Slip Op. 02-118
UNITED STATES COURT OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE
BEFORE: SENIOR JUDGE NICHOLAS TSOUCALAS
________________________________________
:
LUOYANG BEARING FACTORY, :
:
Plaintiff and :
Defendant-Intervenor, :
:
v. : Consol. Court No.
: 99-12-00743
UNITED STATES, :
:
Defendant, :
:
and :
:
THE TIMKEN COMPANY, :
:
Defendant-Intervenor :
and Plaintiff. :
________________________________________:
This consolidated action concerns the claims raised by
plaintiff and defendant-intervenor, Luoyang Bearing Factory
(“Luoyang”), and defendant-intervenor and plaintiff, The Timken
Company (“Timken”), who move pursuant to USCIT R. 56.2 for judgment
upon the agency record challenging the Department of Commerce,
International Trade Administration’s (“Commerce”) final
determination, entitled Final Results of 1997-1998 Antidumping Duty
Administrative Review and Final Results of New Shipper Review of
Tapered Roller Bearings and Parts Thereof, Finished and Unfinished,
From the People’s Republic of China (“Final Results”), 64 Fed. Reg.
61,837 (Nov. 15, 1999).
Specifically, Luoyang contends that Commerce erred in
selecting, for valuing the bearing quality steel bar used to
manufacture tapered roller bearings (“TRBs”) cups and cones, export
data from Japan to India, rather than reviewing and using People’s
Republic of China (“PRC”) trading company import data.
Timken contends that Commerce erred in: (1) including
“consumption of traded goods” in Indian bearing producers’ direct
input costs when calculating the overhead, selling, general and
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 2
administrative expenses (“SG&A”) and profit rates; (2) selecting,
for valuing PRC labor costs, the wage rates in Chapter 5 of the
International Labor Office’s (“ILO”) 1998 Yearbook of Labor
Statistics (“1998 Yearbook”) rather than the labor costs reported
in Chapter 6A of the ILO’s 1998 Yearbook; (3) valuing certain steel
inputs by using the price paid by a PRC bearing producer to a
market-economy supplier; and (4) excluding the annual report data
of the National Engineering Company (“NEI”) in Commerce’s
determination of overhead, SG&A and profit rates.
Held: Luoyang’s 56.2 motion is granted. Timken’s 56.2 motion
is granted in part and denied in part. This case is remanded to
Commerce to: (1)(a) examine whether or not the PRC trading company
import prices constitute the “best available information” to value
either all of the subject merchandise at issue or a portion of the
subject merchandise purchased by Luoyang through the trading
company and used by Luoyang in the manufacture of TRB cups and
cones and, if Commerce concludes that the PRC trading company
import prices present the “best available information” for the
purpose of such surrogate evaluation, to recalculate Commerce’s
determination not inconsistent with this opinion; and (b) examine
if, and only if, Commerce finds that the PRC trading company import
prices do not constitute the “best available information,” whether
or not Indonesian data (that is, Indonesian import statistics and
export data from Japan to Indonesia) constitute the “best available
information” over export data from Japan to India to value the
bearing quality steel bar used in the production of TRB cups and
cones, and to explain, (if Commerce finds that export data from
Japan to India is the “best available information,”) how the entire
export data from Japan to India falls within the range of values in
the United States category benchmark range; (2) exclude
“consumption of traded goods” from Commerce’s overhead, SG&A and
profit rate calculations and to recalculate the dumping margins
accordingly; and (3) (a) explain, with reference to the record,
whether or not the PRC bearing producer’s import data at issue was
“meaningful”; and (b) provide the Court with an explanation as to
why the PRC trading company data is not the “best available
information” for the purpose of valuing either the entire factor of
production (“FOP”) (that is, both the directly imported FOP and the
non-market economy country (“NME”) sourced FOP) or the NME sourced
FOP. Commerce’s final determination is affirmed in all other
respects.
[Luoyang’s 56.2 motion is granted. Timken’s 56.2 motion is granted
in part and denied in part. Case remanded.]
Dated: October 1, 2002
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 3
Hume & Associates, PC (Robert T. Hume and Stephen M. De Luca)
for Luoyang, plaintiff and defendant-intervenor.1
Robert D. McCallum, Jr., Assistant Attorney General; David M.
Cohen, Director, Commercial Litigation Branch, Civil Division,
United States Department of Justice (Lucius B. Lau); of counsel:
Rina Goldenberg, Office of the Chief Counsel for Import
Administration, United States Department of Commerce, for the
United States, defendant.
Stewart and Stewart (Terence P. Stewart, Geert De Prest,
Wesley K. Caine and Amy S. Dwyer) for Timken, defendant-intervenor
and plaintiff.
OPINION
TSOUCALAS, Senior Judge: This consolidated action concerns
the claims raised by plaintiff and defendant-intervenor, Luoyang
Bearing Factory (“Luoyang”), and defendant-intervenor and
plaintiff, The Timken Company (“Timken”), who move pursuant to
USCIT R. 56.2 for judgment upon the agency record challenging the
Department of Commerce, International Trade Administration’s
(“Commerce”) final determination, entitled Final Results of 1997-
1998 Antidumping Duty Administrative Review and Final Results of
New Shipper Review of Tapered Roller Bearings and Parts Thereof,
Finished and Unfinished, From the People’s Republic of China
(“Final Results”), 64 Fed. Reg. 61,837 (Nov. 15, 1999).
1
On January 26, 2000, this Court granted Luoyang’s Consent
Motion For Intervention but Luoyang has not filed any briefs as a
defendant-intervenor in this action.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 4
Specifically, Luoyang contends that Commerce erred in
selecting, for valuing the bearing quality steel bar used to
manufacture tapered roller bearings (“TRBs”) cups and cones, export
data from Japan to India, rather than reviewing and using People’s
Republic of China (“PRC”) trading company import data.
Timken contends that Commerce erred in: (1) including
“consumption of traded goods” in Indian bearing producers’ direct
input costs when calculating the overhead, selling, general and
administrative expenses (“SG&A”), and profit rates; (2) selecting,
for valuing PRC labor costs, the wage rates in Chapter 5 of the
International Labor Office’s (“ILO”) 1998 Yearbook of Labor
Statistics (“1998 Yearbook”) rather than the labor costs reported
in Chapter 6A of the ILO’s 1998 Yearbook; (3) valuing certain steel
inputs by using the price paid by a PRC bearing producer to a
market-economy supplier; and (4) excluding the annual report data
of the National Engineering Company (“NEI”) in Commerce’s
determination of overhead, SG&A and profit rates.
BACKGROUND
This case concerns the antidumping duty order on TRBs and
parts thereof, finished and unfinished, from the PRC for the period
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 5
of review (“POR”) covering June 1, 1997, through May 31, 1998.2
See Final Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at 61,837. On July 8, 1999,
Commerce published the preliminary results of the subject review.
See Preliminary Results of 1997-1998 Antidumping Duty
Administrative Review and Partial Recission of Antidumping Duty
Administrative Review of Tapered Roller Bearings and Parts Thereof,
Finished and Unfinished, From the People’s Republic of China
(“Preliminary Results”), 64 Fed. Reg. 36,853. Commerce published
the Final Results on November 15, 1999. See Final Results, 64 Fed.
Reg. 61,837.
JURISDICTION
The Court has jurisdiction over this matter pursuant to 19
U.S.C. § 1516a(a) (2000) and 28 U.S.C. § 1581(c) (2000).
STANDARD OF REVIEW
In reviewing a challenge to Commerce’s final determination in
an antidumping administrative review, the Court will uphold
Commerce’s determination unless it is “unsupported by substantial
2
Since the administrative review at issue was initiated after
December 31, 1994, the applicable law is the antidumping statute as
amended by the Uruguay Round Agreements Act (“URAA”), Pub. L. No.
103-465, 108 Stat. 4809 (1994) (effective January 1, 1995). See
Torrington Co. v. United States, 68 F.3d 1347, 1352 (Fed. Cir.
1995) (citing URAA § 291(a)(2), (b) (noting effective date of URAA
amendments)).
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 6
evidence on the record, or otherwise not in accordance with law .
. . .” 19 U.S.C. § 1516a(b)(1)(B)(i) (1994).
I. Substantial Evidence Test
Substantial evidence is “more than a mere scintilla. It means
such relevant evidence as a reasonable mind might accept as
adequate to support a conclusion.” Universal Camera Corp. v. NLRB,
340 U.S. 474, 477 (1951) (quoting Consolidated Edison Co. v. NLRB,
305 U.S. 197, 229 (1938)). Substantial evidence “is something less
than the weight of the evidence, and the possibility of drawing two
inconsistent conclusions from the evidence does not prevent an
administrative agency’s finding from being supported by substantial
evidence.” Consolo v. Federal Maritime Comm’n, 383 U.S. 607, 620
(1966) (citations omitted). Moreover, “[t]he court may not
substitute its judgment for that of the [agency] when the choice is
‘between two fairly conflicting views, even though the court would
justifiably have made a different choice had the matter been before
it de novo.’” American Spring Wire Corp. v. United States, 8 CIT
20, 22, 590 F. Supp. 1273, 1276 (1984) (quoting Penntech Papers,
Inc. v. NLRB, 706 F.2d 18, 22-23 (1st Cir. 1983) (quoting, in turn,
Universal Camera, 340 U.S. at 488)).
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 7
II. Chevron Two-Step Analysis
To determine whether Commerce’s interpretation and application
of the antidumping statute is “in accordance with law,” the Court
must undertake the two-step analysis prescribed by Chevron U.S.A.
Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837
(1984). Under the first step, the Court reviews Commerce’s
construction of a statutory provision to determine whether
“Congress has directly spoken to the precise question at issue.”
Id. at 842. “To ascertain whether Congress had an intention on the
precise question at issue, [the Court] employ[s] the ‘traditional
tools of statutory construction.’” Timex V.I., Inc. v. United
States, 157 F.3d 879, 882 (Fed. Cir. 1998) (citing Chevron, 467
U.S. at 843 n.9). “The first and foremost ‘tool’ to be used is the
statute’s text, giving it its plain meaning. Because a statute’s
text is Congress’ final expression of its intent, if the text
answers the question, that is the end of the matter.” Id.
(citations omitted). Beyond the statute’s text, the tools of
statutory construction “include the statute’s structure, canons of
statutory construction, and legislative history.” Id. (citations
omitted); but see Floral Trade Council v. United States, 23 CIT 20,
22 n.6, 41 F. Supp. 2d 319, 323 n.6 (1999) (noting that “[n]ot all
rules of statutory construction rise to the level of a canon,
however”) (citation omitted).
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 8
If, after employing the first prong of Chevron, the Court
determines that the statute is silent or ambiguous with respect to
the specific issue, the question for the Court becomes whether
Commerce’s construction of the statute is permissible. See
Chevron, 467 U.S. at 843. Essentially, this is an inquiry into the
reasonableness of Commerce’s interpretation. See Fujitsu Gen. Ltd.
v. United States, 88 F.3d 1034, 1038 (Fed. Cir. 1996). Provided
Commerce has acted rationally, the Court may not substitute its
judgment for the agency’s. See Koyo Seiko Co. v. United States,
36 F.3d 1565, 1570 (Fed. Cir. 1994) (holding that “a court must
defer to an agency’s reasonable interpretation of a statute even if
the court might have preferred another”); see also IPSCO, Inc. v.
United States, 965 F.2d 1056, 1061 (Fed. Cir. 1992). The “[C]ourt
will sustain the determination if it is reasonable and supported by
the record as a whole, including whatever fairly detracts from the
substantiality of the evidence.” Negev Phosphates, Ltd. v. United
States, 12 CIT 1074, 1077, 699 F. Supp. 938, 942 (1988) (citations
omitted). In determining whether Commerce’s interpretation is
reasonable, the Court considers the following non-exclusive list of
factors: the express terms of the provisions at issue, the
objectives of those provisions and the objectives of the
antidumping scheme as a whole. See Mitsubishi Heavy Indus. v.
United States, 22 CIT 541, 545, 15 F. Supp. 2d 807, 813 (1998).
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 9
DISCUSSION
I. Commerce’s Selection of Export Data from Japan to India as a
Surrogate Value for Bearing Quality Steel Bar Used by a PRC
Producer to Manufacture TRB Cups and Cones
A. Background
1. Statutory Background
An antidumping margin is the difference between normal value
(“NV”) and United States price of the merchandise. When the
merchandise is produced in a non-market economy country (“NME”)
such as the PRC, Commerce constructs NV pursuant to section
1677b(c), which provides that
the valuation of the factors of production shall be based
on the best available information regarding the values of
such factors in a market economy country or countries
considered to be appropriate by [Commerce].
19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(1) (1994) (emphasis supplied).
The statute does not define the phrase "best available
information,” it only provides that
[Commerce], in valuing factors of production . . . ,
shall utilize, to the extent possible, the prices or
costs of factors of production in one or more market
economy countries that are--
(A) at a level of economic development comparable to
that of the nonmarket economy country, and
(B) significant producers of comparable merchandise.
19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(4) (1994) (emphasis supplied).
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 10
Thus, the statute grants to Commerce broad discretion to
determine the “best available information” in a reasonable manner
on a case-by-case basis. See Lasko Metal Prods., Inc. v. United
States (“Lasko”), 43 F.3d 1442, 1446 (Fed. Cir. 1994) (noting that
the statute “simply does not say--anywhere--that the factors of
production must be ascertained in a single fashion.”)
Consequently, Commerce values as many factors of production
(“FOPs”) as possible using information obtained from the “primary”
surrogate country, that is, the country that Commerce considers to
be most comparable in economic terms to the NME country being
investigated, and that also produces merchandise comparable to the
subject merchandise. See, e.g., Tianjin Mach. Import & Export
Corp. v. United States, 16 CIT 931, 940-41, 806 F. Supp. 1008, 1018
(1992); Timken Co. v. United States, 16 CIT 142, 143-44, 788 F.
Supp. 1216, 1218 (1992). Additionally, if Commerce determines that
suitable values cannot be obtained from the data of the primary
surrogate country, Commerce resorts to the data from the second,
and sometimes the third, surrogate. See, e.g., Timken Co. v.
United States (“Timken 2001"), 25 CIT __, __, 166 F. Supp. 2d 608,
621-23 (2001); Notice of Final Determination of Sales at Less Than
Fair Value: Certain Cased Pencils From the People’s Republic of
China, 59 Fed. Reg. 55,625, 55,629 (Nov. 8, 1994); Final
Determination of Sales at Less Than Fair Value: Certain Helical
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 11
Spring Lock Washers From the People’s Republic of China, 58 Fed.
Reg. 48,833, 48,835 (Sept. 20, 1993).
2. Factual Background
During this review, Commerce initially chose secondary
surrogate data (that is, export data from Japan to Indonesia) over
data from the primary surrogate country (that is, India) to value
bearing quality steel bar used by Luoyang, a PRC producer, in the
manufacturing of TRB cups and cones.3 See Preliminary Results, 64
Fed. Reg. at 36,856; see also Def.’s Mem. Opp’n Luoyang’s Mot. J.
Agency R. (“Def.’s Mem. Opp’n Luoyang”), App. Ex. 4. In the
Preliminary Results, Commerce also determined that it would use
export data from Japan to Indonesia to value the steel bar
purchased by Luoyang from a PRC trading company rather than that
“trading company[’s] prices.” Preliminary Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at
36,856.
