (quoting USX Corp. v. United States, 11 CIT 82, 84, 655 F. Supp.
487, 489 (1987)).
Maverick bases this argument on the results of a 2013 Korean National Assembly report,
which found that KEPCO sells electricity for less than cost. Pl.’s Br. 29 (“‘The government
subsidizes and charges less-than-normal electricity cost to the steel industries for their exceeding
use of electricity. . . . The 100 biggest corporations [in Korea] are using over KRW 9 trillion worth
of discounted industrial scale electricity. . . . There are huge losses because of discounted industrial
electricity consumption.’” (quoting Initial Questionnaire Resp., C.R. 76, P.R. 127, ECF. No. 35-2
(Jan. 21, 2015) Ex. E-4)). Plaintiff also supports its argument by referencing the Korean Board of
Audit and Inspection report, which stated that KEPCO’s electricity tariffs for industrial use
covered only 85.8 percent of its production costs. Pl.’s Br. 29 (citing Petition for Imposition of
Court No. 15-00303 Page 28
Antidumping and Countervailing Duties, C.R. 1-28, P.R. 1-28, ECF No. 35-2 (Oct. 16, 2014) Ex.
IV-49). Maverick then notes that some record evidence indicates that KEPCO itself has conceded
that it sells electricity at a loss. Pl.’s Br. 30 (“‘The distortion of the energy price structure resulting
from the less-than-cost electricity prices has rapidly increased electricity consumption in place of
petroleum or gas, which has resulted in record high electricity consumption peaks in winter seasons
since 2009.’” (quoting Suppl. Questionnaire Resp., Ex. GSQ4RE-4)).
Finally, Maverick adds that the Korean Government’s “failure to provide and Commerce’s
refusal to request data regarding KEPCO’s actual costs of generating electricity” undermines its
conclusion that the cost of electricity is identical for all classes of consumers and for Commerce
“to conclude that the only relevant question is the price at which KEPCO purchased the electricity
from its affiliate, the KPX, wholly ignores the fact that KEPCO’s subsidiaries generated the
electricity, which KEPCO is reselling at a loss.” Pl.’s Br. 31, 33. Therefore, plaintiff argues that
Commerce’s determination is not supported by substantial evidence.
In response, the Government argues that Commerce verified that KEPCO developed its
electricity tariff schedules during the POI based on (1) the company’s annual cost data, as audited
and calculated by an independent accounting firm, and (2) Korea’s standard methodology for
establishing electricity tariffs. Def.’s Br. 13 (citing Final Determination at 17). Defendant then
notes that Commerce also verified that this same standard pricing mechanism was applied during
the POI. Accordingly, defendant argues that, using the factors found in 19 C.F.R.
§ 351.511(a)(2)(iii) and the Preamble, substantial evidence supported Commerce’s determination
that the prices were set in accordance with market principles. Def.’s Br. 15-16.
Also, as has been noted, defendant maintains that Commerce did not ignore costs in its
analysis. Def.’s Br. 17. Specifically, the Government contends that “KEPCO developed its
Court No. 15-00303 Page 29
electricity tariff schedules based on the company’s annual cost data, as audited and calculated by
an independent accounting firm, and an amount for investment return . . . [and] Commerce
explained that it relied on the cost data underlying KEPCO’s standard price calculations because
they were prepared by an independent accounting firm, which served to support their accuracy.”
Def.’s Br. 17 (citing Final Determination at 17, 28, 30 n.132). Therefore, in Commerce’s view, the
use of numbers overseen by an independent accounting firm as part of KEPCO’s standard pricing
mechanism established that the electricity tariffs would capture KEPCO’s costs, even if Commerce
did not actually audit the numbers provided. See Def.’s Br. 17.
Defendant further argues that “Commerce did not ignore the reports [cited by plaintiff];
rather, it utilized and referred to multiple reports in its summary of background information in the
[Final Determination].” Def.’s Br. 22. The Government then notes that Commerce reviewed the
Korea National Assembly report on KEPCO, but found that respondents were not among the
companies for which KEPCO reported losses. Def.’s Br. 23 (citing Final Determination at 14, 23).
In other words, Commerce did not find this evidence as convincing as plaintiff.
As to Commerce’s decision not to request cost information from KEPCO’s electricity-
generating subsidiaries, defendant insists that this information “was not relevant” to its analysis
because KEPCO’s subsidiaries “sold electricity to the [KPX], which then sold KEPCO nearly all
of the electricity it distributed.” Def.’s Br. 17-18 (citing Final Determination at 23-24). Put another
way, for defendant, the relevant cost associated with KEPCO’s standard pricing mechanism was
the purchase price paid to KPX, not electricity-generation costs. Def.’s Br. 18. Therefore,
defendant maintains that, by verifying the information used to develop KEPCO’s rates, Commerce
verified all that was required under its regulations and the preamble to § 351.511(a)(2)(iii) (i.e.,
Court No. 15-00303 Page 30
that KEPCO used a standard pricing mechanism), and its determination is thus supported by
substantial evidence.
The court finds that Commerce’s determination was supported by substantial evidence.