Commerce explained that in order to value the steel bar used
by Luoyang to manufacture TRB cups and cones, Commerce compared
3
“To make cups and cones, Luoyang used both domestic and
imported hot-rolled[,] [that is, bearing quality] steel bar. The
imported steel bar was imported from a market economy country for
Luoyang by a [PRC] trading company.” Pl.’s Mem. P. & A. Supp. Rule
56.2 Mot. J. Agency R. (“Luoyang’s Mem.”) at 5 (emphasis supplied);
see also Def.’s Mem. Opp’n Luoyang’s Mot. J. Agency R. (“Def.’s
Mem. Opp’n Luoyang”) at 3-5 (citing Def.’s Mem. Opp’n Luoyang,
Proprietary App. Exs. 1, 2, and 4).
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 12
several data sources (including: (1) Indian import statistics; (2)
export data from Japan to India; (3) Indonesian import statistics;
and (4) export data from Japan to Indonesia) to the United States
import statistics for the Harmonized Tariff Schedule (“HTS”)
category which “isolates bearing quality steel used in the
production of cups and cones and has been used for comparison
purposes in past reviews.” Def.’s Mem. Opp’n Luoyang, App. Ex. 4
at 4 (citing Final Results of 1996-1997 Antidumping Duty
Administrative Review and New Shipper Review and Determination Not
To Revoke Order in Part of Tapered Roller Bearings and Parts
Thereof, Finished and Unfinished, From the People’s Republic of
China (“10th Annual Review”), 63 Fed. Reg 63,842, 63,845 (Nov. 17,
1998)). Commerce reasoned that it decided to use export data from
Japan to Indonesia to value steel bar used in the production of TRB
cups and cones over import data from India because Commerce
determined that steel values contained in the Indian import data
were not reliable for two reasons: (1) Commerce was unable to
isolate Indian import value for bearing quality steel used to
manufacture the merchandise at issue; and (2) when compared with
the United States import statistics “the[] Indian values [were] too
high to be considered a reliable indicator of the value of bearing
quality steel used for the production of cups and cones.” Def.’s
Mem. Opp’n Luoyang, App. Ex. 4 at 4. Similarly, Commerce
determined that: (1) export data from Japan to India was unreliable
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 13
because “the prices [were] too high, when compared to the U.S.
benchmark,” id.; and (2) “[a]lthough . . . Indonesian [import
statistics] [were] closer to the U.S. benchmark in terms of price
than the Indian values, like the Indian data, the Indonesian import
statistics d[id] not provide a further breakdown of the
aforementioned Indonesian basket category.” Id. at 4-5. Commerce,
however, re-examined the matter after considering comments made by
Timken, namely, that Commerce can use a “range of [United States
import] prices contained in HTS category 7228.30.20 . . . to gauge
the reliability of Indian import values.” Final Results, 64 Fed.
Reg. at 61,839.
Upon examining the United States import data from HTS category
7228.30.20, Commerce determined that during the POR, “the range of
prices from the countries with the most significant volumes of
sales [was] approximately $642 [per metric ton (“MT”)] to $834 [per
MT].” Id. In the Final Results, Commerce compared Indian import
data to the range of United States prices and found that: (1) as
“in the past, [Commerce] [was] unable to isolate bearing quality
steel in Indian import category 7228.30 because none of the eight-
digit sub-categories within 7228.30 specifically include bearing
quality steel bar,” id. at 61,839-40; and (2) although the
“‘Others’ category, 7228.3019, could contain the type of steel [at
issue,] . . . the Indian values continue to be unreliable because
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 14
the values for these imports remain significantly higher than any
price in the U.S. import range.” Id. at 61,840.
Since the Indian import data was unreliable, Commerce then
proceeded to examine export data from Japan to India. Id.
Commerce observed that the export data from Japan to India “f[e]ll
within the range of the values in the U.S. [benchmark] category,”
7228.30.20, that is, the value of steel imported into the United
States during the POR which ranged from $642 per MT to $834 per MT.
Id. Consequently, Commerce concluded that export data from Japan
to India would constitute the best available information to value
steel used to produce the merchandise at issue. See id. Commerce
stated that
[b]ecause this Japanese tariff category is the narrowest
category which could contain bearing quality steel, and
because it is consistent with values contained in . . .
[the United States] benchmark category, [Commerce]
believe[s] that these data are the best alternative for
valuing steel used in the production of cups and cones.
It is [Commerce’s] stated preference to use information
from its primary surrogate to the extent possible. . .
. Because these data relate to [Commerce’s] primary
surrogate and are within the price range of the U.S.
benchmark category, [Commerce] ha[s] not analyzed data
from [Commerce’s] secondary surrogate, Indonesia, to find
a value for steel used to produce cups and cones.
Final Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at 61,840.
Commerce refused to use Luoyang’s PRC trading company import
prices to value the bearing quality steel bar used in the
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 15
production of the subject merchandise at issue. See id. at 61,845.
Commerce pointed out:
[Commerce] recognize[s] that in [Olympia Indus.,
Inc. v. United States (“Olympia 1999”), 23 CIT 80, 36 F.
Supp. 2d 414 (1999)], the Court, in dicta, stated that
Commerce must test the reliability of the trading company
value in order to determine whether it comprises the best
available information for purposes of the FOP
calculation. However, Commerce respectfully disagrees
with the Court’s interpretation of the statute. As
[Commerce] stated in [Commerce’s] . . . Final Results of
Redetermination Pursuant to Court Remand of Olympia
Indus., Inc. v. United States [(“Olympia 1998”), 22 CIT
387, 7 F. Supp. 2d 997 (1998)] . . . , nothing in the
Lasko, [43 F.3d 1442,] decision alters the statutory
mechanism for selection of surrogate values. In Lasko,
the Court [of Appeals for the Federal Circuit (“CAFC”)]
merely recognized that, where the actual cost to the
producer was a market economy price (and paid in a market
economy currency), the actual cost to the producer was
better information than a surrogate value. See Lasko, 43
F.3d at 1446. The selection of surrogate values is
governed by section [1677b(c)(4)] . . . , which, as
discussed above, establishes a preference for values from
a comparable market economy that is a significant
producer of comparable merchandise. Had Congress
intended a preference for using import prices into the
NME as surrogate values, it could easily have stated this
preference.
Id. (emphasis in original).
B. Contentions of the Parties
1. Luoyang’s Contentions
Luoyang contends that Commerce’s decision to value bearing
quality steel bar by using export data from Japan to India was not
supported by substantial evidence and was contrary to law. See
Pl.’s Mem. P. & A. Supp. Rule 56.2 Mot. J. Agency R. (“Luoyang’s
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 16
Mem.”) at 10-15, 17-31; Luoyang’s Reply Br. (“Luoyang’s Reply”) at
2-15. In particular, Luoyang argues that Commerce’s refusal to
review PRC trading company import prices “and to determine whether
that data constituted the best available information for purposes
of the FOP analysis,” Luoyang’s Mem. at 17, was (1) an
“[un]reasonable interpretation of [19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(1)],” id.
at 21 (citing Olympia 1998, 22 CIT at 392, 7 F. Supp. 2d at 1002);
(2) an “utter disregard” of Olympia 1999, 23 CIT 80, 36 F. Supp. 2d
414, Luoyang’s Mem. at 17; and (3) inconsistent with Commerce’s
prior administrative determination in the 10th Annual Review, 63
Fed. Reg. at 63,853-54.4 See Luoyang’s Mem. at 24-27. Luoyang
4
Luoyang points out that in past reviews, “Commerce has
determined that [NV] can most accurately be calculated by first
valuing the factors of production on the basis of prices paid by
the nonmarket economy country to market-economy suppliers
before resorting to surrogate values.” Luoyang’s Mem. at 24
(emphasis in original) (citing Final Determination of Sales at Less
Than Fair Value: Sparklers From the People’s Republic of China, 56
Fed. Reg. 20,588, 20,590 (May 6, 1991); Final Determinations of
Sales at Less Than Fair Value: Oscillating Fans and Ceiling Fans
From the People’s Republic of China (“Oscillating Fans”), 56 Fed.
Reg. 55,271 (Oct. 25, 1991); and Final Results of Antidumping Duty
Administrative Review: Tapered Roller Bearings and Parts Thereof,
Finished and Unfinished, from the Republic of Hungary, 55 Fed. Reg.
21,066, 21,067 (May 22, 1990)).
Moreover, Luoyang asserts that in the 10th Annual Review, 63
Fed. Reg. at 63,853-54, “Commerce addressed the question [of]
whether trading company import prices, as alternate surrogate data,
are preferable to surrogate data from a market-economy country that
is a significant producer and at a level of comparable economic
development.” Luoyang’s Mem. at 25. In that review, Commerce
stated:
(continued...)
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 17
maintains that the PRC trading company import data constitutes the
“best available information” because “‘[t]he cost for raw materials
from a market economy supplier, paid in convertible currencies,
provides Commerce with the closest approximation of the cost of
producing the goods in a market economy country,’” Luoyang’s Mem.
4
(...continued)
“To assess the reliability of the Chinese trading
company’s steel prices, [Commerce] . . . examined the
[following] factors outlined in . . . Olympia [1999, 23
CIT at 82, 36 F. Supp. 2d at 416] . . . : (1) the value
and volume of steel imports, (2) the type and quality of
the imported steel, and (3) consumption of imported steel
by the NME producer.
. . . .
Regarding the value of the steel imported by the trading
company, [Commerce] found that the price paid by the
trading company is within the range of prices created by
the actual steel prices paid by PRC producers and
[Commerce’s] surrogate value. Consequently, the price
paid by the PRC trading company is not aberrational.
With respect to volume and consumption of steel by the
NME producer [Commerce] note[s] that the amount of steel
imported by the trading company was significant and that
the NME producer in question consumed a significant
amount of imported steel to produce the subject
merchandise.
Based on the above, [Commerce is] using the trading
company import steel price as surrogate data for those
companies that actually used the imported steel.”
Id. at 25 (emphasis in original) (quoting 10th Annual Review, 63
Fed. Reg. at 63,854).
Applying Commerce’s three-prong test, Luoyang maintains that
“[t]he PRC trading company prices [in the case at bar] are not
aberrational and satisfy each of the Olympia [1999, 23 CIT 80, 36
F. Supp. 2d 414] criteria.” Luoyang’s Mem. at 26.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 18
at 23 (quoting Lasko Metal Prods., Inc. v. United States (“Lasko
Metal”), 16 CIT 1079, 1081, 810 F. Supp. 314, 317 (1992), aff’d,
Lasko, 43 F.3d 1442), and “‘[t]he same holds true . . . with
respect to the trading company data.’”5 Luoyang’s Mem. at 23
(quoting Olympia 1998, 22 CIT at 392, 7 F. Supp. 2d at 1002).
Responding to Commerce’s argument that Commerce’s “policy [i]s
to evaluate inputs sourced from market-economy suppliers only when
those inputs are actually purchased by the NME [producer], and not
when purchased by NME trading companies,” Luoyang’s Mem. at 19,
Luoyang asserts that: (1) 19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(1) (1998) does not
“limit the use of NME import prices from market economy countries
to those paid by the producer,” Luoyang’s Reply at 4; (2) both
Olympia 1999, 23 CIT at 83, 36 F. Supp. 2d at 417, and Olympia
1998, 22 CIT at 390, 7 F. Supp. 2d at 1001, require Commerce,
pursuant to 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(1), to review PRC trading company
import prices and to determine whether that data constitutes the
best available information for the FOP analysis, see Luoyang’s Mem.
at 20; (3) “Commerce used trading company prices to value factors
of production” in the 10th Annual Review, 63 Fed. Reg. at 63,854,
5
Luoyang further maintains that “[u]se of the PRC trading
company data would lead to the most accurate, fair and predictable
dumping margin calculations because this data shows what Luoyang’s
costs or prices would be if determined by market forces.” Luoyang
Mem. at 24 (citing Olympia 1998, 22 CIT at 392, 7 F. Supp. 2d at
1002).
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 19
Luoyang’s Reply at 4; (4) although the language in “the commentary
accompanying the promulgation of [19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(1)] noted
that the NME buyer should be the ‘producer,’” id., “Commerce’s use
of the phrase ‘normally’” means that Commerce did not choose to
limit its evaluation of inputs sourced from market-economy
suppliers solely to those inputs actually purchased by an NME
producer, id. at 5;6 and (5) 19 U.S.C. §§ 1677b(c)(1) and (c)(4),
the legislative history of these provisions and Lasko, 43 F.3d
1442, do not prohibit the use of trading company import prices to
value steel bar used in the production of TRB cups and cones.
See Luoyang’s Reply at 5-7. Luoyang, therefore, argues that a
remand is necessary so that Commerce, by applying the three-pronged
test approved in Olympia 1999, 23 CIT 80, 36 F. Supp. 2d 414, would
review and assess the reliability of the PRC trading company import
6
In its reply brief, Luoyang cites to the commentary
accompanying the promulgation of 19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(1). See
Luoyang’s Reply at 4 n.1 (citing Final Rule on Antidumping Duties;
Countervailing Duties (“Final Rule”), 62 Fed. Reg. 27,296 (May 19,
1997). The Final Rule provides in pertinent part:
[Commerce] normally will use publicly available
information to value factors. However, where a factor is
purchased from a market economy supplier and paid for in
a market economy currency, [Commerce] normally will use
the price paid to the market economy supplier. In those
instances where a portion of the factor is purchased from
a market economy supplier and the remainder from a
nonmarket economy supplier, [Commerce] normally will
value the factor using the price paid to the market
economy supplier.
62 Fed. Reg. at 27,413; 19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(1).
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 20
prices as a surrogate to value all the bearing quality steel bar
used by Luoyang to manufacture TRB cups and cones and, if Commerce
“finds that the data is not ‘aberrational’ and . . . me[ets] the
requirements of the Olympia [1999] reliability test,” to use the
PRC trading company data to value all of the subject merchandise at
issue. Luoyang’s Mem. at 31. In the alternative, Luoyang asserts
that the PRC trading company data should be used as a surrogate to
value “the steel Luoyang purchased through the trading company and
actually used in the manufacture of those subject cups and cones.”
Id.
Next, Luoyang argues that Commerce erred in selecting export
data from Japan to India under HTS category 7228.30.900 to value
the subject merchandise at issue because that data is not an
appropriate surrogate. See id. at 27-29; accord Luoyang’s Reply at
8-12. In particular, Luoyang maintains that: (1) “the surrogate
values based on . . . [export data from Japan] to India represent
values for steel in category 7228.30.900 which could include the
type of steel used to produce the cups and cones, but which in fact
also may not include the type of steel used,” Luoyang’s Mem. at 27
(emphasis in original) (citing Final Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at
61,840); and (2) the export data from Japan to India fell outside
the United States benchmark range of $642 per MT to $834 per MT.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 21
See Luoyang’s Reply at 8-9.7 Responding to Commerce’s statement
that “Commerce’s regulations give preference to the use of one
surrogate country” to value all factors of production, Luoyang
argues that there is no such restriction.8 Id. at 9; see also
Luoyang’s Reply at 10-11 (citing 10th Annual Review, 63 Fed. Reg.
at 63,846; Final Results of Antidumping Administrative Review of
Tapered Roller Bearings and Parts Thereof, Finished and Unfinished,
7
In its reply brief, Luoyang points out that “for only three
months did the monthly Japanese export prices to India fall within
the [United States benchmark] range.” Luoyang’s Reply at 9 (citing
id., Pub. Doc. 141 at Att. 1). “For the other nine (9) months the
prices were either below (Apr-98 at $561 [per MT]) or above (the
other 8 months).” Luoyang’s Reply at 9. Additionally, Luoyang
asserts that
[t]he range of values for [export data from Japan] to
India in HTS category 7228.30.900 was $561 per metric ton
to $1,414 per metric ton and the average value was $871
per metric ton. . . . The average value of $871 per
metric ton is not between [the United States benchmark
range of] $642 per metric ton and $834 per metric ton.
Id. at 8-9 (emphasis in original) (citing Def.’s Mem. Opp’n Luoyang
at 9).
8
The Court shall not entertain Commerce’s statement since the
Court is not aware of any particular preference which trumps the
general requirement for precision that underlines the antidumping
law. See Timken 2001, 25 CIT at __, 166 F. Supp. 2d at 621
(stating that “[t]he statute permits Commerce to draw surrogate
value information from more than one market economy country,”
citing 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(1); and quoting Chemical Prods. Corp.
v. United States, 10 CIT 700, 706, 650 F. Supp. 178, 182
(1986)(which provides that “‘[t]he regulation [relied upon by
Commerce] is silent concerning whether Commerce may use data from
a country other than its designated surrogate when Commerce finds
that a comparison of one element of foreign market value in the
surrogate would yield an unrealistic result.’”)
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 22
From the People’s Republic of China, 62 Fed. Reg. 61,276, 61,282
(Nov. 17, 1997); and Timken Co. v. United States, 82 F. Supp. 2d
1371 (CIT 1999) [sic].9) Luoyang, therefore, asserts that if PRC
trading company import prices are not used as a surrogate, Commerce
should use export data from Japan to Indonesia over export data
from Japan to India as a surrogate to value the subject merchandise
at issue. See Luoyang’s Mem. at 32. Alternatively, Luoyang
contends that if the Court sustains Commerce’s use of export data
from Japan to India as a surrogate to value the subject merchandise
at issue, the values for January 1998 and March 1998 should be
excluded because they are aberrational. See id.
2. Commerce’s Contentions
Commerce responds that its decision to use export data from
Japan to India to value bearing quality steel bar used by Luoyang
to manufacture TRB cups and cones is supported by substantial
evidence and otherwise in accordance with law. See Def.’s Mem.
Opp’n Luoyang at 15-28. Specifically, Commerce maintains that its
selection of the export data from Japan to India as the “best
available” surrogate value should be sustained because that data
represents “‘a category which would include the type of bearing
9
The Court assumes that the correct citation is Timken Co.
v. United States (“Timken 1999”), 23 CIT 509, 59 F. Supp. 2d 1371
(1999).
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 23
quality steel bar [used in the production of the subject
merchandise]’; and . . . ‘these Japanese export prices to India
fall within the range of the values in the [United States
benchmark].’” Def.’s Mem. Opp’n Luoyang at 18 (quoting Final
Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at 61,840). Responding to Luoyang’s argument
that “Commerce’s selection of [export data from Japan to India] is
erroneous because it ‘only theoretically includes bearing steel
prices,’” Commerce maintains that Luoyang’s argument is merely a
crafty restatement of “Commerce’s own statement” aiming to distort
the gist of Commerce’s conclusion.10 Def.’s Mem. Opp’n Luoyang at
18. With respect to Luoyang’s argument that the export data from
Japan to India is not a reliable surrogate, Commerce points out
that “‘[t]he court’s role is not to determine whether the
information chosen by Commerce is the ‘best’ actually available,
but whether the choice is supported by substantial evidence and is
in accordance with law.’” Id. at 19 (quoting Novachem, Inc. v.
United States, 16 CIT 782, 786, 797 F. Supp. 1033, 1037 (1992)).11
10
The Court agrees with Commerce and is not persuaded by
Luoyang’s assertion since Luoyang fails to use evidence on the
record to illustrate that export data from Japan to India does not
include the type of steel used to produce the TRB cups and cones at
issue.
11
Commerce contends that Luoyang “does not challenge
Commerce’s conclusion that the average [export data from Japan to
India] falls within the [United States] benchmark range.” Def.’s
Mem. Opp’n Luoyang at 19. Moreover, Commerce asserts that “by
suggesting the adoption of its own benchmark methodology while
(continued...)
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 24
Additionally, Commerce argues that its decision to reject the
PRC trading company data as an alternative for valuing the bearing
quality steel bar used in the production of the subject merchandise
at issue was in accordance with law. See Def.’s Mem. Opp’n Luoyang
at 20-28. Relying on Lasko, 43 F.3d 1442, and 19 C.F.R. §
351.408(c)(1), Commerce asserts that the transaction involving the
PRC trading company’s purchase of the steel bar at issue from a
market-economy country does not “qualif[y] as a market economy
purchase.” Id. at 22. In particular, Commerce maintains that: (1)
“the commentary accompanying the promulgation of [19 C.F.R. §
351.408(c)(1)] makes clear that Commerce intended to use a market
economy price to value a factor of production only when the PRC
producer itself made the purchase,” id. (citing Final Rule, 62 Fed.
11
(...continued)
failing to find error with the methodology actually used by
Commerce, Luoyang is merely challenging the correctness of
Commerce’s result.” Id. at 20.
The Court disagrees with Commerce. Although Luoyang initially
stated in its brief that “the average figure [that is, the average
value of export data from Japan to India] is within the range of
the [United States] benchmark range,” Luoyang’s Mem. at 28, in its
reply brief Luoyang argues that
[t]he range of values for [export data from Japan] to
India in HTS category 7228.30.900 was $561 per metric ton
to $1,414 per metric ton and the average value was $871
per metric ton. . . . The average value of $871 per
metric ton is not between [the United States benchmark
range of] $642 per metric ton and $834 per metric ton.
Luoyang’s Reply at 8-9 (emphasis in original) (citing Def.’s Mem.
Opp’n Luoyang at 9).
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 25
Reg. at 27,366); and (2) “the use of the price paid by Luoyang to
the trading company in question would be contrary to congressional
intent because that [NME] transaction is not reliable.” Def.’s
Mem. Opp’n Luoyang at 24 (citing S. Rep. No. 93-1298 (1974),
reprinted in 1974 U.S.C.C.A.N. 7186, 7311).
Contrary to Luoyang’s argument that both Olympia 1999, 23 CIT
at 83, 36 F. Supp. 2d at 417, and Olympia 1998, 22 CIT 387, 7 F.
Supp. 2d 997, require Commerce to review PRC trading company import
prices and to determine whether that data constitutes the best
available information for the FOP analysis pursuant to 19 U.S.C. §
1677b(c)(1), Commerce maintains that it disagrees with those
decisions and that Lasko, 43 F.3d at 1446, “‘merely recognized
that, where the actual cost to the producer was a market economy
price (and paid in a market economy currency), the actual cost to
the producer was better information than a surrogate value.’”
Def.’s Mem. Opp’n Luoyang at 25 (quoting Final Results, 64 Fed.
Reg. at 61,845, emphasis in original). Commerce further maintains
that it properly rejected PRC trading company import prices from
its FOP analysis because “[t]his ‘actual cost’ does not exist in
the trading company situation because the price paid by the trading
company to the market economy supplier does not reflect the price
paid by the PRC producer to the trading company.” Def.’s Mem.
Opp’n Luoyang at 25.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 26
Commerce concedes that during its prior determination (that
is, 10th Annual Review, 63 Fed. Reg. at 63,854), it adhered to
Olympia 1999, 23 CIT at 83, 36 F. Supp. 2d at 417, and Olympia
1998, 22 CIT 387, 7 F. Supp. 2d 997, by reviewing PRC trading
company import prices and determining whether that data constituted
the best available information for purposes of the FOP analysis,
see id. at 27. However, Commerce maintains that
[h]aving reconsidered the meaning of Lasko, [43 F.3d
1442,] and the statute’s NME provisions, Commerce now
views Lasko, [43 F.3d 1442] as limited to the situation
involving the actual cost to the producer (not the price
paid by the trading company). Commerce further views the
statute itself as expressing a preference for the use of
values from a comparable market economy that is a
significant producer of comparable merchandise.
th
Moreover, in [10 Annual Review, 63 Fed. Reg. 63,842],
Commerce conducted its review applying its prior
regulations. . . . The current regulations do not
permit the result advocated by Luoyang.
Id. at 27-28.
3. Timken’s Contentions
Timken generally agrees with Commerce and maintains that
Commerce’s decision to use export data from Japan to India to value
the bearing quality steel bar used by Luoyang in the production of
TRB cups and cones over PRC trading company import prices was
supported by substantial evidence and was in accordance with law.
See Timken’s Resp. Opp’n Pl.’s Mot. J. Agency R. (“Timken’s Resp.”)
at 8-33. In particular, Timken argues that by selecting export
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 27
data from Japan to India to value the subject merchandise at issue,
Commerce “followed the statutory scheme [under 19 U.S.C. §
1677b(c)(4) and 19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(1)], since [Commerce]
clearly used, ‘to the extent possible,’ the ‘best available
information’ as judged by the surrogate selection.”12 Timken’s
Resp. at 9. Moreover, Timken asserts that the Court should sustain
Commerce’s selection of export data from Japan to India as the
“best available information” to value the subject merchandise at
issue because: (1) unlike export data from Japan to India which
meets the statutory preference of 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(4) since it
constitutes a “surrogate value[] from a comparable market economy
that is a significant producer of comparable merchandise[,] . . .
there is no statutory preference, mandatory or otherwise, for the
use of PRC trading company import prices,” id. at 10; (2) export
12
In its response brief Timken points out that
[a]pplying . . . § 1677b(c)(4)[’s preference] in this
case, [Commerce] found that the use of values from its
primary-surrogate-country India was possible. [Commerce]
was, therefore, not required to assess the pros and cons
of using PRC trading company import prices.
Timken’s Resp. at 21; see also id. at 28-29.
Moreover, contrary to Luoyang’s argument that Commerce should
have used export data from Japan to Indonesia over export data from
Japan to India, Timken contends that export data from Japan to
India is the “best available information” to value the subject
merchandise at issue because: (1) “Indonesia has only two bearings
producers and neither produces [TRBs]” whereas “India’s bearing
industry has at least 17 producers and 7 producers of [TRBs].” Id.
at 30.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 28
data from Japan to India is “consistent with the objectives of §
1677b(c)(4) which favor the use of publicly available sources of
information to value factors of production,” id. at 11, whereas
“Luoyang’s PRC trading company import prices are not broad,
publicly-available information from a comparably reliable,
verifiable, and reusable source,” id. at 12; (3) Luoyang has failed
to assert that it purchased the subject merchandise at issue from
the PRC trading company in a convertible currency, see id.; and (4)
Commerce’s selection of export data from Japan to India to value
the bearing quality steel bar used by Luoyang to manufacture TRB
cups and cones was consistent with “[t]he purpose of the
antidumping statute[s] [that is, 19 U.S.C. §§ 1677b(c)(1) and (4)]
. . . to calculate dumping margins as accurately as possible.” Id.
(citing Lasko, 43 F.3d at 1446).
Additionally, Timken maintains that Luoyang’s reliance on
Lasko, 43 F.3d 1442, Olympia 1999, 23 CIT 80, 36 F. Supp. 2d 414,
Olympia 1998, 22 CIT 387, 7 F. Supp. 2d 997, and Olympia Indus.,
Inc. v. United States (“Olympia 1997”), 21 CIT 364 (1997), is
misplaced. See Timken’s Resp. at 14-26. First, referring to
Lasko, 43 F.3d at 1446, and Olympia 1998, 22 CIT at 390-91, 7 F.
Supp. 2d at 1001, Timken asserts that the PRC trading company
import prices are not actual prices but are merely surrogate
values. See Timken’s Resp. at 14 n.5. Second, Timken argues that
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 29
the CAFC in Lasko, 43 F.3d at 1446, addressed “‘whether or not . .
. [Commerce was] permit[ted] to determine the factors of production
using both surrogate country values and actual cost values,’”
id. at 14-15 (quoting Lasko, 43 F.3d at 1445), and did not address
the issue of the proper interpretation of 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(4)
or the use of Chinese trading company purchases as surrogates. See
id. at 15. Third, Timken contends that the Olympia cases (that is,
Olympia 1999, 23 CIT 80, 36 F. Supp. 2d 414, Olympia 1998, 22 CIT
387, 7 F. Supp. 2d 997, and Olympia 1997, 21 CIT 364) were “decided
on [the] facts [of those cases] and did not address the proper
interpretation of 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(4).” Id. at 15-20. Fourth,
Timken maintains that since the Court in Olympia 1999, 23 CIT 80,
36 F. Supp. 2d 414, took an “additional step of disapproving
[Commerce’s] interpretation of 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(4)” by stating
that Commerce must test the reliability of the trading company
value in order to determine whether it comprises the best available
information for purposes of the FOP calculation, this additional
step was merely dicta and “this Court remains free to sustain”
Commerce. Id. at 19-20. Finally, Timken asserts that Commerce is
not required to apply the three-pronged test approved in Olympia
1999, 23 CIT 80, 36 F. Supp. 2d 414, to review and assess the
reliability of the PRC trading company import prices because: (1)
“[t]here is no three-part . . . test in the statute or regulations
compelling a specific methodology to be used in selecting surrogate
values,” id. at 23 (citing Lasko, 43 F.3d at 1446); and (2)
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 30
Commerce, despite Commerce’s application of the three-pronged test
in the 10th Annual Review, 63 Fed. Reg. 63,842, “provided a
reasonable explanation . . . for rejecting PRC trading company
import prices.” Timken’s Resp. at 24.
In the alternative, Timken argues that, if the Court remands
to Commerce to review and assess the reliability of the PRC trading
company import prices, Commerce should consider whether there was:
(1) “a significant difference between the resale price and the PRC
trading company import prices and whether that difference was
sufficient to cover the trading company’s costs”; (2) “any
countertrade or other arrangements between the trading company and
its market-economy supplier”; (3) “any commissions or other
consideration paid by the purchaser or supplier to the trading
company, or lack thereof”; and (4) “any affiliation between the
trading company, the market-economy supplier and/or the Chinese
manufacturer.” Id. at 25. Moreover, Timken maintains that “[i]f
the Court requires use of Luoyang’s PRC trading company import
prices, those prices should not be extended to value other
purchases of steel.” Id. at 26.
Next, contrary to Luoyang’s argument that certain values of
export data from Japan to India should be excluded because they are
aberrational (that is, values for January 1998 and March 1998),
Timken asserts that: (1) “the mere fact that some months were high
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 31
is not a basis for exclusion,” id. at 31; (2) “in any average, some
values exceed the norm, while other values are below, id. at 32;
and (3) “Luoyang cannot ‘pick and choose’ and conveniently
eliminate only high values.” Id.
C. Analysis
1. Commerce’s Changes of Policy or Methodology
Agency statements provide guidance to regulated industries.
While “‘an agency does not act rationally when it chooses and
implements one policy and decides to consider the merits of a
potentially inconsistent policy in the very near future,’”
Transcom, Inc. v. United States, 24 CIT ___, ___, 123 F. Supp. 2d
1372, 1381 (2000) (quoting ITT World Communications, Inc. v. FCC,
725 F.2d 732, 754 (D.C. Cir. 1984)), Commerce, in view of the
rapidly-changing world of global trade and Commerce’s limited
resources, should be able to rely on its “unique expertise and
policy-making prerogatives.” Southern Cal. Edison Co. v. United
States, 226 F.3d 1349, 1357 (Fed. Cir. 2000). “‘The power of an
administrative agency to administer a congressionally created . .