“Substantial evidence is ‘such relevant evidence as a reasonable mind might accept as adequate to
support a conclusion.’” Huaiyin Foreign Trade Corp. v. United States, 322 F.3d 1369,1374
(quoting Consol. Edison Co., 305 U.S. at 229). As discussed above, Commerce provided a clear
explanation for why KEPCO’s standard pricing mechanism was in accordance with market
principles (albeit the principles of a monopolistic market), and thus, why the Korean Government
received adequate remuneration. See supra Section I.B. Here, Commerce was able to verify that
“KEPCO applied the same price-setting philosophy or standard pricing mechanism to determine
the electricity tariffs for each tariff classification including the industrial tariff that was paid by
[SeAH] during the POI” and further found that “there is no information on the record that SeAH
. . . [is] treated differently from other industrial users of electricity that purchase comparable
amounts of electricity,” and thus, reasonably determined that, pursuant to § 351.511(a)(2)(iii),
respondents did not receive a benefit. Final Determination at 17-18.
Although plaintiff makes arguments that the record is devoid of evidence supporting
Commerce’s conclusion because certain financial information could not be traced, the court notes
that Commerce reasonably found that this evidence (e.g., data sourced from the KEPCO Data
Network17) was not necessary to verify the standard pricing mechanism used by KEPCO to set its
electricity tariffs as required under a tier three benchmark analysis. Therefore, because
17
The KEPCO Data Network is a “statistical division within KEPCO.” Verification
Questionnaire Resp. at 10.
Court No. 15-00303 Page 31
Commerce’s method conformed to the law and the information Commerce relied on was fully
verifiable, its determination is supported by substantial evidence.
Based on the forgoing, the court finds that the Department has cited substantial evidence
that respondents did not receive a benefit by KEPCO’s provision of electricity.
II. COMMERCE’S DETERMINATION NOT TO APPLY ADVERSE FACTS AVAILABLE TO THE
KOREAN GOVERNMENT WAS SUPPORTED BY SUBSTANTIAL EVIDENCE
Finally, Maverick argues that the Department’s failure to apply AFA to the Korean
Government is unsupported by substantial evidence and an abuse of discretion. Pl.’s Br. 43. Under
19 U.S.C. § 1677e(b), when a party fails to act to the best of its ability in responding to information
requests, Commerce may apply AFA. According to Maverick, “the [Korean Government]
blatant[ly] refus[ed] to cooperate to the best of its ability with Commerce’s repeated requests for
necessary information.” Pl.’s Br. 43. Specifically, plaintiff claims that the Korean Government did
not provide cost data in electronic format, did not make necessary officials available, did not
provide electricity generation costs, and that it provided “insufficient, incomplete, and inconsistent
questionnaire responses to Commerce.” Pl.’s Br. 43.
Defendant argues that the Korean Government was “fully cooperative,” and responded to
Commerce’s multiple and detailed questionnaires. Def.’s Br. 23. Defendant notes that “an
interested party fails to cooperate to ‘the best of its ability’” when it fails to “‘put forth its maximum
effort to provide Commerce with full and complete answers to all inquiries.’” Def.’s Br. 24
(quoting Nippon Steel Corp. v. United States, 337 F.3d 1373, 1382 (Fed. Cir. 2003)). Defendant
emphasizes, that Commerce is “only required to verify factual information relied upon in making
its final determination.” Def.’s Br. 24 (citing 19 U.S.C. § 1677e(a)(2)(D)); 19 U.S.C.
§ 1677m(i)(1). Thus, Commerce claims that it did not rely on unverified data in making its final
Court No. 15-00303 Page 32
determination and that it was able to verify how KEPCO set its prices based on the questionnaire
responses. Def.’s Br. 24 (citing Final Determination at 26-27, 30). Commerce states that the
Korean Government cooperated by providing the information needed to complete this verification.
Final Determination at 29-30.
With regard to the lack of electricity-generating cost information, defendant contends that
Commerce did not ask the Korean Government to provide this information, because, as has been
seen, it deemed that the information was irrelevant. Def.’s Br. 25 (citing Final Determination at
27). Next, the Government maintains that Commerce issued a substantial number of questionnaires
not because of the Korean Government’s “unwillingness to respond, but rather of the complicated
nature of an analysis of market principles under 19 C.F.R. § 351.511(a)(2)(iii).” Def.’s Br. 25
(citing Final Determination at 29). Therefore, according to defendant, none of the grounds for
applying AFA pursuant to § 1677e(b) were present, and Commerce’s failure to apply AFA was
supported by substantial evidence.
The court finds that Commerce reasonably determined that the use of AFA was not
required by the facts or the law. The Korean Government provided extensive answers to
Commerce’s detailed and complicated questions in its January 21, 2015, March 6, 2015, March
11, 2015, April 14, 2015, and May 19, 2015 responses. See Final Determination at 29. Based on
these responses, Commerce was able to verify the information it actually used to reach its
determination. No interested party can be found to have failed to cooperate for not answering
questions it was not asked. Nor can a party be found to have failed to cooperate by not providing
information irrelevant to a proceeding. Accordingly, it cannot be said that the Korean Government
failed to “put forth its maximum effort to provide Commerce with full and complete answers to all
Court No. 15-00303 Page 33
inquiries” in this investigation. Nippon Steel Corp., 337 F.3d at 1382. Commerce, then, reasonably
determined it was unnecessary to apply AFA in this case.
CONCLUSION
For the foregoing reasons, plaintiff’s motion for judgment on the agency record is denied.
Judgment will be entered accordingly.
Dated: October 27, 2017
New York, New York
/s/ Richard K. Eaton
Richard K. Eaton, Judge