. program necessarily requires the formulation of policy . . . .’”
Chevron, 467 U.S. at 843 (quoting Morton v. Ruiz, 415 U.S. 199, 231
(1974)).
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 32
An agency decision involving the meaning or reach of a statute
that reconciles conflicting policies “‘represents a reasonable
accommodation of conflicting policies that were committed to the
agency’s care by the statute, [and a reviewing court] should not
disturb [the agency decision] unless it appears from the statute or
its legislative history that the accommodation is not one that
Congress would have sanctioned.’” Chevron, 467 U.S. at 845
(quoting United States v. Shimer, 367 U.S. 374, 382-83 (1961)).
Furthermore, an agency must be allowed to assess the wisdom of its
policy on a continuing basis. Under the Chevron regime, agency
discretion to reconsider policies is inalienable. See Chevron, 467
U.S. at 843. Any assumption that Congress intended to freeze an
administrative interpretation of a statute would be entirely
contrary to the concept of Chevron which assumes and approves the
ability of administrative agencies to change their interpretations.
See, e.g., Maier, P.E. v. United States EPA, 114 F.3d 1032, 1043
(10th Cir. 1997), J.L. v. Social Sec. Admin., 971 F.2d 260, 265 (9th
Cir. 1992), Saco Defense Sys. Div., Maremont Corp. v. Weinberger,
606 F. Supp. 446, 450-51 (D. Me. 1985). In sum, underlying agency
interpretative policies “are given controlling weight unless they
are arbitrary, capricious, or manifestly contrary to the statute.”
Chevron, 467 U.S. at 844.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 33
Moreover, “‘[a]n [agency] announcement stating a change in the
method . . . is not a general statement of policy.’” American
Trucking Ass’ns, Inc. v. ICC, 659 F.2d 452, 464 n.49 (5th Cir. 1981)
(quoting Brown Express, Inc. v. United States, 607 F.2d 695, 701
(5th Cir. 1979) (internal quotations omitted)). While a policy
“denotes . . . [the] general purpose . . . [of the statute]
considered as directed to the welfare or prosperity of the state,”
BLACK’S LAW DICTIONARY 1157 (6th ed. 1990), methodology refers only to
the “performing [of] several operations[] in the most convenient
order,” id. at 991; accord Avoyelles Sportsmen’s League, Inc. v.
Marsh, 715 F.2d 897 (5th Cir. 1983); Interstate Natural Gas Ass’n
of Am. v. Federal Energy Regulatory Comm’n, 716 F.2d 1 (D.C. Cir.
1983); Hooker Chems. & Plastics Corp. v. Train, 537 F.2d 620 (2d
Cir. 1976). Consequently, the courts are even less in the position
to question an agency action if the action at issue is a choice of
methodology, rather than policy. See, e.g., Maier, P.E., 114 F.3d
at 1043 (citing Professional Drivers Council v. Bureau of Motor
Carrier Safety, 706 F.2d 1216, 1221 (D.C. Cir. 1983)). Similarly,
an agency decision to change its methodology, that is, to take an
act of statutory implementation while pursuing the same policy,
should be examined under the Chevron test and sustained if the new
methodology is reasonable. See, e.g., Koyo Seiko Co., v. United
States, 24 CIT ___, ___, 110 F. Supp. 2d 934, 942 (2000) (stating
that “‘the use of different methods [of] calculati[on] . . . does
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 34
not [mean there is a] conflict with the statute,’”) (quoting
Torrington Co. v. United States, 44 F.3d 1572, 1578 (Fed. Cir.
1995)).
Therefore, Commerce’s refusal to review and use PRC trading
company import data and Commerce’s consequential use of export data
from Japan to India as a surrogate value for bearing quality steel
bar used by Luoyang to manufacture TRB cups and cones was a
justifiable change of methodology as long as such change in
position was reasonably supported by the record.
2. Commerce’s Determination at Bar
The CAFC has reasoned that “the purpose of the statutory
provisions [that is, 19 U.S.C. §§ 1677b(c)(1) and (4)] is to
determine antidumping margins ‘as accurately as possible.’”
Shakeproof Assembly Components, Div. of Illinois Tool Works, Inc.
v. United States, 268 F.3d 1376, 1382 (Fed. Cir. 2001) (quoting
Lasko, 43 F.3d at 1446); see also Olympia 1998, 22 CIT at 390, 7 F.
Supp. 2d at 1000-01 (noting that “accuracy is the touchstone of the
antidumping statute” and citing Rhone Poulenc, Inc. v United
States, 899 F.2d 1185, 1191 (Fed. Cir. 1990)). Additionally,
Commerce’s “task in [an NME] investigation is to calculate what .
. . [the] costs or prices would be [in the NME] if such prices or
costs were determined by market forces.” Tianjin, 16 CIT at 940,
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 35
806 F. Supp. at 1018.
a. Commerce’s Refusal to Review and
Use PRC Trading Company Import Prices
The Court finds that Commerce’s refusal to review PRC trading
company import prices and to determine whether that data
constituted the best available information for purposes of the FOP
analysis was unreasonable. Specifically, the Court disagrees with
Commerce’s and Timken’s narrow reading of Lasko, 43 F.3d 1442, and
19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(1).13 The Court in Lasko Metal, 16 CIT at
1081, 810 F. Supp. at 317, reasoned that “[t]he cost for raw
materials from a market economy supplier, paid in convertible
currencies, provides Commerce with the closest approximation of the
cost of producing the goods in a market economy country.”
Additionally, the CAFC observed:
“[w]here [it] can [be] determine[d] that a [non-market
economy] producer’s input prices are market determined,
accuracy, fairness, and predictability are enhanced by
using those prices. Therefore, using surrogate values
when market-based values are available would, in fact, be
contrary to the intent of the law.”
Shakeproof, 268 F.3d at 1382 (emphasis in original) (quoting Lasko,
13
The Court also disagrees with Timken that Commerce was not
required to assess the PRC trading company data since Commerce,
applied 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(4)’s preference by valuing the subject
merchandise using values from its primary surrogate (that is,
India). The Court finds that there is no requirement that Commerce
value FOPs pursuant to 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(4) prior to resorting
to a PRC trading company’s import prices paid to a market-economy
supplier to value material costs for certain steel inputs.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 36
43 F.3d at 1446); accord Oscillating Fans, 56 Fed. Reg. at 55,275;
see also Olympia 1998, 22 CIT at 392, 7 F. Supp. 2d at 1002
(stating that the “same holds true here with respect to the trading
company data”); Timken Co. v. United States, 26 CIT __, __, 201 F.
Supp. 2d 1316, 1335 (2002)(finding that “Commerce’s decision to use
[a] PRC trading company’s import steel price as surrogate data for
[certain PRC producers] is reasonable, is in accordance with law
and is in accord with the purpose of the statutory provisions [that
is, §§ 1677b(c)(1) and (c)(4)] to determine antidumping margins as
accurately as possible”).
Next, observing that 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(1) does not specify
what constitutes “best available information,” the Court concludes
that “‘[t]he statute[,] [therefore,] does not require Commerce to
follow any single approach in evaluating data.’” Timken 1999, 23
CIT at 515, 59 F. Supp. 2d at 1376 (quoting Olympia 1997, 21 CIT at
368, and citing Lasko, 43 F.3d at 1446); see also Shakeproof
Assembly Components, Div. of Illinois Tool Works, Inc. v. United
States, 23 CIT 479, 481, 59 F. Supp. 2d 1354, 1357 (1999), aff’d,
Shakeproof, 268 F.3d 1376 (stating that the “statute requires
Commerce to use the best available information, but does not define
that term” and quoting Olympia 1998, 22 CIT at 389, 7 F. Supp. 2d
at 1000, that “‘[t]he relevant statute does not clearly delineate
how Commerce should determine what constitutes’” the best available
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 37
information). While the Court finds that Commerce is not required
to apply the three-pronged test approved in Olympia 1999, 23 CIT
80, 36 F. Supp. 2d 414, to review and assess the reliability of the
PRC trading company import prices, the Court remands this issue to
Commerce with instructions to examine whether or not the PRC
trading company import prices constitute the “best available
information” to value either all of the subject merchandise at
issue or a portion of the subject merchandise purchased by Luoyang
through the trading company and used by Luoyang in the manufacture
of TRB cups and cones and, if Commerce concludes that the PRC
trading company import prices present the “best available
information” for the purpose of such surrogate evaluation, to
recalculate Commerce’s determination not inconsistent with this
opinion.
b. Commerce’s Decision to Value Bearing
Quality Steel Bar by Using Export Data
from Japan to India
The Court disagrees with Commerce and Timken that Luoyang is
assailing not the reasoning but rather the correctness of
Commerce’s result, which is outside the Court’s standard of review.
See Writing Instrument Mfrs. Ass’n, Pencil Section v. United
States, 21 CIT 1185, 1195, 984 F. Supp. 629, 639 (1997). During
the review at issue, Commerce observed:
In comparing [export data from Japan to India] to the
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 38
range of values contained in the [United States]
benchmark [that is, the value of steel imported into the
United States during the POR under HTS category
7228.30.20 which ranged from $642 per MT to $834 per MT],
[Commerce] found that these Japanese export prices to
India fall within the range of the values in the [United
States] category.
Final Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at 61,840.
Nevertheless, as Luoyang points out:
The range of values for [export data from Japan] to India
in HTS category 7228.30.900 was $561 per metric ton to
$1,414 per metric ton and the average value was $871 per
metric ton. . . . The average value of $871 per
metric ton is not between [the United States benchmark
range of] $642 per metric ton and $834 per metric ton.
Luoyang’s Reply at 8-9 (emphasis in original) (citing Def.’s Mem.
Opp’n Luoyang at 9).
However, the Court disagrees with Luoyang that the Court
should order that Commerce exclude the values for January 1998 and
March 1998 from the export data from Japan to India. Luoyang may
not usurp Commerce’s role as fact-finder and substitute Luoyang’s
analysis for the result reached by Commerce.
Next, with respect to Luoyang’s argument that Commerce should
have used export data from Japan to Indonesia over export data from
Japan to India as a surrogate to value the subject merchandise at
issue, the Court notes that Commerce admittedly failed to review
export data from Japan to Indonesia as a surrogate value. See
Final Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at 61,840 (Commerce “ha[s] not analyzed
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 39
data from [Commerce’s] secondary surrogate, Indonesia, to find a
value for steel used to produce cups and cones”). The Court finds
that Commerce’s reasoning for refusing to review the export data
from Japan to Indonesia as a surrogate value was not sufficiently
explained. To the contrary, it was illogical for Commerce to
utilize export data from Japan to India and then to subsequently
fail to review analogously structured export data from Japan to
Indonesia.
Based on the foregoing, the Court remands this issue to
Commerce to examine if, and only if, Commerce finds that the PRC
trading company import prices do not constitute the “best available
information,” whether or not Indonesian data (that is, Indonesian
import statistics and export data from Japan to Indonesia)
constitute the “best available information” over export data from
Japan to India to value the bearing quality steel bar used in the
production of TRB cups and cones, and to explain, (if Commerce
finds that export data from Japan to India is the “best available
information,”) how the entire export data from Japan to India falls
within the range of values in the United States category benchmark
range.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 40
II. Commerce’s Inclusion of “Consumption of Traded Goods”
in Indian Bearings Producers’ Direct Input Costs
A. Background
In the Final Results, Commerce designated the line item
“consumption of traded goods” in certain Indian bearings producers’
1997-98 annual reports as material costs to be included in direct
input costs that were used as the denominator of the overhead,
SG&A, and profit rate calculations. See 64 Fed. Reg. at 61,844;
see also Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken’s Mot. J. Agency R.
(“Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken), App. Ex. 5 at 3-4.
Specifically, Commerce explained that
[Commerce] disagree[s] that [Commerce] should exclude
“Consumption of Traded Goods” from the direct input costs
calculated for the Indian bearings producers. Although
the CIT did instruct [Commerce] to exclude the purchases
of traded goods from the cost of manufacture with respect
to the 1994-95 administrative review of TRBs in Timken v.
U.S., [23 CIT 509, 59 F. Supp. 2d 1371], that ruling is
not yet final. Thus, [Commerce is] not compelled to
apply the court-directed methodology in these reviews.
[Commerce] further note[s] that [Commerce] excluded
“Consumption of Traded Goods” from [Commerce’s] direct
input costs calculation in the preliminary results of the
new shipper review. Again, because Timken v. U.S., [23
CIT 509, 59 F. Supp. 2d 1371] is not yet final,
[Commerce] ha[s] revised [Commerce’s] preliminary
calculations to include the traded goods amount in direct
input costs.
Final Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at 61,844.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 41
B. Contentions of the Parties
Timken asserts that the “consumption of traded goods” should
be excluded from the direct input costs denominator used in the
overhead, SG&A and profit rate calculations. See Mem. P&A Supp.
Timken’s Mot. J. Agency R. (“Timken’s Mem.”) at 2, 22-23. Relying
on Timken 1999, 23 CIT at 518-19, 59 F. Supp. 2d at 1378-79, Timken
maintains that this Court: (1) “rejected [Commerce’s] inclusion of
the line item for ‘traded goods’ in material costs used to
calculate overhead, SG&A and profit ratios in its review of the
1994-95 period,” id. at 22; and (2) “agreed that [Commerce] had
failed to demonstrate how these already manufactured goods
constitute a material cost incurred in manufacturing the subject
merchandise.” Id. (internal quotations omitted). Moreover,
contrary to Commerce’s argument that this Court’s decision in
Timken 1999, 23 CIT 509, 59 F. Supp. 2d 1371, is not yet final,
Timken points out that “this Court’s decision in Timken [1999], did
become final and was not appealed.” Id. (citing Timken Co. v.
United States, 2000 Ct. Intl. Trade LEXIS 12, *1, Slip. Op. 00-13
(Feb. 8, 2000)). Timken, therefore, argues that this case should
be remanded to Commerce with instructions that Commerce exclude
“consumption of traded goods from the cost of materials used in the
denominator of the overhead, SG&A, and profit ratios” and
recalculate the dumping margins accordingly. Timken’s Mem. at 23.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 42
Commerce agrees that a remand is necessary to exclude the
“consumption of traded goods” from Commerce’s overhead, SG&A and
profit rate calculations since “consumption of traded goods
utilized by Commerce in the Final Results, [64 Fed. Reg. at
61,844,] are similar in nature to the ‘purchases of traded goods’
reviewed by the Court in Timken [1999].” Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n
Timken at 21.
C. Analysis
In Timken 1999, 23 CIT 509, 59 F. Supp. 2d 1371, this Court
determined that “Commerce failed to demonstrate how these already
manufactured goods [that is, purchases of traded goods] constitute
a material cost incurred in manufacturing the subject merchandise.”
Id., 23 CIT at 519, 59 F. Supp. 2d at 1379.
Because Commerce’s inclusion of the “consumption of traded
goods” in Commerce’s overhead, SG&A and profit rate calculations,
and the parties’ arguments are practically identical to those
presented in Timken 1999, 23 CIT 509, 59 F. Supp. 2d 1371, the
Court adheres to its reasoning in Timken 1999, and remands this
issue with instructions that Commerce exclude “consumption of
traded goods” from Commerce’s overhead, SG&A and profit rate
calculations and to recalculate the dumping margins accordingly.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 43
III. Commerce’s Use of Wage Rates from Chapter 5
of the International Labor Office’s 1998
Yearbook of Labor Statistics to Value Labor
A. Background
During the POR, Commerce, pursuant to 19 C.F.R. §
351.408(c)(3) (1998), used a regression-based wage rate to value
labor costs. See Preliminary Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at 36,856.
Commerce explained that
[b]ecause of the variability of wage rates in countries
with similar levels of per capita Gross Domestic Product
(GDP), section 351.408(c)(3) of [Commerce’s] regulations
(19 CFR Part 351, April 1998) requires the use of a
regression-based wage rate. Therefore, to value the
labor input, [Commerce] used the PRC regression-based
wage rate published by Import Administration on its
website, which was last revised on May 1999. The source
of the wage rate data on the Import Administration’s
website is the 1998 Yearbook of Labour Statistics,
published by the International Labour Office (ILO) . . .
Chapter 5: Wages in Manufacturing.
Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken, App. Ex. 3 at 4.
In the Final Results, Commerce valued the PRC labor costs by
utilizing the wage rates reported in Chapter 5 of the 1998 Yearbook
instead of the labor costs reported in Chapter 6A of the 1998
Yearbook as proposed by Timken.14 Commerce determined that
14
Commerce and Timken point out that the differences between
Chapter 5 and Chapter 6A of the 1998 Yearbook are:
Chapter 6A of the 1998 Yearbook of Labour Statistics [is]
a category of “labour costs” that includes the
compensation of employees as well as additional costs
borne by the employer such as vocational training,
(continued...)
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 44
[Commerce’s] regulations at section 351.408(c)(3) state
that “[Commerce] will use regression-based wage rates
reflective of the observed relationship between wages and
national income in market economy countries.” Therefore,
to value the labor inputs[,] . . . [Commerce] applied the
PRC regression-based wage rate published by the Import
Administration on its website, which was last revised in
May 1999.
With respect to [Timken’s] argument, [Commerce]
disagree[s]. The [1998 Yearbook] states that the wage
rates, used to calculate the regression analysis are
comprehensive wage rates which also includes overtime,
bonuses, holiday pay, incentive pay, pay for piecework,
and cost-of-living allowances. See Magnesium from the
People’s Republic of China, Final Results of Antidumping
Duty New Shipper Administrative Review, 63 Fed. Reg.
3085, 3091 (Jan. 21, 1998). Thus, for purposes of these
final results, [Commerce] ha[s] not adjusted the
regression-based wage rate used in the preliminary
results.
Final Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at 61,842.
B. Contentions of the Parties
Timken contends that Commerce’s decision to value PRC labor
costs by using the wage rates in Chapter 5 of the 1998 Yearbook
rather than the labor costs in Chapter 6A of the 1998 Yearbook was
14
(...continued)
welfare services, the cost of workers’ housing, the cost
of educational facilities, grants to credit unions, the
cost of recruitment, and taxes. . . . [Whereas,] Chapter
5 of the 1998 Yearbook of Labour Statistics [is] a
category of “wage rates” that reflects cash payments
received from employers, including overtime, bonuses,
holiday pay, incentive pay, pay for piecework, and cost-
of-living allowances.
Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken at 26 (citing Timken’s Mem. at
11).
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 45
not supported by substantial evidence and was contrary to law. See
Timken’s Mem. at 23-25. In particular, Timken argues that: (1)
Commerce’s use of Chapter 5 wage rates was a departure from
Commerce’s consistent practice of “interpret[ing] [19 U.S.C. §§
1677b(c)(1) and (3)] . . . as calling for the use of fully-loaded
costs, including all the costs and benefits in addition to basic
wage, of employing labor,” Timken’s Mem. at 23 (citing 10Th Annual
Review, 63 Fed. Reg. at 63,848, and Final Results and Partial
Recission of Antidumping Duty Administrative Review of Maganese
Metal From the People’s Republic of China, 63 Fed. Reg. 12,440,
12,446 (March 13, 1998)); see also, Reply Br. Timken Co. (“Timken
Reply”) at 2-4; (2) “the record is devoid of evidence that Chapter
5 wage rates [of the 1998 Yearbook] are comprehensive,” Timken’s
Mem. at 24, because “[f]or example, the wage rates in Chapter 5 did
not include additional costs for employers’ social security
expenditures or welfare services . . . [and these] costs [are not]
captured anywhere else in [Commerce’s] calculation,” Timken’s Reply
at 6-7; and (3) “[a] broad reading of ‘wage rates’ in §
351.408(c)(3), which calls for use of fully-loaded labor costs when
available, would save the regulation from running afoul of the
statutory scheme.” Timken’s Reply at 9 (emphasis omitted).
Timken, therefore, asserts that a remand is necessary so that
Commerce can value PRC labor costs using Chapter 6A of the 1998
Yearbook or, in the alternative, “explain why [Commerce’s]
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 46
departure from established practice was lawful in the face of the
statute and statutory scheme.” Timken’s Reply at 8; see
also Timken’s Mem. at 25. In the alternative, Timken argues that,
if the Court sustains Commerce’s use of Chapter 5 wage rates, the
Court should “require [Commerce] to account for all labor costs not
included in Chapter 5 wage rates elsewhere in [Commerce’s]
calculation.” Timken’s Reply at 9.
Additionally, Timken maintains that Commerce’s “labor cost
methodology should be the same for calculating constructed value
and factors of production.” Id. at 5; see also id. at 9 (stating
that “the statutory scheme calls for costs included in constructed
value and factors of production to be the same”).15 Responding to
Commerce’s argument that 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(1), 19 U.S.C. §
1677b(c)(3), and 19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(3) do not require Commerce
to use comprehensive costs in valuing labor, Timken maintains that
this argument “must be rejected as a post hoc rationalization
15
The Court disagrees with Timken’s argument that Commerce’s
labor cost methodology should be the same for calculating
constructed value and factors of production. Unless Commerce
interprets the very same terms differently for the purpose of
interrelated statutes during the same review, Commerce could
utilize the interpretations that Commerce could reasonably derive
from the gists of the respective statutes. The Court can envision
a distinction between 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(a) and 19 U.S.C. §
1677b(c)(1). Moreover, with respect to Timken’s argument that
“Generally Accepted Accounting Principles [“GAAP”]. . . call for
the use of fully absorbed costs of producing the subject
merchandise,” Timken’s Reply at 4, the Court observes that GAAP
serves as a guide and Commerce is not statutorily bound by GAAP
when valuing PRC labor costs.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 47
because [Commerce] did not take this position” in Final Results, 64
Fed. Reg. at 61,842.16 Id. at 7.
In response, Commerce asserts that its decision to use Chapter
5 wage rates to value PRC labor costs is supported by substantial
evidence and is in accordance with law. See Def.’s Mem. Partial
Opp’n Timken at 21-26. Commerce argues that 19 U.S.C. §
1677b(c)(3) does not require Commerce “to utilize comprehensive
costs for purposes of valuing labor [but] [r]ather, the statute
merely directs [Commerce] to value the ‘hours of labor required’ as
part of the [FOP] utilized in producing the merchandise.” Id. at
25. Commerce further argues that Commerce complied with 19 C.F.R.
§ 351.408(c)(3) in using Chapter 5 wage rates rather than Chapter
6A labor costs to value PRC labor costs because: (1) 19 C.F.R. §
351.408(c)(3) “does not provide that Commerce must utilize
comprehensive labor costs [but] [i]nstead, that . . . ‘[Commerce
16
The Court disagrees with Timken that Commerce’s argument
amounts to a post hoc rationalization. Commerce’s decision to
employ an easier and, in Commerce’s view, a more accurate
methodology to value PRC labor costs, falls within Commerce’s power
and the Court will uphold such methodology as long as it is
reasonable. See Final Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at 61,842 (stating
that the wage rates of Chapter 5 “are comprehensive wage rates”).
Moreover, a legal argument entered by Commerce in its capacity as
a defendant to a civil action with respect to the level of
discretion offered by the relevant statute and regulation does not
amount to a post hoc rationalization since Commerce argues its
position within the parameters of common law litigation. If
Timken’s argument is taken to its logical conclusion, every
argument by every party with respect to the legal boundaries of any
applicable provision should be deemed a form of post hoc
rationalization.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 48
shall] use regression-based wage rates,’” id. (quoting 19 C.F.R. §
351.408(c))(3)) (emphasis omitted); (2) 19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(3)
is silent as to the particular source Commerce is to use to value
wages, see Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken at 26; and (3)
Commerce’s preference to use Chapter 5 wage rates over Timken’s
preference to use Chapter 6A labor costs to value PRC labor costs
should be sustained because “the Court should defer to Commerce’s
interpretation of [the] regulation, not Timken’s interpretation.”
Id.
C. Analysis
As a preliminary matter, the Court finds that Commerce’s
decision to use the wage rates of Chapter 5 of the 1998 Yearbook
over the labor costs of Chapter 6A of the 1998 Yearbook to value
the PRC labor costs was a justifiable change of methodology as long
as such change in position was reasonably supported by the record.
See supra Discussion Part I, C1 (Analysis).
The applicable statute provides that, when dealing with
imports from an NME country such as the PRC, Commerce shall
determine the NV of the subject merchandise based on FOPs utilized
in producing the merchandise and that Commerce shall value the
reported FOPs based on the best available information regarding the
values of FOPs in an appropriate market economy. See 19 U.S.C. §
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 49
1677b(c)(1). According to section 1677b(c)(3), the FOPs to be
utilized in valuing merchandise from an NME include, but are not
limited to: “(A) hours of labor required, (B) quantities of raw
materials employed, (C) amounts of energy and other utilities
consumed, and (D) representative capital cost, including
depreciation.” The statute further provides that while conducting
NME investigations, Commerce “shall utilize, to the extent
possible, the prices or costs of [FOPs] in one or more market
economy countries that are[:] (A) at a level of economic
development comparable to that of the nonmarket economy country,
and (B) significant producers of comparable merchandise.” See 19
U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(4).
Moreover, the relevant regulation provides:
[f]or labor, [Commerce] will use regression-based wage
rates reflective of the observed relationship between
wages and national income in market economy countries.
[Commerce] will calculate the wage rate to be applied in
nonmarket economy proceedings each year. The calculation
will be based on current data, and will be made available
to the public.
19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(3).
In the case at bar, Commerce used the wage rates reported in
Chapter 5 of the 1998 Yearbook, which were “made available to the
public by means of Import Administration’s website,” to value the
PRC labor costs. Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken at 24. “The
[1998 Yearbook] states that the wage rates [that is, the wage rates
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 50
of Chapter 5], used to calculate the regression analysis are
comprehensive wage rates which also includes overtime, bonuses,
holiday pay, incentive pay, pay for piecework, and cost-of-living
allowances.” Final Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at 61,842. Based on the
foregoing, the Court finds that Commerce’s decision to value PRC
labor costs by using wage rates reported in Chapter 5 of the 1998
Yearbook over the labor costs reported in Chapter 6A of the 1998
Yearbook was reasonable, in accordance with law (that is, Sections
1677b(c)(1), (c)(3), (c)(4) and 19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(3)),
supported by substantial evidence, and in accord with the purpose
of the statutory scheme of determining antidumping margins as
accurately as possible.17 See Peer Bearing Co. v. United States,
25 CIT __, __, 182 F. Supp. 2d 1285, 1305 (2001) (pointing out that
17
Timken, in support of its argument that the Court should
“require [Commerce] to account for all labor costs not included in
Chapter 5 wage rates elsewhere in [Commerce’s] calculation [that
is, for example in the SG&A expenses,]” Timken’s Reply at 9,
provided the Court with a letter dated January 8, 2001 indicating
among other things that the 12th Administrative Review’s Issues and
Decision Memo for the 1998-99 Administrative Review of Tapered
Roller Bearings and Parts Thereof, Finished and Unfinished, from
the People’s Republic of China; Final Results “is . . . relevant to
Timken’s position in the instant judicial review” with regard to
labor costs. Timken’s January 8, 2001, letter (citing Ex. 2 at 16-
17). The Court is not persuaded by Timken’s reference to the 12th
Administrative Review and finds that while it is possible that the
labor costs not included in Chapter 5 could have been included
elsewhere in Commerce’s calculation, the Court’s “duty is not to
weigh the wisdom of, or to resolve any struggle between, competing
views of the public interest, but rather to respect legitimate
policy choices made by the agency in interpreting and applying the
statute.” Suramerica de Aleaciones Laminadas, C.A. v. United
States, 966 F.2d 660, 665 (Fed. Cir. 1992).
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 51
“‘[i]n the absence of a statutory mandate to the contrary,
Commerce’s actions must be upheld as long as they are reasonable’”
(quoting Timken 1999, 23 CIT at 516, 59 F. Supp. 2d at 1377)); see
also Chevron, 467 U.S. at 844-45, Skidmore v. Swift & Co., 323 U.S.
134, 139-40 (1944).
IV. Commerce’s Use of a PRC Producer’s Market Economy Import Data
A. Background
In the Preliminary Results, Commerce stated that a PRC
producer purchased part of its steel sheet directly from a market-
economy supplier and paid for such steel with market-economy
currency. See 64 Fed. Reg. at 36,856. In the Final Results,
Commerce used the PRC producer’s import data, rather than surrogate
data, to value the entire FOP (that is, both the directly imported
FOP and the NME sourced FOP). See 64 Fed. Reg. at 61,844.
Commerce reasoned that,
[i]n accordance with [Commerce’s] established practice
and [Commerce’s] regulations, [Commerce is] continuing to
use the actual prices of directly imported steel to value
steel inputs because these prices represent the actual
market-based prices incurred in producing the subject
merchandise and, as such, are the most accurate and
appropriate values for this particular factor for the
purpose of calculating NV. As noted by the respondents,
this practice has been affirmed in court decisions, such
as Lasko, [43 F.3d 1442] and is codified in [Commerce’s]
regulations at section 351.408(c)(1).
As noted in [Commerce’s] Final Rule, [62 Fed. Reg.
at 27,366,] while [Commerce] do[es] not view the Lasko
decision as permitting [Commerce] to use distorted
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 52
prices, [Commerce] believe[s] that the Court’s emphasis
on ‘accuracy, fairness and predictability’ provides
[Commerce] with the ability to rely on prices paid by NME
producers to market-economy suppliers in lieu of using
surrogate values. . . . [Commerce] disagree[s] with
[Timken] that imports into China are unreliable
indicators of market values because China’s domestic
market is distorted by government intervention. While
China’s NME status indicates that domestic prices in
China are unreliable, there is no evidence that domestic
distortions impact the price at which market-economy
suppliers would offer products for sale to Chinese
producers. [Commerce] ha[s] no reason to assume that,
when dealing with Chinese importers, market-economy
suppliers ignore rules of supply, demand, and profit-
seeking behavior within a competitive world market.
Id. at 61,844-45.
Moreover, Commerce observed:
Even if [Commerce] were to accept [Timken’s] argument
that excess steel supply in China leads foreign
competitors to ‘dump’ steel on the Chinese market,
[Timken] has not presented evidence that there is an
excess supply of the particular type of steel used in the
production of TRBs nor evidence that such excess supply
somehow renders the steel prices being offered to certain
Chinese TRB producers by market-economy suppliers
unreliable. There are a variety of reasons for setting
a particular price higher or lower than a world benchmark
in an arm’s length transaction. In examining actual
sales between private parties, [Commerce] would have to
be convinced by evidence on the record that the
particular sale in question was in some way
unrepresentative of market-economy forces. For example,
[Commerce] would be willing to disregard a price paid by
an NME producer to a market-economy supplier if the
quantity of the input purchased in a given transaction
is, for example, less than the volume that would normally
be traded. Where the transaction is not in commercial
quantities, the price may not be truly representative of
a market price.
Id. at 61,845.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 53
B. Contentions of the Parties
1. Timken’s Contentions
Timken argues that Commerce’s determination that a PRC bearing
producer’s import price18 constituted the “best available
information” under 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(1) to value steel sheet was
contrary to 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(1) and unsupported by substantial
evidence because Commerce failed to determine whether the price
paid by the PRC bearing producer to the market-economy supplier was
“market-driven” or representative of market prices. See Timken’s
Mem. at 25-34. In particular, Timken maintains that Commerce
“should not assume that Chinese bearing producers are paying world
market prices for imported inputs,” id. at 27 (emphasis omitted),
because: (1) “[l]egislative history . . . warns that the ‘best’
information cannot be prices believed or suspected to be dumped or
subsidized,” Timken’s Reply at 15; (2) “NME markets are ‘riddled
with distortions’ . . . [and] State-controlled economies control
the entities that engage in foreign trade, as well as their sales
prices,” Timken’s Mem. at 29 (quoting Georgetown Steel Corp. v.
United States, 801 F.2d 1308, 1315 (Fed. Cir. 1986)); (3) “third
countries do not necessarily trade with China on a market-economy
basis,” Timken’s Mem. at 30; and (4) “China was the world’s biggest
18
The Court notes that the PRC bearing producer’s import
price was the same for all of the imported steel sheet from the
market-economy supplier. See Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken,
Proprietary App. Ex. 1.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 54
steel producer with excess capacity during the period of review .
. . [and, therefore,] Chinese bearing producers . . . could have
easily sourced their material inputs from domestic suppliers.”
Id.; see also Timken’s Reply at 21 n.11.
Timken further argues that Commerce’s presumption that the PRC
bearing producer’s import price constituted the “best available
information” to value the steel sheet used in the production of
cages “was tantamount to [a] conclusive presumption . . . and was
. . . inconsistent” with 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(1) and 19 C.F.R. §
351.408(c)(1).19 Timken’s Reply at 17. Relying on the CAFC’s
decision in Delverde, SRL v. United States, 202 F.3d 1360 (Fed.
Cir. 2000), Timken maintains that just as the CAFC “found that
[Commerce] erred when [Commerce] failed to consider the ‘facts or
circumstances of the sale,’ to produce evidence to show a subsidy,
or to make the specific findings required by [19 U.S.C. §
1677(5),]” id. at 14 (quoting Delverde, 202 F.3d at 1367), the
Court in this case should disapprove Commerce’s determination that
the PRC bearing producer’s import price constituted the “best
19
In its reply brief, Timken asserts that Commerce’s use of
the word “normally” in 19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(1) “must be
understood as contemplating additional circumstances,” that is,
circumstances in addition to those indicated by Commerce in Final
Rule, 62 Fed. Reg. at 27,366, “wherein import prices would be
rejected.” Timken’s Reply at 12 n.8. The Court does not agree
with Timken’s reading of 19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(1). Although the
term “normally” refers to a predominate scenario, it does not
preclude the same process of analysis in other situations.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 55
available information” to value the steel sheet at issue because,
“[a]nalogously to what [Commerce] did in Delverde, [Commerce in the
case at bar] simply presumed that the import price[] w[as] the
‘best’ information without testing the facts in any way, much less
producing evidence to support [Commerce’s] finding of fact.”
Timken’s Reply at 16.
Additionally, Timken contends that Commerce has the burden to
establish the accuracy of the dumping margins and cannot assign the
burden to prove the contrary to interested parties. See id. at 17-
18. In particular, Timken maintains that Commerce’s allocation of
the burden of proof on Timken to show that the import price
Commerce used was unrepresentative of market-economy forces was
unreasonable because: (1) “[w]hile it may be reasonable for
[Commerce] to allocate the burden of proof to the party with
knowledge or having access to facts, it is unreasonable to allocate
such burden to a party that has neither and can only raise
questions,” id. at 18; and (2) “Timken has repeatedly challenged
the use of import prices in [various] reviews . . . [and Commerce]
has rejected [Timken’s] contentions without articulating what is
required for Timken to show that such prices are unreliable.”20
20
Timken points out that Commerce, in rejecting Timken’s
challenges to the use of import prices in various reviews, “has
merely suggested that it would reject prices that were not arm’s
length or for merchandise in quantities that were ‘insignificant’
or not ‘meaningful.’” Timken’s Reply at 20. Timken maintains that
(continued...)
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 56
Id. at 20. Timken, therefore, argues that Commerce “must itself
test the import prices to determine whether they are market
driven.” Timken’s Mem. at 32 (emphasis omitted). Timken contends
that, “as [Commerce] evaluates market-economy prices to determine
whether they are reliable in a market-economy case, [Commerce]
should evaluate those prices to determine whether they are reliable
in an NME case.”21 Timken’s Mem. at 33-34. Timken also contends
that Commerce “did not compare the [import] price[] to other world
market prices or consider the volume and frequency of imports from
a market economy” and “did not consider whether the import price[]
w[as] at arm’s length, reflected commercial quantities, or
reasonably reflected the actual cost of production in a comparable
market economy.” Id. at 32.
Alternatively, Timken argues that “Timken amply rebutted
[Commerce’s] presumption” that the import data constituted the
“best available information” to value the steel sheet at issue.
Timken’s Reply at 21 (emphasis omitted); see id. at 21-24.
20
(...continued)
“this is insufficient to address the host of other potential
situations wherein import prices would clearly not be the best
available information on the facts.” Id.
21
Timken asserts that although Lasko, 43 F.3d at 1446, allows
Commerce to use import prices from market-economy sources to value
FOPs in appropriate situations, “the Court [in Lasko] did not
address the issue [presented in this case] of whether [Commerce]
had an obligation to determine whether the prices . . . were, in
fact, market-driven or otherwise reliable.” Timken’s Reply at 11
n.7.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 57
Specifically, Timken points out that: (1) the import price used by
Commerce to value the subject merchandise at issue was based on a
sale that predated the POR by over a year “and more information was
needed to determine whether that steel was actually used to
manufacture the merchandise under review,” id. at 21 n.12
(proprietary version); (2) a “single purchase was not sufficient to
meet [the PRC producer’s] steel requirements, and that further
inquiry was necessary to determine whether non-price factors
affected the sale,” id.; (3) the import price used by Commerce to
value the steel sheet at issue was lower than various benchmarks,
see Timken’s Mem. at 31-32 (proprietary version) (citing Timken’s
Mem. at 17, Table 3); (4) “[t]here was no evidence supporting
[Commerce’s] belief that the price the Chinese bearing producers
would pay for imported steel would be unaffected by non-market
considerations,” Timken’s Reply at 22; and (5) Commerce “had no
information concerning how [the PRC producer] identified the source
of its steel, traced the steel to production during the [POR], or
produced from this steel [TRBs] exported to the United States. Nor
did [Commerce] know whether the import price represented an
ordinary transaction.” Id. at 22-23 (proprietary version).
Timken, therefore, requests that this Court remand the issue to
Commerce with instructions “to determine whether or not the import
price[] paid to [a] market-economy supplier[] to value steel sheet
w[as] market driven . . . .” Timken’s Reply at 23.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 58
Next, relying on Shakeproof Assembly, 23 CIT 479, 59 F. Supp.
2d 1354, Timken contends that Commerce’s decision to use a PRC
producer’s import data to value other purchases (that is, the NME
sourced FOP) without “explain[ing] why [the] import [data was] more
accurate (or ‘meaningful’) than surrogate-country values” was
unsupported by substantial evidence and was contrary to law.22
Timken’s Reply at 28; see also id. at 24-28; Timken’s Mem. at 34-
37. Timken further contends that “[e]xtending the actual import
[data] to the additional relevant steel served to magnify the
original error.” Timken’s Reply at 26. Moreover, responding to
Commerce’s arguments that 19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(1) “(1) . . .
permits [Commerce] to determine [NV] based on the company’s own
market-based experience; (2) . . . leads to more accurate dumping
margins . . . ; and (3) . . . is consistent with the purpose of the
statute [that is, 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(1)] . . .,” Timken asserts
22
In its reply brief, Timken maintains that “Timken does not
argue, as [Commerce] suggests, that [Commerce] incorrectly valued
domestically-purchased steel using import prices from a market
source, but instead that [Commerce] incorrectly valued the steel
imported through a PRC trading company (to be distinguished from a
market-[economy] country trading company).” Timken’s Reply at 24
n.13 (proprietary version). The Court assumes that Timken’s
aforementioned statement means that Timken is contesting Commerce’s
decision to use a PRC producer’s import data to value the FOP
purchased from a PRC trading company. The record indicates that a
PRC producer purchased various portions of the steel sheet at issue
(1) directly from a market-economy supplier and paid for such steel
with market-economy currency; and (2) from a certain PRC company
that imported steel sheet from a certain country to China.
See Preliminary Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at 36,856; Final Results, 64
Fed. Reg. at 61,844; Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken, Proprietary
App. Exs. 1, 2, 4, 6; Timken’s Mem. Prop. Docs. 7, 15, 31, 34.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 59
that these arguments must be rejected as post hoc rationalizations
because Commerce did not articulate them in Final Results, 64 Fed.
Reg. 61,844-45.23 Timken’s Reply at 25.
2. Commerce’s Contentions
Commerce responds that its determination to value certain
steel inputs by using the price paid by a PRC bearing producer to
a market-economy supplier was supported by substantial evidence,
was in accordance with law and sustained by the CAFC in Lasko, 43
F.3d 1442. See Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken at 26-40. In
particular, Commerce points out that the CAFC in Lasko, 43 F.3d
1442, recognized that 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(1) “requires Commerce to
value factors of production using the ‘best available information’
and that,” the CAFC found that “‘the best available information on
what the supplies used by the Chinese manufacturers would cost in
a market economy country was the price charged by those supplies on
the international market.’” Id. (quoting Lasko, 43 F.3d at 1446).
Additionally, with respect to Timken’s argument that Commerce
erred in its decision to use a PRC bearing producer’s import data
to value the steel sheet at issue by failing to determine whether
the prices paid by the PRC bearing producer to the market-economy
23
The Court disagrees with Timken that Commerce’s arguments
amount to a post hoc rationalization. See supra Discussion Part
III, B (Contentions of the Parties) n.16.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 60
supplier were “market-driven” or representative of market prices,
Commerce argues that Timken’s argument should be rejected because
Timken never presented this argument to Commerce in its case brief.
See Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken at 28-31. Commerce alleges
that Timken, therefore, “failed to exhaust its administrative
remedies with respect to this issue.”24 Id. at 28 (emphasis
24
In its reply brief, Timken first points out that “in its
case brief, Timken argued”:
[C]oncerning the price of imported steel used for one
Chinese producer’s cages in the 97-98 review . . . , the
unusual circumstances attending the importation indicate
that the price was not representative and was indeed
“aberrational” and unreliable. All surrogate values,
including those based on market economy imports into
China, must be reliable and reasonable values to be used
for purposes of calculating normal value. . . .
. . . .
. . . Commerce does not have any reason to relax the
require[ment]s of the statute and practice.
To the contrary, Commerce should assume that any imports
from market-economy countries are not valued at
“reliable” market values, absent evidence that such
values are otherwise consistent with world-market prices.
The current approach turns this policy on its head – in
effect ignoring the market distortions that NME
methodology is designed to address.
. . . The statute does not compel Commerce to use factor
values that are unreliable or unrepresentative of market
economy prices.
Timken’s Reply at 29-30 (quoting Timken’s Reply Pub. Doc. 132,
emphasis omitted).
Second, Timken argues that “[d]uring the hearing, counsel for
Timken again explained that [Commerce] was required to test every
(continued...)
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 61
omitted).
In the alternative, Commerce argues that, “[e]ven if Timken
has exhausted its administrative remedies, Commerce acted within
its discretion by not testing the prices in question to determine
whether they were market-driven.” Id. at 31. In particular,
Commerce maintains that: (1) “Commerce properly assumes that, where
a factor is purchased from a market economy supplier and purchased
with a market economy currency, the price paid for that imported
merchandise is not distorted [and could be] appropriately used for
purposes of valuing the factor in question [in a manner] . . .
consistent with the purpose of the antidumping law,” id. at 31-32
(citing Lasko, 43 F.3d at 1446); (2) “Commerce[’s] require[ment
that] the party challenging the use of the market economy price
[should] present evidence that the price is somehow inappropriate
for determining NV” is consistent with Commerce’s “‘broad
discretion in allocating investigative and enforcement resources,’”
Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken at 32 (quoting Torrington Co., 68
F.3d at 1350); and (3) since Timken fails to present “specific
evidence of distortion” with regards to Commerce’s use of the PRC
producer’s import data at issue, “Commerce does not err when it
requires [Timken] to substantiate [its] views with record evidence
24
(...continued)
factor value and repeatedly requested that [Commerce] rethink its
regulation.” Timken’s Reply at 30 (emphasis omitted).
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 62
as opposed to mere speculation.” Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken
at 33 (citing LMI La-Metalli Industriale, S.p.A. v. United States,
912 F.2d 455, 460 (Fed. Cir. 1990)).
Finally, with respect to Commerce’s determination to value the
entire FOP (that is, both the imported FOP and the NME sourced FOP)
by using a PRC producer’s import data, Commerce asserts that
Commerce acted within the plain meaning of 19 C.F.R. §
351.408(c)(1). See Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken at 34-35.
Commerce further asserts that 19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(1) is a
reasonable interpretation of 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(1) because: (1)
“Commerce’s interpretation is consistent with the fact that dumping
is an activity that is ‘defined in terms of the marketplace,’”
id. at 36 (quoting Lasko, 43 F.3d at 1446); (2) “Commerce’s use of
imported prices to value all purchases of the same factor of
production results in a more accurate dumping margin because these
imported prices reflect[] a market-driven decision by the company
in question,” Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken at 37; and (3)
“Commerce’s interpretation is consistent with the underlying
purposes governing the non-market economy provisions of the
statute.” Id.
Moreover, Commerce argues that Timken’s contention regarding
Commerce’s use of a PRC bearing producer’s import data to value the
entire FOP at issue “do not demonstrate error in Commerce’s
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 63
determination.” Id. at 38 (emphasis omitted). Commerce points out
that Timken’s reliance on Shakeproof Assembly, 23 CIT 479, 59 F.
Supp. 2d 1354, is mistaken because that “decision[] reviewed a
Commerce determination that pre-dated the effective date of 19
C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(1).” Id. at 39. Commerce also points out that
although “Commerce did not explain [in the Final Results, 64 Fed.
Reg. at 61,844-45,] why the imports in question were meaningful[,]
. . . Timken itself must accept responsibility for the absence of
such an explanation because Timken never raised that issue with
Commerce.” Id. Commerce, therefore, contends that Timken failed
to exhaust its administrative remedies with respect to this issue.25
See id. at 39-40.
C. Analysis
The applicable statute provides that, when dealing with
imports from an NME country such as the PRC, Commerce shall
determine the NV of the subject merchandise based on FOPs utilized
in producing the merchandise. See 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(1). The
statute further provides that Commerce shall value the reported
FOPs based on the best available information regarding the values
of FOPs in an appropriate market economy. See id. While
25
Commerce asserts that “[i]ndeed, the proprietary figures
referenced by Timken appear to indicate that the amount of imported
steel was, in fact, meaningful.” Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken
at 40 n.30 (citing Timken’s Reply Prop. Doc. 35).
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 64
conducting NME investigations, Commerce “shall utilize, to the
extent possible, the prices or costs of [FOPs] in one or more
market economy countries that are[:] (A) at a level of economic
development comparable to that of the nonmarket economy country,
and (B) significant producers of comparable merchandise.” See 19
U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(4).
The CAFC, however, reasoned that “the purpose of the statutory
provisions [that is, §§ 1677b(c)(1) and (4)] is to determine
antidumping margins ‘as accurately as possible.’” Shakeproof, 268
F.3d at 1382 (quoting Lasko, 43 F.3d at 1446); see also Olympia
1998, 22 CIT at 390, 7 F. Supp. 2d at 1000-01 (noting that
“accuracy is the touchstone of the antidumping statute” and citing
Rhone Poulenc, 899 F.2d at 1191. Additionally, Commerce’s “task in
[an NME] investigation is to calculate what [the] . . . costs or
prices would be [in the NME] if such prices or costs were
determined by market forces.” Tianjin, 16 CIT at 940, 806 F. Supp.
at 1018.
1. Commerce’s Decision to Value Certain Steel Inputs
by Using the Price Paid by a PRC Bearing Producer
As a preliminary matter, the Court addresses Commerce’s
argument that Timken failed to exhaust its administrative remedies.
The exhaustion doctrine requires a party to present its claims to
the relevant administrative agency for the agency’s consideration
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 65
before raising these claims to the Court. See Unemployment
Compensation Comm’n of Alaska v. Aragon, 329 U.S. 143, 155, (1946)
(“A reviewing court usurps the agency’s function when it sets aside
the administrative determination upon a ground not theretofore
presented and deprives the [agency] of an opportunity to consider
the matter, make its ruling, and state the reasons for its
action”).26
26
There is however, no absolute requirement of exhaustion in
the Court of International Trade in non-classification cases. See
Alhambra Foundry Co. v. United States, 12 CIT 343, 346-47, 685 F.
Supp. 1252, 1255-56 (1988). Section 2637(d) of Title 28 directs
that “the Court of International Trade shall, where appropriate,
require the exhaustion of administrative remedies.” By its use of
the phrase “where appropriate,” Congress vested discretion in the
Court to determine the circumstances under which it shall require
the exhaustion of administrative remedies. See Cemex, S.A. v.
United States, 133 F.3d 897, 905 (Fed. Cir. 1998). Therefore,
because “each exercise of judicial discretion [does] not requir[e]
litigants to exhaust administrative remedies,” the court is
authorized to determine proper exceptions to the doctrine of
exhaustion. Alhambra, 12 CIT at 347, 685 F. Supp. at 1256 (citing
Timken Co. v. United States, 10 CIT 86, 93, 630 F. Supp. 1327, 1334
(1986), rev’d in part on other grounds, Koyo Seiko Co. v. United
States, 20 F.3d 1156 (Fed. Cir. 1994)).
In the past, the court has exercised its discretion to obviate
exhaustion where: (1) requiring it would be futile, see Rhone
Poulenc, S.A. v. United States, 7 CIT 133, 135, 583 F. Supp. 607,
610 (1984) (“it appears that it would have been futile for
plaintiffs to argue that the agency should not apply its own
regulation”), or would be “inequitable and an insistence of a
useless formality” as in the case where “there is no relief which
plaintiff may be granted at the administrative level,” United
States Cane Sugar Refiners’ Ass’n v. Block, 3 CIT 196, 201, 544 F.
Supp. 883, 887 (1982); (2) a subsequent court decision has
interpreted existing law after the administrative determination at
issue was published, and the new decision might have materially
affected the agency’s actions, see Timken, 10 CIT at 93, 630 F.
(continued...)
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 66
The purpose behind the doctrine of exhaustion is to prevent
courts from premature involvement in administrative proceedings,
and to protect agencies “from judicial interference until an
administrative decision has been formalized and its effects felt in
a concrete way by the challenging parties.” Abbott Labs. v.
Gardner, 387 U.S. 136, 148-49 (1967); see also Public Citizen
Health Research Group v. Comm’r, FDA, 740 F.2d 21, 29 (D.C. Cir.
1984) (pointing out that the “exhaustion doctrine . . . serv[es]
four primary purposes: [(1)] it ensures that persons do not flout
[legally] established administrative processes . . .; [(2)] it
protects the autonomy of agency decisionmaking; [(3)] it aids
judicial review by permitting factual development [of issues
relevant to the dispute]; and [(4)] it serves judicial economy by
avoiding [repetitious] administrative and judicial factfinding and
by” resolving sole claims without judicial intervention).
While a plaintiff cannot circumvent the requirements of the
doctrine of exhaustion by merely mentioning a broad issue without
raising a particular argument, plaintiff’s brief statement of the
26
(...continued)
Supp. at 1334; (3) the question is one of law and does not require
further factual development and, therefore, the court does not
invade the province of the agency by considering the question, see
id.; R.R. Yardmasters of Am. v. Harris, 721 F.2d 1332, 1337-39
(D.C. Cir. 1983); and (4) plaintiffs had no reason to suspect that
the agency would refuse to adhere to clearly applicable precedent.
See Philipp Bros., Inc. v. United States, 10 CIT 76, 80, 630 F.
Supp. 1317, 1321 (1986).
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 67
argument is sufficient if it alerts the agency to the argument with
reasonable clarity and avails the agency with an opportunity to
address it. See generally, Hormel v. Helvering, 312 U.S. 552
(1941); see also Rhone Poulenc, 899 F.2d at 1191. The sole fact of
an agency’s failure to address plaintiff’s challenge does not
invoke the exhaustion doctrine and shall not result in forfeiture
of plaintiff’s judicial remedies. See generally, B-West Imports,
Inc. v. United States, 19 CIT 303, 880 F. Supp. 853 (1995). An
administrative decision not to address the issue cannot be
dispositive of the question whether or not the issue was properly
brought to the agency’s attention. See, e.g., Allnutt v. United
States DOJ, 2000 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 4060 (D. Md. 2000).
In the case at bar, Timken sufficiently provided Commerce with
an opportunity to address the issue of Commerce’s failure to
determine whether the price paid by the PRC bearing producer to the
market-economy supplier was “market-driven” or representative of
market prices when Timken in its case brief argued inter alia that:
(1) “‘the unusual circumstances attending the importation indicate
that the price was not representative and was indeed
‘abberrational’ and unreliable,’” Timken’s Reply at 29 (quoting
Timken’s Reply Pub. Doc. 132, emphasis omitted); (2) “‘Commerce
should assume that any imports from market-economy countries are
not valued at ‘reliable’ market values, absent evidence that such
values are otherwise consistent with world-market prices,’” id.;
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 68
(3) “‘[Commerce’s] current approach . . . in effect ignor[es] the
market distortions that NME methodology is designed to address,’”
id. at 29-30 (quoting Timken’s Reply Pub. Doc. 132); and (4)
“‘[t]he statue does not compel Commerce to use factor values that
are unreliable or unrepresentative of market economy prices.’”
Id. at 30 (quoting Timken’s Reply Pub. Doc. 132, emphasis omitted).
Moreover, at the administrative level, counsel for Timken
“explained that [Commerce] was required to test every factor value
and repeatedly requested that [Commerce] rethink its regulation.”
Timken’s Reply at 30 (emphasis omitted).
The Court, therefore, concludes that Timken properly exhausted
its administrative remedies and has the right to raise this issue
to the Court.
The Court disagrees with Timken’s argument that since Commerce
did not use the mode of examination offered by Timken on the issue,
that is, whether the price paid by a PRC bearing manufacturer to a
market-economy supplier was market-driven or representative of
market-prices, Commerce’s determination to value certain steel
inputs by using the price paid by the PRC bearing producer was
contrary to 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(1) and unsupported by substantial
evidence.
First, the Court is not persuaded by Timken’s reliance on the
CAFC’s decision in Delverde, 202 F.3d 1360, for the proposition
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 69
that this Court should disapprove Commerce’s determination that the
PRC bearing producer’s import price constituted the “best available
information” to value the steel sheet at issue because,
“[a]nalogously to what [Commerce] did in Delverde, [Commerce in the
case at bar] simply presumed that the import price[] w[as] the
‘best’ information without testing the facts in any way, much less
producing evidence to support [Commerce’s] finding of fact.”
Timken’s Reply at 16. As the Court in Lasko Metal, 16 CIT at 1081,
810 F. Supp. at 317, stated: “[T]he cost for raw materials from a
market economy supplier, paid in convertible currencies, provides
Commerce with the closest approximation of the cost of producing
the goods in a market economy country.” 16 CIT at 1081, 810 F.
Supp. at 317 (emphasis supplied).
“[W]here we can determine that a [non-market economy]
producer’s input prices are market determined, accuracy,
fairness, and predictability are enhanced by using those
prices. Therefore, using surrogate values when market-
based values are available would, in fact, be contrary to
the intent of the law.”
Shakeproof, 268 F.3d at 1382 (emphasis in original) (quoting Lasko,
43 F.3d at 1446); accord Oscillating Fans, 56 Fed. Reg. at 55,275.
Therefore, the cost for raw materials from a market-economy
supplier, paid in convertible currency, constitutes an alternative
market-driven price for the purpose of valuation.
In the case at bar, Commerce determined that the import price
paid by a PRC bearing producer in market-economy currency to a
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 70
market-economy supplier represented the “best available
information” to value the steel sheet at issue. Commerce reasoned:
In accordance with [Commerce’s] established practice and
[Commerce’s] regulations, [Commerce is] continuing to use
the actual prices of directly imported steel to value
steel inputs because these prices represent the actual
market-based prices incurred in producing the subject
merchandise and, as such, are the most accurate and
appropriate values for this particular factor for the
purpose of calculating NV. As noted by the respondents,
this practice has been affirmed in court decisions, such
as Lasko, [43 F.3d 1442] and is codified in [Commerce’s]
regulations at section 351.408(c)(1).
Final Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at 61,844-45.
The Court finds that Commerce’s determination to value certain
steel inputs by using the price paid by a PRC bearing producer to
a market-economy supplier is reasonable and is in accordance with
19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(1) and 19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(1). See Peer
Bearing, 25 CIT at __, 182 F. Supp. 2d at 1305 (“‘In the absence of
a statutory mandate to the contrary, Commerce’s actions must be
upheld as long as they are reasonable’” (quoting Timken 1999, 23
CIT at 516, 59 F. Supp. 2d at 1377)); see also Chevron, 467 U.S. at
844-45, and Skidmore, 323 U.S. at 139-40.
Second, the Court disagrees with Timken’s argument that
Commerce unreasonably allocated the burden of proof to Timken to
show that the import data Commerce used to value certain steel
inputs was unrepresentative of market-economy forces. As Commerce
correctly notes, “Commerce does not err when it requires parties to
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 71
substantiate their views with record evidence as opposed to mere
speculation.” Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken at 33 (citation
omitted).
During the POR, Commerce stated:
[Commerce] disagree[s] with [Timken] that imports into
China are unreliable indicators of market values because
China’s domestic market is distorted by government
intervention. While China’s NME status indicates that
domestic prices in China are unreliable, there is no
evidence that domestic distortions impact the price at
which market-economy suppliers would offer products for
sale to Chinese producers. [Commerce] ha[s] no reason to
assume that, when dealing with Chinese importers, market-
economy suppliers ignore rules of supply, demand, and
profit-seeking behavior within a competitive world
market.
Final Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at 61,845.
Commerce observed:
Even if [Commerce] were to accept [Timken’s] argument
that excess steel supply in China leads foreign
competitors to “dump” steel on the Chinese market,
[Timken] has not presented evidence that there is an
excess supply of the particular type of steel used in the
production of TRBs nor evidence that such excess supply
somehow renders the steel prices being offered to certain
Chinese TRB producers by market-economy suppliers
unreliable. There are a variety of reasons for setting
a particular price higher or lower than a world benchmark
in an arm’s length transaction. In examining actual
sales between private parties, [Commerce] would have to
be convinced by evidence on the record that the
particular sale in question was in some way
unrepresentative of market-economy forces. For example,
[Commerce] would be willing to disregard a price paid by
an NME producer to a market-economy supplier if the
quantity of the input purchased in a given transaction
is, for example, less than the volume that would normally
be traded. Where the transaction is not in commercial
quantities, the price may not be truly representative of
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 72
a market price.
Id.
Moreover, with respect to Timken’s generalization that
“Chinese bearing producers are [not] paying world market prices for
imported inputs,” Timken’s Mem. at 27 (emphasis omitted), the Court
finds that Timken’s arguments amount to mere speculation.
Similarly, with regards to Timken’s contention that Timken “amply
rebutted [Commerce’s] presumption” that the import data constituted
the “best available information” to value the steel sheet at issue,
Timken’s Reply at 21, the Court is unconvinced. The Court holds
that Commerce did not unreasonably allocate the burden of proof to
Timken to show that the import data Commerce used to value certain
steel inputs was unrepresentative of market-economy forces.
Finally, the Court disagrees with Timken’s arguments that: (1)
“as [Commerce] evaluates market-economy prices to determine whether
they are reliable in a market-economy case, [Commerce] should [use
the same mode to] evaluate those prices to determine whether they
are reliable in [an] NME case,”27 Timken’s Mem. at 33-34; and (2)
27
Market-economy cases and non-market economy cases are
distinct. See, e.g., Shakeproof, 268 F.3d at 1379 n.1. (“The [NV]
of goods in ‘market economy’ cases is generally the price at which
the foreign product is first sold in the exporting country. . . .
[T]he normal value of goods in [NME] may be instead determined by
looking at the ‘factors of production’ used to manufacture the
goods,” (citations omitted)); see also Lasko, 43 F.3d at 1445
(“[I]f [Commerce] cannot determine [NV] pursuant to the general
(continued...)
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 73
Commerce was obligated to examine the volume and frequency of
Luoyang’s market-economy purchases. See Timken Co., 26 CIT at __,
201 F. Supp. 2d at 1337 (citing Final Results of Antidumping Duty
Administrative Review of Certain Helical Spring Lock Washers From
the People’s Republic of China, 62 Fed. Reg. 61,794, 61,796 (Nov.
19, 1997), and Final Rule, 62 Fed. Reg. at 27,366, and stating that
“[a]s Commerce correctly notes, . . . it is [Commerce’s] practice
to consider the volume of market-economy purchases for purposes of
determining whether to value domestically-purchased inputs based
upon the value of imports from a market-economy country”).
Accordingly, the Court affirms Commerce’s decision to value
certain steel inputs by using the price paid by a PRC producer to
a market-economy supplier.28
27
(...continued)
provisions of [19 U.S.C.] § 1677b(a), then [Commerce] must use the
[FOP] methodology to estimate [NV] for the merchandise in question”
(emphasis in original)).
28
Timken provided the Court with a letter dated January 8,
2001, indicating, among other things, that the 12th Administrative
Review’s Issues and Decision Memo for the 1998-99 Administrative
Review of Tapered Roller Bearings and Parts Thereof, Finished and
Unfinished, from the People’s Republic of China; Final Results and
the Allegation of Unfair Steel Prices memorandum, “suggest[s] . .
. that [Commerce] ha[s] taken a new position respecting the use of
actual market-prices in calculating Chinese values.” Timken’s
January 8, 2001, letter (citing Exs. 2 at 3-8 and 3). The Court is
not persuaded by Timken’s argument. See generally, Hoogovens Staal
BV v. United States, 22 CIT 139, 144, 4 F. Supp. 2d 1213, 1218
(1998) (stating that “[w]hatever additional information that
persuaded Commerce that [the plaintiffs] had discontinued [their]
practice . . . during [the subsequent] period of review was not a
(continued...)
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 74
2. Commerce’s Decision to Value the Entire FOP by
Using the Price Paid by a PRC Bearing Producer
In applying the FOP methodology to an NME, if Commerce finds
that actual costs represent the “best available information,”
Commerce has the discretion to take a combined approach and to
consider actual costs paid by the NME producer for each FOP.
See Lasko, 43 F.3d at 1445-46; Magnesium Corp. of Am. v. United
States, 20 CIT 1092, 1098, 938 F. Supp. 885, 892 (1996). The
statute does not specify what constitutes “best available
information,” nor does it prescribe a specific method for valuing
FOP when a portion of the factor to be valued represents a source
in the NME itself and a portion of the same FOP represents a source
obtained from a market-economy supplier and paid for in market-
economy currency.
Moreover, the relevant regulation provides:
[Commerce] normally will use publicly available
information to value factors. However, where a factor is
purchased from a market economy supplier and paid for in
a market economy currency, [Commerce] normally will use
the price paid to the market economy supplier. In those
instances where a portion of the factor is purchased from
a market economy supplier and the remainder from a
nonmarket economy supplier, [Commerce] normally will
value the factor using the price paid to the market
economy supplier.
19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(1).
28
(...continued)
part of the record for this review,” and “Commerce correctly based
its decision on the information in the record”).
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 75
In the case at bar, Commerce used the PRC producer’s import
data, rather than surrogate data, to value the entire FOP (that is,
both the directly imported FOP and the NME sourced FOP). See Final
Results, 64 Fed. Reg. 61,844. Commerce, however, admittedly failed
to “explain [in the Final Results, 64 Fed. Reg. 61,844-45,] why the
imports in question were meaningful.” Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n
Timken at 39.
As a preliminary matter, the Court finds that Timken exhausted
its administrative remedies and has the right to raise the issue of
Commerce’s failure to determine whether the imports in question
were meaningful because Timken sufficiently provided Commerce with
an opportunity to address this issue when Timken in its case brief
argued that “Commerce should not assign the Chinese imported steel
values to a larger volume of steel inventory than such purchases
actually represent.” Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken, App. Ex. 7
at 24 (proprietary version) (emphasis omitted); see also
supra Discussion Part IV, C1 (Analysis).
Commerce’s failure to address whether the import data at issue
was meaningful, however, prevents the Court from reviewing the
issue of Commerce’s decision to value the entire FOP (that is, both
the directly imported FOP and the NME sourced FOP) intelligibly.
In the commentary accompanying the promulgation of 19 C.F.R. §
351.408(c)(1) Commerce states that:
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 76
[Commerce] would not rely on the price paid by an NME
producer to a market economy supplier if the quantity of
the input purchased was insignificant. . . . [T]he
amounts purchased from the market economy supplier must
be meaningful. . . .
Final Rule, 62 Fed. Reg. at 27,366 (emphasis supplied).
Similarly, with respect to Timken’s argument that Commerce’s
decision to use a PRC producer’s import data to value other
purchases (that is, the NME sourced FOP) without “explain[ing] why
[the] import [data was] more accurate (or ‘meaningful’) than
surrogate-country values,” Timken’s Reply at 28, the Court finds
that while the Court’s “duty is not to weigh the wisdom of, or to
resolve any struggle between, competing views of the public
interest, but rather to respect legitimate policy choices made by
the agency in interpreting and applying the statute,” Suramerica,
966 F.2d at 665, it was illogical for Commerce to utilize a PRC
bearing producer’s import data to value the entire FOP (that is,
both the directly imported FOP and the NME sourced FOP) without
explaining why analogously structured PRC trading company data
could not be used as a surrogate value.
Based on the foregoing, the Court remands this issue to
Commerce with instructions to: (1) explain, with reference to the
record, whether or not the PRC bearing producer’s import data at
issue was “meaningful”; and (2) provide the Court with an
explanation as to why the PRC trading company data is not the “best
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 77
available information” for the purpose of valuing either the entire
FOP (that is, both the directly imported FOP and the NME sourced
FOP) or the NME sourced FOP.
V. Commerce’s Reliance on Six Indian Producers’ Reported Data in
Commerce’s Determination of Overhead, Selling, General and
Administrative Expenses and Profit Rates
A. Background
Section 1677b(c)(1) of Title 19 requires Commerce to “deter-
mine the [NV] of the subject merchandise on the basis of the value
of the [FOPs] utilized in producing the merchandise and to which
shall be added an amount for general expenses and profit plus the
cost of containers, coverings, and other expenses.” General
expenses are the expenses that do not bear a direct relationship to
the production of the merchandise at issue, such as SG&A expenses.
The subsection also states that the valuation of FOPs “shall be
based on the best available information regarding the values of
such factors in a market economy country or countries considered to
be appropriate by [Commerce].” Id. Section 1677b(c)(4) provides
that, in valuing FOPs under paragraph (1) of § 1677b(c), Commerce
“shall utilize, to the extent possible, the prices or costs of
[FOPs] in one or more market economy countries. . . .”
Moreover, the relevant regulation provides
[f]or manufacturing overhead, general expenses, and
profit, [Commerce] normally will use non-proprietary
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 78
information gathered from producers of identical or
comparable merchandise in the surrogate country.
19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(4) (1998).
In the Preliminary Results, Commerce used “information
obtained from the fiscal year 1997-98 annual reports of six Indian
bearing producers” as surrogate values for factory overhead, SG&A
and profit.29 64 Fed. Reg. at 36,856; see also Def.’s Mem. Partial
29
In Commerce’s June 30, 1999, decision memorandum discussing
the FOP values used for the Preliminary Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at
36,856, Commerce stated:
To calculate surrogate values for factory overhead and
SG&A, [Commerce] first categorized all of the non-direct
expenses (excluding labor) of six Indian bearings
producers, as reported in their 1997-98 annual reports,
as either overhead or SG&A, as appropriate. [Commerce]
ha[s] excluded the data for Asian Bearings [“Asian”] and
[National Engineering Company] [“]NEI[”] in calculating
surrogate overhead, SG&A and profit ratios primarily
because, according to the Auditor’s Reports, the
methodology used in recording and reporting the financial
condition of these two companies appears, in certain
instances, to be inconsistent with the methodology (i.e.,
Indian GAAP) used by the remaining five companies. Given
these significant differences, it would be incongruous to
combine the reported data of all seven companies.
Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken, App. Ex. 3 at 4-5.
Additionally, Commerce in its brief states with respect to
NEI’s annual report that
Note 11 to the auditors’ report provided that “[n]o
provision has been made for Doubtful debts & advances
aggregating Rs 183.65 lacs (Previous year Rs 149.37
lacs).” Note 22 to the auditors’ report provided that
“[t]he Company has not made provision for the Leave
liability of employees (amount unascertained) and the
same as per consistent practice will be accounted for as
(continued...)
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 79
Opp’n Timken, App. Ex. 3.
Specifically, Commerce
calculated factory overhead and [SG&A] expenses
(exclusive of labor and electricity) as percentages of
direct inputs (also exclusive of labor) and applied these
ratios to each producer’s direct input costs. For
profit, [Commerce] totaled the reported profit before
taxes for the six Indian bearing producers and divided it
by the total calculated cost of production (“COP”) of
goods sold. This percentage was applied to each
respondent’s total COP to derive a company-specific
profit value.
Preliminary Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at 36,856.
In the Final Results, during the review at issue, Commerce
continued to use data from only six of the Indian bearing producers
and excluded data from Asian and NEI by stating:
[Commerce] disagree[s] with [Timken] and has[s] excluded
the data for Asian Bearing and NEI in calculating
surrogate overhead, SG&A and profit ratios because,
according to the Auditor’s Reports, the methodology used
in recording and reporting the financial condition of
these two companies appears, in certain instances, to be
inconsistent with the methodology (i.e., Indian GAAP)
used by the remaining six companies.
29
(...continued)
and when paid.”
Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken at 6 (quoting Def.’s Mem. Partial
Opp’n Timken, Proprietary App. Ex. 5 (NEI Annual Report) at 26 and
27)); see also Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken, Proprietary App.
Ex. 5 (NEI Annual Report) at 11.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 80
In this review, the Auditor’s Report included with
Asian Bearing’s 1997-98 financial statements expresses a
clear reservation about how certain interest expenses
(with their corresponding effects on depreciation and
other expenses) have been reported, noting that the
methodology is not in accordance with accounting
principles recommended by the Institute of Chartered
Accountants of India. The Auditor’s Report also notes
that Asian Bearing continues to be a “sick” company as
defined by India’s Sick Industrial Companies Act.
Likewise, the auditors’ endorsement of NEI’s 1997-98
Financial Statements, as contained in the Auditor’s
Report, includes qualifications regarding the company’s
treatment of various overhead and SG&A expenses. As in
[the 10th Annual Review, 63 Fed. Reg 63,842], the
qualifications indicate that the treatment of these
expenses is not consistent with Indian GAAP.
Given these significant differences, it would be
incongruous to combine the reported data of all eight
companies.
Final Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at 61,842-43.
B. Contentions of the Parties
1. Timken’s Contentions
Timken alleges that Commerce’s exclusion of NEI from the
calculation of overhead, SG&A, and profit ratios “was arbitrary and
unreasonable.”30 Timken’s Mem. at 40. In particular, Timken argues
that Commerce “offered no reason and pointed to no facts that would
justify the exclusion of NEI data from the overhead, SG&A, and
30
The Court notes that, in this case, Timken is not
contesting Commerce’s exclusion of Asian from the calculation of
overhead, SG&A, and profit ratios but only the exclusion of NEI.
See Timken’s Mem. at 5 n.4; see also Timken’s Mem. at 37-40 and
Timken’s Reply at 32-35.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 81
profit ratios.” Id. at 38. Timken maintains that: (1) “a
comparison of NEI’s overhead, SG&A, and profit ratios with the
other six companies shows ratios that are well within the range of
other Indian bearing producers,” id. at 38 (citing Timken’s Mem. at
19, Table 4); (2) NEI’s annual report was audited and approved by
Chartered Accountants in India, see Timken’s Mem. at 19; and (3)
“the Auditor’s Report reveals only inconsequential omissions,” id.
at 20.
Timken further argues that “the aggregate annual report data
of all seven Indian bearing producers would have been more
descriptive of the variety of companies in China than the data of
only six producers . . . ,” id. at 40, and “the record included the
figures necessary to make NEI’s annual report data GAAP-compliant.”
Id. at 39. Timken contends, for example, that since NEI’s leave
data was not provided for in NEI’s annual report, Commerce could
have “based the profit ratio on an average labor cost of the other
six Indian bearing companies or relied on another company’s leave
data.” Timken’s Reply at 34.
Finally, Timken asserts that “[a]s there is no evidence that
NEI’s overhead or SG&A ratios were affected by its accounting
methodologies, [Commerce] should at least have used the NEI’s data
for those factors as the best available information for Indian
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 82
bearing producers.” Timken’s Reply at 34 (citing 19 U.S.C. §
1677b(c)(1)).
2. Commerce’s Contentions
Commerce responds that it properly used data from only six of
the Indian bearing producers and excluded the annual report data
contained in NEI when calculating the ratios for overhead, SG&A and
profit. See Def’s Mem. Partial Opp’n Timken at 40-42. Commerce
explained that it rejected NEI’s annual report data because
“the auditors’ endorsement of NEI’s 1997-98 Financial
Statements, as contained in the Auditor’s Report,
includes qualifications regarding the company’s treatment
of various overhead and SG&A expenses.” These
qualifications reveal that NEI made no provision for
doubtful debts and advances or for the leave liability of
employees. . . . Commerce found these qualifications to
be significant because they were inconsistent with Indian
generally accepted accounting principles (“GAAP”)
utilized by the other six companies.
Id. at 41 (quoting Final Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at 61,842).
Moreover, relying on Writing Instrument, 21 CIT at 1195, 984
F. Supp. at 639, Commerce argues that “in determining whether a
surrogate value represents the best available information, Commerce
is authorized to determine the reliability of that value and, if it
is established that the value is unreliable, decline to use that
data for purposes of factor valuation.” Def.’s Mem. Partial Opp’n
Timken at 41.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 83
C. Analysis
The Court finds that Commerce acted reasonably within its
discretion in excluding the annual report data contained in NEI
when calculating the ratios for overhead, SG&A and profit. In
particular, Commerce pointed out that it rejected NEI’s annual
report data because
“the Auditor’s Report [of NEI’s Financial Statements]
includes qualifications regarding the company’s treatment
of various overhead and SG&A expenses.” These
qualifications reveal that NEI made no provision for
doubtful debts and advances or for the leave liability of
employees. . . . Commerce found these qualifications to
be significant because they were inconsistent with Indian
generally accepted accounting principles (“GAAP”)
utilized by the other six companies.
Id. at 41 (quoting Final Results, 64 Fed. Reg. at 61,842).
This Court is not in a position to declare such a conclusion
unreasonable. See Chevron, 467 U.S. at 844-45, and Skidmore, 323
U.S. at 139-40; see also Timken Co., 26 CIT at __, 201 F. Supp. 2d
at 1346 (finding that “Timken may not usurp Commerce’s role as fact
finder and substitute their analysis for the result reached by
Commerce”).
Accordingly, the Court sustains Commerce’s determination to
use the annual report data of six Indian bearing producers as a
surrogate for determining overhead, SG&A and profit rates as
reasonable, in accordance with law and supported by substantial
evidence.
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 84
CONCLUSION
This case is remanded to Commerce to: (1)(a) examine whether
or not the PRC trading company import prices constitute the “best
available information” to value either all of the subject
merchandise at issue or a portion of the subject merchandise
purchased by Luoyang through the trading company and used by
Luoyang in the manufacture of TRB cups and cones and, if Commerce
concludes that the PRC trading company import prices present the
“best available information” for the purpose of such surrogate
evaluation, to recalculate Commerce’s determination not
inconsistent with this opinion; and (b) examine if, and only if,
Commerce finds that the PRC trading company import prices do not
constitute the “best available information,” whether or not
Indonesian data (that is, Indonesian import statistics and export
data from Japan to Indonesia) constitute the “best available
information” over export data from Japan to India to value the
bearing quality steel bar used in the production of TRB cups and
cones, and to explain, (if Commerce finds that export data from
Japan to India is the “best available information,”) how the entire
export data from Japan to India falls within the range of values in
the United States category benchmark range; (2) exclude
“consumption of traded goods” from Commerce’s overhead, SG&A and
profit rate calculations and to recalculate the dumping margins
accordingly; and (3) (a) explain, with reference to the record,
Consol. Court No. 99-12-00743 Page 85
whether or not the PRC bearing producer’s import data at issue was
“meaningful”; and (b) provide the Court with an explanation as to
why the PRC trading company data is not the “best available
information” for the purpose of valuing either the entire FOP (that
is, both the directly imported FOP and the NME sourced FOP) or the
NME sourced FOP. Commerce’s final determination is affirmed in all
other respects.
______________________________
NICHOLAS TSOUCALAS
SENIOR JUDGE
Dated: October 1, 2002
New York, New York